The Use And Effect Of Social Capital In New Venture Creation

Description
Brief file with regards to the use and effect of social capital in new venture creation.


J ENA ECONOMIC
RESEARCH PAPERS




#2010 – 012



The Use and Effect of Social Capital in New Venture
Creation – Solo Entrepreneurs vs. New Venture Teams


by



Uwe Cantner
Michael Stützer




www.jenecon.de

ISSN 1864-7057

The J ENA ECONOMIC RESEARCH PAPERS is a joint publication of the Friedrich
Schiller University and the Max Planck Institute of Economics, J ena, Germany.
For editorial correspondence please contact [email protected].

Impressum:

Friedrich Schiller University J ena Max Planck Institute of Economics
Carl-Zeiss-Str. 3 Kahlaische Str. 10
D-07743 J ena D-07745 J ena
www.uni-jena.de www.econ.mpg.de

©by the author.



1
The Use and Effect of Social Capital in New Venture Creation – Solo
Entrepreneurs vs. New Venture Teams
a


Uwe Cantner, Michael Stuetzer
*

Friedrich Schiller University Jena, Department of Economics, Chair of Microeconomics, Carl-
Zeiss-Str. 3, 07743 Jena, Germany

a
An earlier version of this paper was presented at the Babson College Entrepreneurship Research Conference,
Wellesley, MA (USA), 2009
E-mail addresses: [email protected] (Uwe Cantner), [email protected] (Michael Stuetzer)
* Corresponding author: Tel. +49-3641-943207: fax: +49-3641-943199.

Abstract

This paper examines the use of social capital in the venture creation process. We compare solo
entrepreneurs (n=182) and new venture teams (n=274) from a random sample of start-ups in
innovative industries and test social capital use and its effects on firm performance. Our results
reveal that solo entrepreneurs and new venture teams do not differ in their degree of use of social
capital. However, there are differences in the determinants of social capital use in both groups.
We find that weak ties assist solo entrepreneurs and have positive significant effects on new venture
performance. For team start-ups, we find no direct effect of social capital. However, further tests
indicate for teams that human capital variety positively moderates the effect of social capital on
performance.

Key words: Entrepreneurship; Nascent entrepreneurship; Social capital; Start-up teams;
Entrepreneurial learning

JEL classification: M13, L25, L26, D83
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
2

Acknowledgements

Financial support of the research project “Success and Failure of Innovative Start-ups - A Process-
oriented Analysis of Economic and Psychological Determinants” by the Thuringian Ministry of
Education (Thüringer Kultusministerium) and by the Hans-Böckler-Stiftung is gratefully
acknowledged. We also thank the members of the DFG RTG 1411 “The Economics of Innovative
Change” as well as the participants of conferences at the 12th Annual Interdisciplinary
Entrepreneurship Conference G-Forum 2008 in Dortmund (Germany) at the 6th EMAEE
conference 2009 in J ena (Germany) and at the Babson College Entrepreneurship Research
Conference 2009 in Babson Park, MA for helpful comments. The usual caveats apply.

1. Executive Summary
Social capital theory argues that the social embeddedness of entrepreneurs plays a pivotal role in
the venture creation process and the further fate of a start-up (e.g. Burt, 2000; Nahapiet & Goshal,
1998). It is known that nascent entrepreneurs draw on advice, support and help from their social
networks in the venture creation process (Davidsson & Honig, 2003; Samuelsson & Davidsson,
2009; Elfring & Hulsink, 2003). This use of social capital enables the entrepreneurs to access
resources, novel information and trusted feedback – the latter two being a necessary component of
entrepreneurial learning (Politis, 2005).
This paper focuses on the actual use of social capital by solo-entrepreneurs and entrepreneurial
teams in the venture creation phase. Do teams have more social capital than solo-entrepreneurs?
This argument has been sometimes explicitly (Davidsson & Honig, 2003) but more often implicitly
(e.g. Colombo & Grilli, 2005; van Gelderen et al., 2005) made in a considerable number of studies,
suggesting that belonging to a start-up team is an indicator for social capital. Based on a literature
review, this essay argues that there are two mechanisms by which the decision to launch a start-up
in a team format as opposed to a solo format influences the actual use of social capital. On the one
hand, a team has more contacts to exploit, which increases the probability to actually use social
capital. On the other hand, in a team, the members combine often different skills and abilities,
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
3
enabling them to complete more venture creation activities in house. The actual use of social capital
may thus decrease.
Our second objective is to investigate the impact of social capital use in the venture creation
process on subsequent new venture performance, measured by the number of employees in the third
business year. Thereby, we specifically examine the moderating role of human capital variety on the
link between social capital use and performance.
This essay tests these hypotheses by using a dataset of start-ups in innovative industries (182
solo entrepreneurs and 274 new venture teams). To generate this dataset, face-to-face interviews
with the solo-entrepreneur or the leading entrepreneur of the start-up team
1
were conducted. To
measure social capital use, we apply a new method – the resource generator (van der Gaag &
Snijders, 2004). We study the comparative importance of different types of social capital, such as
“weak ties” (assistance from the circle of the entrepreneurs’ acquaintances), “strong ties”
(assistance from the circle of closest friends and family members) and overall social capital use.
Our results suggest that entrepreneurial teams and solo entrepreneurs do not differ significantly
in their degree of use of social capital. However, there are pronounced differences in how they
employ social capital in the venture creation process. In particular, we find a substitutive
relationship between overall social capital use and human capital in solo start-ups, while no such
clear relationship was found for team start-ups. We find that, for these firms, team size increases the
probability of social capital use, whereas the human capital variety of the team decreases the
probability of using social capital.
Differences also exist in the effect of social capital use on venture performance. For solo start-
ups, weak ties is a strong predictor of employment. However, the use of strong ties has no effect on
employment. No moderating effect of human capital variety on the link between social capital use
and performance was found.

1
We use the terms new venture teams, entrepreneurial teams, and start-up teams interchangeable throughout the essay.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
4
For team start-ups, we determine no direct effect of social capital use. Further tests indicate that,
for teams, human capital variety positively moderates the effect of social capital use (overall and for
weak ties) on new venture performance. Teams with pronounced variety of their knowledge base
profited from the use of social capital. One plausible interpretation of this result is that teams with a
diverse knowledge base have advantages in comparison to less equipped teams. They can better
evaluate information from outside concerning their usefulness and integrate this information into
their knowledge base, thereby facilitating the entrepreneurial learning process.
The results of our research further suggest that solo start-ups and team start-ups differ beyond
the pure number of entrepreneurs. Although the difference in the results of the interaction term
between human capital and social capital variables is only through indirect evidence, we argue that
one of the key characteristics which differentiate solo entrepreneurs from entrepreneurial teams is
the learning process (Politis, 2005). This process seems to be more complex for teams, emphasizing
the role of collective work and information sharing in the learning process.

2. Introduction
A central development within the management literature has been the growth of nascent
entrepreneur research analyzing on-going venture start-up efforts and/or firms in gestation over time
(Davidsson, 2006). New ventures have an important effect on economic development. They are
credited for the transfer of innovations into the market (Schumpeter, 1934) and thereby with
creating regional employment (Fritsch & Mueller, 2004).
Central questions in nascent entrepreneurship research concern the characteristics of the venture
creation process and the factors affecting performance of these firms (see for an overview,
Davidsson, 2006). Among other factors considered in the literature, the social embeddedness of the
entrepreneur has been found to play a pivotal role (Davidsson & Honig, 2003). Social capital
enables entrepreneurs to access resources (Florin et al., 2003) or novel information (Uzzi, 1997) in
order to create opportunities (Baker & Nelson, 2005). During the venture creation process, most
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
5
firms suffer from substantial resource constraints (Shepherd et al., 2000) and use their personal
networks as a means to access resources and information far below market price (Elfring &
Hulsink, 2003).
However, a sizeable gap exists in the burgeoning social capital literature on the subject of team
start-ups. A most prominent result is that team start-ups are more successful than solo start-ups (e.g.
Lechler, 2001). One of the offered explanations is that entrepreneurs can combine their abilities and
financial capital in a team, giving them an advantage above solo entrepreneurs (e.g. Gartner, 1985;
Stam & Schutjens, 2006). Sometimes explicitly (e.g. Colombo & Grilli, 2005; Stam & Schutjens,
2006) but more often implicitly (e.g. Davidsson & Honig, 2003; van Gelderen et al., 2005), the
same argument is applied to the usage of social capital, i.e. that the social capital from individual
team members is combined to provide an advantage for teams over solo entrepreneurs. As yet, to
our knowledge, no study has explicitly analyzed whether, compared to solo-entrepreneurs, more
social capital is found within teams and whether this leads to their better performance.
In this paper, we approach these two questions and empirically explore the use of social capital
of solo entrepreneurs and entrepreneurial teams during the venture creation process. In doing so, we
refine the empirical concept of social capital in that we do not look at its mere existence but focus
on its use in terms of concrete support (e.g. advice on the business plan, marketing, or research and
development (R&D)) for the entrepreneurs. We address two major research questions. The first
concerns the differential use of social capital. Do solo entrepreneurs rely more often on social
capital than new venture teams, or is it the other way around? How do both types of start-ups use
social capital? More precisely, we investigate the relationship between social capital and other
characteristics of the new venture and its founders (e.g. human capital). Our second research
question then turns to the effect of social capital on subsequent new venture performance.
Appropriate hypotheses in this study are tested using a dataset of 456 start-ups in innovative
industries in the German state Thuringia.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
6
The reminder of the paper is organized as follows: in section 3, we review the theory and
previous research on social capital in order to generate six testable hypotheses. In section 4, we
describe the dataset and the methods employed to measure the use of social capital. We then present
(section 5) the results of our analysis. The paper concludes in section 6, where we interpret and
discuss our results and draw some conclusions.

3. Theoretical Background
3.1. New Firm Creation and Social Capital
Creating a new firm, in comparison to being employed, involves high levels of risk and
uncertainty (Lumpkin & Dess, 2001). Entrepreneurs may consider alleviating the effects of risk and
uncertainty by approaching others for help and advice, broadly captured by the concept of social
capital. On the individual level, social capital is defined “as the sum of the actual and potential
resources embedded within, available through, and derived from the network of relationships
possessed by an individual or a social unit” (Nahapiet & Goshal, 1998). According to this
definition, social capital includes a structural dimension taking into account the people an
entrepreneur knows. One of the most important facets of the structural dimension of networks “is
the presence or absence of network ties between actors” (Liao & Welsch, 2005, p. 349). Only if an
entrepreneur has ties to other individuals or institutions may he receive tangible resources via such
relationships, e.g. a first loan, or intangible resources such as information about potential customers.
Furthermore, the definition emphasizes the relational dimension of social capital, by highlighting
the ability and willingness of the entrepreneur to receive network support.
Using this definition as a starting point, different implications arise for solo and team-started
ventures. We return to that point immediately after the introduction of the concept of new venture
teams. We define a venture as a team start-up when more than one person is actively involved in the
venture creation process and when these persons own or had owned a part of the venture (Kamm et
al., 1990). As to mastering the venture creation process, the superiority of team start-ups compared
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
7
to solo start-ups is one result readily acknowledged in entrepreneurship research (e.g. Cooper &
Bruno, 1977; Lechler, 2001). In particular, for high technology firms (our sample of interest), there
is a higher requirement of skills, making team start-up a necessity. Gartner (1985, p.703) argues that
“individuals combine their abilities in teams in order to start an organization successfully.” Hence,
the advantage of a team lies in the bundling of human and financial capital (Stam & Schutjens,
2007).
Upon initial investigation, the argument of bundling of human and financial capital can as well
be applied to a solo entrepreneur’s use of social capital, considered as the ability of an actor to
mobilize useful resources from his social network (Bourdieu, 1986; Burt, 1992; Coleman, 1988).
Teams combine and integrate the social capital of their members, possibly providing them with an
advantage above solo-entrepreneurs (Davidsson & Honig, 2003). As yet, to our knowledge, no
study has explicitly analyzed whether, compared to solo-entrepreneurs, more social capital is found
within teams and whether this leads to their superior performance.
Comparing venture teams and solo entrepreneurs with respect to the structural dimension of
social capital, the former may have an advantage through broader access to critical resources
through their larger number of contacts within their social network. The decision to create a venture
team or to add an additional team member has the potential to increase the social capital base of the
start-up and, as a result, may improve the resource profile of the new venture leading to increased
new venture persistence and success. Implicitly, this argument is made in a considerable number of
studies, as belonging to a start-up team is considered to be an indicator of social capital (e.g.
Colombo & Grilli, 2005; Davidsson & Honig, 2003; van Gelderen et al., 2005).
Looking at the relational dimension of social capital, a contrary argument can be put forward.
While a positive correlation may exist between team size and the possible access to resources via
entrepreneurs’ contacts, the actual use of those contacts may not be correlated with team size.
Compared to a solo entrepreneur, a new venture team can complete more venture creation activities
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
8
in house through combining (often different) skills from its members (Gartner, 1985, p.703). The
actual use of social capital may thus decrease.
In our empirical analysis, we explore whether the mere use of social capitals differs between
solo and team start-ups. With respect to the team start-ups, the two counteracting arguments are to
be considered: First, the strengthening and broadening of the social network in a team, on the one
hand, increases (ceteris paribus) the likelihood of using social capital. Second, the ability of a team
to perform more tasks on its own decreases the likelihood of using social capital. Both effects work
in opposite directions concerning the use of social capital. With due care, we therefore test whether
the use of social capital differs at all between the two types of venture founding by the following
hypothesis:

H1: Solo Entrepreneurs and entrepreneurial teams differ regarding their respective use of social
capital in the venture creation process.

3.2. The Effects of Social Capital
A further focus of our analysis is on the way in which social capital use differently affects the
venture performance for solo entrepreneurs and new venture teams. Given the nature of our dataset
consisting of start-ups in innovative industries, we assess the literature concerning social capital of
tech-based as well as knowledge-based start-ups. The review of that literature reveals that social
capital influences the venture creation process via three different channels. It 1) assists (nascent)
entrepreneurs in accessing resources, 2) provides trusted feedback to the entrepreneurs and 3)
provides access to novel information.
Access to resources is of critical importance to small and young companies in innovative
industries which traditionally suffer from a range of resource constraints including financial capital,
a skilled work-force, or equipment necessary for R&D and production (Aldrich & Martinez, 2001),
which are critical for growth. Anderson et al. (2007) analyze ten technology companies in Aberdeen
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
9
and find evidence for the use of the contacts of the entrepreneurs to former business partners
supported them to recruit their work-force. Much more work has been done in studying the
relationship between social capital and the financing of start-ups. Shane & Cable (2002) argue that
via network ties potential investors were able to screen and to evaluate the entrepreneurs and their
business ideas, which was the basis of the investment decision. Florin et al. (2003) reports for a
sample of US-firms seeking to float on the stock exchange, that the level of social capital is
positively and significantly related to the level of attracted funds and return on sales. However, this
result could only be partially confirmed by Honig et al. (2006), who find some evidence for a
relationship between social capital and the amount of sales, but no links between social capital and
financial capital.
Furthermore, social capital affects growth aspirations among nascent entrepreneurs (Liao &
Welsch, 2003), which is considered a precursor of subsequent venture growth (Baum et al., 2001).
Using a sample of Swedish tech-nascent entrepreneurs, Samuelsson & Davidsson, (2009) find that
projects which extensively use social capital significantly make progress in the venture creation
process. Taken together, we propose the hypothesis:

H2: Social capital in the venture creation process has a positive impact on later new venture
performance.

Trusted feedback is the second transfer channel of social capital. Its theoretical foundations lie
in the relational dimension of social capital (Nahapiet & Goshal, 1998) which deals with the quality
or the kind of ties an actor possesses (Granovetter, 1990). Within the relational aspect of social
capital, tie strength has attracted great interest in the research community. Although it is a
simplification of Granovetter’s (1973) original argument that tie strength is a continuum, ties are
typically categorized as being either weak or strong. Thereby, Granovetter characterizes strong ties
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
10
in contrast to weak ties by a combination of high emotional intensity and intimacy, much time spent
with the network contact, and high reciprocity of services.
The strength of strong ties lies in the high level of trust between the network members. It is well
known that networks with a high proportion of strong ties are “dense” networks (Burt, 2000), which
indicates that many network members are directly connected to each other. Scholars highlight the
importance of trusted feedback and the transfer of tacit knowledge (Aldrich & Martinez, 2001) for
entrepreneurs stemming from such networks as necessary components of entrepreneurial learning
(Zahra et al., 2006). Thereby we understand learning as the process of accumulating knowledge
required for being effective in starting up and managing new ventures (Politis, 2005).
Learning takes place throughout the venture creation process. Bhave (1994) was one of the first
researchers to recognize the complex nature of the venture creation process, which he described as
nonlinear and iterative. Key features of his model are feedback loops between the different stages of
venture creation, allowing for changes in the business concept after receiving corresponding
feedback and information from, e.g., customers and financiers. Other scholars also emphasize the
importance of learning and adapting in the venture creation process (Aldrich & Ruef, 2006;
Ronstadt, 1988; Shane & Venkataraman, 2000) for the development of routines and capabilities
(Zahra et al., 2006) to run a business successfully (Teece et al., 1997).
A well known example of the benefits of learning from strong ties is the study from Elfring and
Hulsink (2003). They report that high-tech start-ups benefit from trusted feedback of their strong
ties to better recognize opportunities. Studying 23 cases in New York’s apparel industry, Uzzi
(1997) finds that companies profit from information transfer on strategies, prices and products from
a dense network which enables them to take advantage on fast changing market opportunities.
However, Uzzi (1997) acknowledges serious drawbacks of relying solely on strong ties and high
density networks. It is argued that information and ideas coming from too densely connected
networks lack newness. Entrepreneurs, who receive information only from inside such insulated
networks, may experience below average performance. This disadvantage is of particular
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
11
importance for high-tech start-up projects with innovative products (as shown by Presutti et al.,
2007), as they operate within global markets, and require greater diversity in ideas, information and
feedback concerning the business idea in line with greater complexity and requirements of their
numerous international markets. In evaluating these mixed findings on the effects of strong ties and
dense networks on entrepreneurial performance, we still postulate the following hypothesis:

H3: Strong ties in the venture creation process have a positive impact on later new venture
performance.

Access to novel information – the third transfer channel – is beneficial for entrepreneurs because
ventures in gestation often do not possess information about relevant facets of business, e.g. prices,
production processes, inputs, and competition (Aldrich & Ruef, 2006) being critical requirements of
the above described entrepreneurial learning (Zahra et al., 2006). This information is widely
dispersed among individual actors within the market (customers and suppliers), as well as among
people seemingly unrelated to the market (engineers, technicians, or financiers).
In general, to access this dispersed information weak ties are considered important, because
through them it is possible to reach distant subgroups of the network via a rather close network
partner. Contrary to strong ties, which have a tendency for closure (Coleman, 1988), weak ties can
serve as bridges to indirect ties (Granovetter, 1973). Therefore, weak ties enlarge the network of an
entrepreneur and provide the nascent entrepreneur access to novel information which may assist in
the discovery of more profitable business opportunities (e.g. Elfring & Hulsink, 2003), to the
development of products (Lechner & Dowling, 2003), to the reduction of the cost of production
(Yli-Renko et al., 2001), and to contacting potential investors (Shane & Cable, 2002). Therefore we
suggest:

Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
12
H4: Weak ties in the venture creation process have a positive impact on later new venture
performance.

To access social capital in general and strong and weak ties in particular requires that the
entrepreneur or the new venture team show an appropriate ability to do so. This leads us to the
concept of human capital. A number of empirical studies report that human capital variables (e.g.
entrepreneurial experience, leadership experience or business experience) have positive significant
effects on the progress of nascent entrepreneurs and subsequent venture success (e.g. Honig et al.,
2006; Samuelsson & Davidsson, 2009). Being more specific in our discussion of the effects of
social capital on venture performance, we argue that an entrepreneur or a new venture team learns
more successfully if human capital aligns with social capital. More precisely, entrepreneurs with a
pronounced human capital variety should have a higher level of “absorptive capacity” to tap a broad
array of relevant information (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990). With human capital variety, we refer
mainly to an entrepreneur’s or a venture teams’ breadth of experience over different functional
activities. Following Hayton and Zahra (2005), we argue that, because of their broader experience,
these entrepreneurs should be more able to rate new information on their usefulness, and
incorporate this new information more easily into their existing knowledge stock.
2
Furthermore, we
suggest that entrepreneurs with higher human capital variety should have a larger social network to
draw on, giving them broader choices and opportunities to select the most appropriate helpers
within their networks. This latter argument is considered within the context of weak ties, because
the strong tie network of an entrepreneur only consists of a very limited number of persons
(Lechner & Dowling, 2003).
To the best of our knowledge, only the study of Batjargal (2007) on internet start-ups in China
has yet examined the moderating effect of human capital on the linkage between social capital and

2
Principally, one could think of different human capital variables affecting the learning process. However, the
approximation of human capital by the heterogeneity of the functional background of top management teams in high-
tech ventures is suggested by Hayton & Zahra (2005), who argue that the absorptive capacity of a new venture team is
better measured with the breadth of the knowledge base instead of the depth of the knowledge base (e.g. heterogeneity
of functional background vs. the average number of years of leadership experience of the entrepreneurial team)
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
13
venture success. Although the econometric findings are mixed, Batjargal (2007) concludes that the
combined effect of human capital and social capital enhances the survival chances of newly
founded businesses. We, therefore, propose the following hypotheses:

H5: The relationship between social capital in the venture creation process and subsequent venture
performance is stronger for solo entrepreneurs and entrepreneurial teams with a higher level of
human capital variety, and
H6: The relationship between weak ties in the venture creation process and subsequent venture
performance is stronger for solo entrepreneurs and entrepreneurial teams with a higher level of
human capital variety.

4. Dataset and Methods
4.1. Dataset and Interview Strategy
For our empirical analysis, we use data from the “Thuringian Founder Study”. This study is an
interdisciplinary research project on success and failure of innovative start-ups and contains both
venture creation data and psychological data. The unique dataset comprises the entries of private
and commercial companies in the commercial register (Handelsregister) between the years 1994-
2006 in the German state Thuringia. This design made it possible to interview not only founders of
active companies but also founders of ventures that had failed. The data base is restricted to entries
in innovative industries (Grupp & Legler, 2000)
3
. The first registered owner-managers for each new
entry form the survey-population. From this population, a random sample of 2,604 start-ups was
generated. From J anuary to October 2008, we conducted 639 face-to-face interviews with the solo
entrepreneur or the leading entrepreneur of a start-up team (response rate 25%). As some companies
were not genuinely new but rather were subsidiaries or the result of a diversification of an existing
company into a new business field, we removed 76 companies from our sample. Thirteen
companies were removed from the sample due to interview quality concerns. For this paper, we

3
Grupp and Legler (2000) define innovativeness at the level of the industry. On average, companies in innovative
industries spend more than 3.5% of their turnover for research and development.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
14
restrict our analysis to observations within the complete dataset and therefore drop 78 observations
with missing values in one or more used variables. Furthermore, to avoid censoring, we dropped 16
observations which started later than 2005.
4
Our empirical analysis evaluates the effect of social
capital use in the venture creation process on subsequent venture performance in the third business
year. The final sample consists of 456 companies, which can be further classified as 182 solo
entrepreneurs and 274 new venture teams.
The structured interviews were conducted by members of the research project and student
research assistants who were trained in various sessions in December 2007. We use a retrospective
design to collect the data. To overcome the bias of hindsight as well as memory decay (Davidsson
2006), we adapt the tool ‘life-history-calendar’ from psychology in order to receive the information
for the venture creation process. The life-history-calendar is a useful tool to reconstruct individual
processes and developments (Caspi et al. 1996; Freedman et al. 1988). One gains more reliable and
valid retrospective information compared to traditional questionnaires (Belli et al., 2001). When the
interview commenced, the participants together with the interviewer filled in major life events and
sequences in the life-history-calendar (family life, working sequences, historical events, and
important dates of the business history). During the interview, the life-history-calendar was visible
to the participants. Before each retrospective item (e.g. team composition, human and social capital
questions) was started, we asked the interviewee to look at the specific time point in the life-history-
calendar and recalled verbally special events taking place during that time in order better to
remember that time. The interview strategy and the life-history-calendar are in line with the
recommendation by Belli et al. (2004). The procedure used for this study enables us to make first
arguments about causality.
The restriction of this study to the German state of Thuringia has the major advantage of
reducing sample heterogeneity stemming from e.g. regional differences. This is of particular

4
Firms founded in 2006 cannot answer any question on their third year of business activity.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
15
importance in Germany where there are still pronounced differences in the determinants of new
venture success between Eastern and Western Germany (Fritsch, 2004).

4.2. Dependent Variables
Our dependent variable attempts to measure the performance of start-up firms. We approximate
this by the absolute number of employees in the third year of operation of the firm. The solo-
entrepreneur, members of the new venture team, as well a potential board of directors were in no
case counted as employees. As our sample consists only of new firms and does not include
franchise or corporate ventures, the vast majority of firms have zero employment in the venture
creation phase. For that reason, employment growth rates could not be computed (see for a similar
approach Baum et al., 2000). If a new venture did not survive the third business year, the number of
employees remained coded as zero.
Traditional outcome variables such as firm value, profitability, and turnover are not applied in
this study for two reasons. First, the self-reported measure of sales turned out to be unreliable.
While respondents could assess the amount of sales generated in the first three business years,
monetary reform in Germany replacing the D-Mark with the Euro in several steps between 1999
and 2001 made it difficult for the entrepreneurs to attribute correctly the sales to either currency.
Second, secondary data from business information providers could not be used, because such
databases tend to focus on larger and surviving firms, reducing substantially the overlap with our
dataset.
Nevertheless we undertook an effort to check the validity of our dependent variable. Two
business information providers (Creditreform and Bureau van Dijk) made available to us data
regarding employment growth in the first three business years for 66 start-ups in our data set. We
found that our measure of number of employees and the corresponding information provided by
Creditreform and Bureau van Dijk (2009) highly correlated (r =.78, p <.001).

Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
16
4.3. Independent Variables
Our independent variables attempt to measure the actual use of social capital in the venture
creation process, which comprises the time from the first concrete steps into the venture creation
process until the start of the of the first business year.
5

Typically, researchers use the name generator or the position generator in social capital
measurement. The name generator (McCallister & Fischer, 1978) maps the ego-centered social
network of an entrepreneur comprising persons who were most helpful in establishing and running
an entrepreneur’s new venture. However, the name generator has a tendency to focus on strong ties
(van der Gaag & Snijders, 2004). Therefore, we opted against this method.
The position generator (Lin & Dumin, 1986) uses the occupations of network members as an
indicator of the access to valuable resources and information. The usefulness of this instrument
hinges on the relative importance and relatedness of the individuals role to the type of start up being
created. For a biotech start-up, knowing bankers or a professor in biology may be more useful then
knowing a poet; but this may be the opposite if an entrepreneur opens up a book store. Hence, this
approach has limited value for studies not focusing on a single industry with a clear hierarchy of
useful contacts.
Therefore, we attempt to improve the measurement of social capital in the field of
entrepreneurship by applying a more recently used measurement procedure, the resource generator,
as developed by van der Gaag and Snijders (2005). This approach focuses on potential helpful
flows of resources and asks typically a battery of questions such as: Do you know any people who
can lend you 5.000 €? The main advantage of this measurement concept is that it measures social
capital at a ‘general’ base (van der Gaag & Snijders, 2004), which refers to the possibility to access
different, concrete and restricted sub domains of social capital. For our analysis, we adapt the
methodology of the resource generator to concrete resource flows instead of potential resource
flows, because our approach is based on the “use” of social capital rather than its mere existence.

5
We define the first business year as the time when accounting started either because of obligations from the
commercial register or because of first revenues. This does not necessarily correspond to the date of registration in the
Handelsregister.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
17
To quantify social capital use, we ask the entrepreneurs if they received advice, support or help
from a third party, free or for less than the usual charge, during the venture creation process in nine
different fields. These fields are derived from the nascent entrepreneurship literature (see
Davidsson, 2006 for an overview), where important activities in the venture creation process are
addressed, such as R&D, market exchange, financing and management. We chose the items to
cover the activities that are important to enable the business to get up and running, primarily
focusing on the recognition and the exploitation of the business opportunity (Shane &
Venkataraman, 2000).
Table 1 displays our measures of social capital use. For solo entrepreneurs and the interviewee
of a start-up team, we have at hand information on whether the advice, support or help came from
the circle of the closest friends and family (strong ties) or from acquaintances (weak ties).
Following the suggestions of Marsden and Campbell (1984), closeness or, in other words,
emotional intensity, serves as an indicator for the tie strength.
6
Note that, in case of a new venture
team, the interviewee was briefed not to report the help which he received from the other members
of the team. We count only help from outside the new venture team. Consequently, the interviewee
was asked whether his team members received advice and support at all from outside, regardless
whether the helpers belonged to family, friends or acquaintances.
7

[Table 1 about here]

To verify the information of the interviewee, for a random sample of 55 cases we conducted an
additional face-to-face interview with another member of the start-up team and received 42
matchable and usable responses. We performed dependent t-tests for paired samples on the equality
of means concerning our main social capital variables, the overall social capital use (indicated by

6
In their seminal work, Marsden and Campbell (1984) identify educational differences, kinship and the fact that two
persons work together as important predictors of tie strength. They suggest closeness or emotional intensity as the best
available indicator for evaluating the strength of a tie. The majority of the empirical studies apply this concept (see for
an overview Kim & Aldrich, 2005), either intentional or unintentional due to practical reasons, since this measurement
procedure is easy to administer and straightforward.
7
In case of team founders, the distinction between weak and strong ties cannot be made, as the interviewee usually was
not able to classify his cofounders’ contacts as weak or strong. Therefore, we only have information about tie strength
concerning the interviewee of the new venture team.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
18
the number of fields with received advises) for the complete team (t =-.48; p =.63) and the
propensity to use any social capital in at least one field (t =-.37; p =.71). The tests reveal no
statistical differences in both cases, giving evidence for the reliability of our social capital variables.
As suggested in the literature (e.g. Delmar & Gunnarson, 2000; Vivarelli, 2004), we also
collected data on whether the entrepreneurs’ networks contained other managers and business
owners (whether they provided support or not), whether the entrepreneur received public advice
from public consulting agencies, and whether people provided encouragement or social support to
start a business. These social capital variables serve as a standard of comparison to our measures of
social capital use and are measured at the venture level (table 1), with the exception of
encouragement and social support. This variable is based on the interviewee only because the
respective question for the other team members can hardly answered by the interviewee in a reliable
way.
[Table 2 about here]
As indicator for human capital variety, we use the variety of functional background of the
entrepreneur(s), which is measured by the number of functional areas in which the founder (team)
has prior work experience (table 2).
8
In case of a new venture team, we count as team members all
persons who were actively involved in the venture creation process and owned or had owned a part
of the venture. Persons entering to and exiting from the team were also counted as team members.
As additional indicators for human capital, we include at the venture level the number of team
members, years of leadership experience, and prior entrepreneurial experience since, in similar
studies, they have been found to have a significant impact on the development and performance of
new ventures (Colombo & Grilli, 2005; Cooper et al., 1994; Eisenhardt & Schoonhoven, 1990).
To control for the effect of financial capital, we include the start-up capital in the first year of
operation. Final controls refer to industry, the start-up year, the possible differences between

8
We choose this simple measure of human capital variety for two reasons. First, Hayton & Zahra (2005) suggest that
the absorptive capacity of the founder (team) in tech ventures is better accessed by variables focussing on the breadth of
the knowledge base instead of the depth of the knowledge base (e.g. the average number of years of leadership
experience of the entrepreneurial team). Second, more complex measures of human capital variety using diversity
indices could not be computed for solo-entrepreneurs.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
19
industrial and service companies, and the innovativeness of the start-up. The descriptive statistics
and correlation matrices are displayed for solo entrepreneurs and entrepreneurial teams separately in
appendices A and B.

5. Results
5.1. Do Solo Entrepreneurs and New Venture Teams Differ in the Use of Social Capital?
We start with a test of hypothesis H1: Do solo entrepreneurs and new venture teams differ in the
use of social capital and, if so, in which fields? To answer this question, we distinguish two cases.
In the first, we compare the interviewees of the different modes of firm founding (solo start-up vs.
team start-up), henceforth called the interviewee level. In the second case, we compare the solo
start-up with the aggregate of all members of a team start-up, henceforth called the venture level.
On the one hand, these comparisons are accomplished by using our measure for overall social
capital use, representing the number out of nine fields in which social capital can be used, and by
the propensity to use any social capital. On the other hand, we compare both start-up modes on the
basis of the traditional social capital variables. We apply Wilcoxon-Man-Whitney and Chi-square
tests in order to find differences in those counts and probabilities.
With respect to the interviewee level, we find (table 3) that a solo entrepreneur uses, in general,
more social capital than the interviewee of a team start-up. More precisely, the solo entrepreneur
uses, with a probability of 76%, any social capital and at the mean overall social capital in 3.0
fields compared to 68% and 2.3 fields in the sub sample of the interviewees of a team start-up.
These differences are significant at least at the 5% level. Looking at the traditional indicators of
social capital, we find no statistical significant differences between the two modes of firm founding
on the interviewee level.
[Table 3 about here]

Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
20
Concerning the venture level (table 3), we find no statistically significant difference between
solo start-ups (76%; 3.0 fields) and team start-ups using any social capital in 73% of the cases
representing overall social capital use in 2.7 fields. Testing also for two of the three traditional
indicators for social capital
9
does not deliver significant differences between the solo and team
responses.
To summarize, we find no support for hypothesis H1 according to which solo entrepreneurs and
new venture teams differ in their use of social capital.
10


5.2. The Effects of Social Capital
Testing the effects of social capital on venture performance, we refer to hypotheses (H2) on
overall social capital, (H3) on strong ties, and (H4) on weak ties. Each of them is supposed to have
a positive impact on new venture performance, as expressed in the absolute number of employees in
the third year of firm operation. We run regressions for a sample containing all start-ups, including
both solo and team start-ups. We again distinguish two ways of representing team start-ups, the
venture level and the interviewee level. These regression results are displayed in the models 1-3 in
table 4. Looking at the venture level in model 1, overall social capital turns out to be insignificant.
In model 2 and model 3, relying on variables at the interviewee level, we get significant coefficients
for neither individual overall social capital nor for weak ties and strong ties. Furthermore, in all
three models, the traditional social capital variables knowing other managers and business owners,
encouragement and social support, and public advice show no significant effects. Concerning
human capital, we only find significant positive effects for variety of functional background at the
1% level. Concerning the controls, we find significantly positive effects for start-up capital at the
1% level, as well as significant time and industry dummies.

9
Since we are operating at the venture level, we cannot perform a comparison with respect to the variable
encouragement and social support, because we only posses these data for the interviewee member of the start-up team.
10
Interestingly, this result holds for the traditional indicators of social capital. What empirically distinguishes these
traditional indicators from the nine fields of used social capital is the fact that they occur with a much higher
probability. Furthermore, the traditional indicators do not show the observed pattern with higher occurrence for a solo
entrepreneur compared to the interviewee of a new venture team. This confirms our argument that traditional indicators
can‘t disentangle social capital from team issues.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
21
[Table 4 about here]

Based on these results, we are forced to reject our hypotheses H2 to H4. This is quite an
unexpected outcome and, combined with the unexpected result of no difference in using social
capital between solo start-ups and entrepreneurial teams, leaves us with a puzzle. A solution to this
puzzle may be found in analyzing whether the two types of start-ups differ in their respective use of
social capital. This may give some justification for the results found so far.

5.3. The Differential Use of Social Capital
Looking at the way in which the two types of start-ups use social capital, as a dependent
variable we use various binary measures for the general use of any social capital. As independent
variables, we include our controls as well as one of the traditional social capital measures, knowing
other managers and business owners. We start by analyzing solo entrepreneurs.
Table 5 provides the results of the logistic regression. Model 1 refers to solo entrepreneurs. We
find knowing other managers and business owners to have a positive significant effect on the use of
social capital at a level of 1%. A significantly negative effect at the 1% level is found for leadership
experience. In addition, service companies are significantly more likely to use social capital,
whereas more innovative ventures use significantly (at 10% level) less social capital.
[Table 5 about here]

Performing the same analyses for entrepreneurial teams, we run two models distinguishing the
venture level (model 2 in table 5) and the interviewee level (model 3 in table 5). For models 2 and
3, as for solo entrepreneurs, knowing other managers and business owners shows up significantly
positive at the 1% level for entrepreneurial teams. At the venture level in model 2, higher
innovativeness and higher leadership experience contribute significantly to the usage of social
capital in the complete team at the 5% and 10% level, respectively. The effect of the variety of
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
22
functional background, however, is significantly negative at the 5% level. The level of the
interviewee in model 3 reveals significantly positive effects from the number of team members
(5%) and the leadership experience (1%).
Comparing these two sets of results, we find major differences in using social capital between
the two types of start-ups. Leadership experience reduces the use of social capital for solo
entrepreneurs, but increases the use of social capital in start-up teams. For new venture teams only,
a higher variety of functional background significantly reduces the use of social capital. In addition,
the number of team members is positively correlated with the use of social capital in entrepreneurial
teams.
This difference in the way the use of social capital is determined between solo entrepreneur and
entrepreneurial teams is remarkable and unexpected given the existing literature on social capital.
One may ask whether this can already be explained by significant differences among the two groups
in some major features such as innovativeness or their assignment to certain industries and start-up
years. However, Chi-square test on equality and Wilcoxon-Mann-Whitney test could neither be
rejected for innovativeness (
2
? =1.27, p =.26), nor for industry assignment (
2
? =.66, p =.88),
nor for service company (
2
? =0.94, p =0.76), nor for start-up year (
2
? =15.99, p =.45). The only
difference between both start-up modes we find concerning our independent and control variables is
the variety of functional background (z =-2.05, p =.04). Hence, we can conclude that the purpose
of accessing social capital differs between solo entrepreneurs and entrepreneurial teams. For the
former, it is rather a matter of whether the entrepreneur is convinced of mastering the task
successfully as expressed by leadership experience. In entrepreneurial teams, the focus is rather on
getting the portfolio of competences right as expressed by the variety of functional background.

5.4. The Differential Effect of Social Capital
Based on these results, we now return to the first analysis of the effects of social capital on firm
performance, as expressed in employment three years after foundation. We run regressions
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
23
separately for the two types of venture founding and integrate interaction terms accounting for the
manner in which social capital is used in both groups.

Solo Entrepreneurs
Table 4 (middle section) displays the results of negative binomial regressions. We distinguish
the case of social capital in general (model 4 and 5) and the case of disaggregated social capital in
terms of weak and strong ties (model 6 and 7). Using identical controls in all four models, we find
start-up capital and leadership experience to be significant predictors (at the 1% level) of venture
performance. The regressions also show significantly negative effects of entrepreneurial experience
on venture success. This result is very unusual and can only be understood in light of the
transformation process of Eastern Germany from a planned to a market economy (Fritsch, 2004).
During this process starting from 1990, a considerable number of western German entrepreneurs
founded businesses in the eastern part of Germany. Our data suggest that these western
entrepreneurs more often failed than eastern entrepreneurs if they did not team up with people from
the eastern part of Germany. It could be argued that these entrepreneurs lacked relationships with
suppliers and critical contacts to access customers and were vulnerable in the face of fast changing
market conditions. Furthermore, western entrepreneurs often ran businesses in their home region to
which they could easily return if the new businesses in Eastern Germany were about to fail.
Looking at our hypotheses stating that (H2) overall social capital, (H3) weak ties, and (H4)
strong ties have a positive impact on new venture performance, we find only hypothesis H3 (model
6) to be supported at the 5% level. Insignificant coefficients for overall social capital (model 4) as
well as strong ties (model 6) force us to reject the respecting hypotheses H2 and H4. In contrast, the
traditional social capital indicator variables, knowing other managers and business owners,
encouragement and social support, and public advice show no significant effects in all models.
For a test of our two hypotheses H5 and H6, suggesting moderating effects of the variety of
functional background (H5) on the relationship between overall social capital and performance as
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
24
well as a (H6) on the relationship between weak ties and performance, we include respective
interaction terms in models 5 and 7 in table 4. However, both hypotheses have to be rejected due to
insignificant coefficients of the respective interaction terms.

Entrepreneurial Teams
Turning to entrepreneurial teams, table 5 (right section) delivers the results of the negative
binomial regressions. We distinguish again between the venture level in models 8 and 9 and the
level of the interviewee in model 10 and 11. As to the human capital variables, the results differ
from those of section 5.4 on solo entrepreneurs: leadership experience and entrepreneurial
experience are not essential for the success of entrepreneurial teams. Instead, team variety of
functional background is highly significant at the 5% level. With respect to the traditional social
capital indicators, all results of section 5.4.1 are confirmed: Neither knowing other managers and
business owners, nor encouragement and social support, nor public advice shows significant
effects.
Again, examining the hypotheses stating that (H2) overall social capital, (H3) strong ties, and
(H4) weak ties will have a positive impact on new venture performance, we find all hypotheses
rejected (models 8 and 10) due to insignificant coefficients. In contrast, the interaction term of
variety of functional background × social capital in model 9 is positive and highly significant at
least at the 1% level. Hence, the variety of functional background moderates the effect of team
social capital on firm performance. This result is also found when looking at level of the
interviewee (model 11). Here again, the interaction term of variety of functional background ×
weak ties is significantly positive at the 5% level. Hence, quite distinct from the evidence on solo
entrepreneurs, we find here a moderating effect of the variety of functional background. Running an
OLS regression instead of a negative binomial regression confirms these results although at a lower
level of significance of 10%.
[Figure 1 about here]
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
25

We examine the impact of the variety of the functional background in more detail in figure 1.
11

As illustrated in the left part of the figure, entrepreneurial teams which had a greater variety in their
functional background enjoyed a higher employment level when more often employed social
capital, supporting hypothesis H5. This result holds if we focus on social capital in terms of weak
ties (right part of figure 2), supporting the respective hypotheses H6.
12


6. Discussion and Conclusion
6.1. Interpretation and Discussion of the Results
Our study empirically examined the use of social capital among solo-entrepreneurs and
entrepreneurial teams in the venture creation process. Based on a sample of 456 start-ups in
innovative industries, we tried to answer two research questions: First, do entrepreneurial teams
more often use social capital than do solo entrepreneurs? Second, what are the effects of social
capital use in the venture creation process on subsequent venture performance? Table 6 summarizes
our results.
To answer the first question, we find that venture teams do not use more social capital than do
solo entrepreneurs in the venture creation process. This unexpected result is due to the fact that the
two links explained in the following have reverse but quantitatively coequal impacts on social
capital use.
The standard proposition concerning the team-social capital issue is that a team start-up
compared to a solo-entrepreneur, or a larger team compared to a smaller team, has more social
capital. This proposition is sometimes more explicitly (e.g. Colombo & Grilli, 2005) made, but
more often implicitly applied (e.g. Davidsson & Honig, 2003; van Gelderen et al., 2005). Its
validity depends on how we define social capital. In case we define social capital as the potential
access to resources and information, the standard proposition holds true, because the number of

11
These figures are computed using the regression coefficient of a respective OLS-regression.
12
The results hold not true if we run a regression on the moderated effect of strong ties. There, the respective interaction
term is insignificant. These regressions is not shown here, but available from the authors upon request.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
26
team members will be positively correlated with the overall number of contacts and hence with the
possible access to resources or information. When we, however, focus on the actual use of the
network contacts, the proposition is at least questionable, if not unfounded. In a start-up team, its
members combine their (often) different skills, abilities, information and resources, enabling them
to perform more activities in the start-up process in house. Hence, the actual use of social capital
will be negatively correlated with the corresponding heterogeneity of the start-up team.
Looking at our empirical results, we find evidence for both links affecting the use of social
capital of new venture teams. First, team size is positively correlated with social capital use,
suggesting that a new venture team compared to a solo entrepreneur as well as a larger team
compared to smaller one has more contacts to use. Second, the variety of functional background in a
team is negatively correlated with social capital use. This result suggests that the use of those
contacts is interdependent of other characteristics of the entrepreneurs. Previous empirical literature
has paid limited attention to that second link. The study of Renzulli and Aldrich (2005) is an
exception and complements our results. They focus on the determinants of tie activation for
business start-ups and find that heterogeneity within the social network of an entrepreneur
significantly increases the probability of using those contacts for business purposes. In contrast to
our study, they evaluate the characteristics of network ties and the resulting impact on social capital
use, while we are concerned with the characteristics of the team or solo entrepreneur and its impact
on social capital use. In both cases, heterogeneity among actors is positively correlated with the use
of social capital.
Despite the evidence that new venture teams and solo-entrepreneurs do not differ in their use of
social capital, there are pronounced differences in the way in which both start-up modes use social
capital in the venture creation process. We find that the human capital characteristics influencing
social capital use are different for both groups. For solo entrepreneurs, there are clear indications of
a substitutive relationship between human capital in terms of the leadership experience of the
founder and social capital use. Contrariwise for start-up teams, no such clear relationship was
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
27
found. Leadership experience positively correlates with social capital use. Team size and the variety
of a team’s knowledgebase have as described above reverse effects on social capital.
Concerning the second question, we find that social capital use affects new venture performance
differently for both start-up modes. The results of section 5.4 lead to the conclusion that, for
entrepreneurial teams, there are rather indirect effects of social capital use on firm performance
moderated by the human capital variety.. The more teams are specialized in their functional
background, the more team members do work with and learn from each other with less of a reliance
on accessing social capital. A more diversified team complements the human capital available by
increasingly relying on social capital. In contrast, for solo entrepreneurs, there appears to be a direct
relationship of social capital on performance. The solo entrepreneurs profit from information
provided by their weak ties. However, their human capital variety (variety of functional
background) does not significantly contribute to any employment effects.
The results of our research lead us to the conclusion that solo start-ups and team start-ups differ
beyond the pure number of entrepreneurs. Although the difference in the significance level of the
interaction term between human capital and social capital variables is only indirect evidence, we
argue that one of the key characteristics which differentiate solo entrepreneurs from entrepreneurial
teams is the learning process. Thereby we understand the need for the development of necessary
knowledge as effective in starting up and managing new ventures (Politis, 2005). This process is
more complex for teams, because, as they work together in the start-up project, they also learn
together. Consider the case of a solo entrepreneur. He can directly evaluate information stemming
from his personal contacts and integrate them into his knowledge base. By way of contrast, a
member of a new venture team may not use directly such contacts. The entrepreneur will probably
first ask his team members if he should approach his personal contact for help or information.
Thereafter, the team members together probably consult this outside help and then evaluate together
the usefulness of the information and their further actions.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
28
This supposed model fits well to the data and to the description the nascent entrepreneurs gave
us during the interviews. We suppose that, for a team which has a broad knowledge base, it is more
likely that they opt against help from the outside. However, if such a team indeed uses social
capital, it profits considerably from the information transfer due to two mechanisms. First, their
learning and evaluation procedure enables them to detect more valuable information. Second,
because of the breadth of their knowledge base, they can more efficiently integrate and exploit the
new knowledge. This view of organizational learning and the importance of diverse knowledge base
are in line with recent studies (e.g. Hayton & Zahra, 2005) on venture teams.

6.2. Implications for Practice
Our study has several implications for practice. For those who have chosen to start up alone,
access to novel information about markets, prices, competitors is of critical importance. This
information is best accessed via weak ties, which includes (former) colleagues, friends, and former
employers, as well as people at conferences and trade fairs. We find that help, advice or support
from those weak ties has positive effects on venture performance. In contrast, help from the circle
of the closest friends and family members does not appear to have measurable effects on
performance. Entrepreneurs may value trusted feedback from such sources highly, but the
information lacks breadth and scope.
For those who have chosen to team up with other people to start a venture, our implications are
somewhat counterintuitive. We observe a high level of human capital in the new venture teams. On
average, in four out of six predefined categories the team as a whole benefits from the work
experience of its members. Such teams with high variety tend not to use their contacts, instead
relying heavily on the knowledge base within the start-up team. However, these teams would gain
the most from really using their network contacts. It seems that these teams have several advantages
compared to less equipped teams. First, they can better evaluate information from outside
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
29
concerning their usefulness. Second, they have probably a choice among different helpers, leading
to better quality of the help.

6.3. Implications for Theory
Our study has one particular implication for entrepreneurship theory, by contributing to the
discussion concerning the nature of an entrepreneurial team. What is an entrepreneurial team? Is it
just the leading entrepreneur dominating? Is it the sum of its parts? Is it more or rather something
different than the sum of its parts? This question is of crucial importance for our understanding of
entrepreneurship, since a substantial share of new venture projects are started by teams. The answer
to that question given by the research community has changed over the past decades.
The trait approach treated the entrepreneur as a lonely hero and mainly paid attention to
psychological characteristics of the single actor (see for an overview Gartner, 1988). The
entrepreneurial team was not part of the research agenda. Over the past few years, the majority of
the research uses the venture as level of analysis (Davidsson & Wiklund, 2001). Often team related
variables are treated by summing the individual responses of the entrepreneurs. In our view, this is a
progress because it at least accepts the existence of the new venture team. However, studies
focusing on team issues in entrepreneurship are scarce – with some notable exceptions (e.g.
Chandler et al., 2005; Chowdhurry, 2005). These studies find evidence that the internal team
processes such as communication, co-laboring and common decision making are important
predictors for team success. This contradicts the view that teams are purely the sum of their parts,
but does not answer the question whether the team is more than the sum of its parts or different
from them.
We find for team start-ups but not for solo start-ups interaction effects between human and
social capital variables, suggesting that the team start-ups are something different than the sum of
their parts. We argue that this interaction effect stems from collective work and information sharing
between the team members in the venture creation process, fostering learning at the individual and
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
30
collective level. Our view is supported by research on teams operating in a range of contexts, such
as primary care teams (Bunniss & Kelly, 2008), new product development teams (Bourgeon, 2007),
and multidisciplinary working teams in the oil and gas industry (van der Vegt & Bunderson, 2005).
All these studies emphasize the roles of collective work and information sharing in the learning
process of a team.
In the field of entrepreneurship, some work has already been done concerning collective
cognition (West, 2007; Shepherd & Krueger, 2002; Ensley & Pearce, 2001). For example, West
(2007, p.83) argues that in team start-ups “decisions are not left up to the individual”. Instead, often
the team makes the decision. For West, it is important to understand how the individual
perspectives of the entrepreneurs about strategy translate into a collective understanding triggering
collective decision and action. His model of collective cognition contains the individual cognition
of the team members, as well as team internal processes and the environment external to the team.
As Weick and Roberts (1993) suggest, we want to emphasize that we use the word collective
instead of group, because we do not think that the team members merge into one group and we
neither deny the existence and importance of the individuals nor the collective. Both levels, the
individual as well as the collective, are present in an entrepreneurial team. In our view, research
combining the individual and the collective level should yield valuable results for entrepreneurship.
Future research may address in more detail how individual skills and individual social network
contacts translate into the knowledge base of the emerging venture and which factors, such as
communication and trust, influence this process. Process research techniques could shed light on
these transfer mechanism.

6.4. Strength and Limitations of our Study
We believe that the strengths of our study mainly lie in the methods applied. First, we apply a
new method to measure social capital in emerging and young organizations. The resource generator
from van der Gaag and Snijders (2005) is a useful tool to access social capital in various concrete
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
31
and restricted sub domains. Furthermore, it is easy to administer and does not consume much time
in an interview. Second, we apply for the first time in entrepreneurship research the established
method of the life-history-calendar (Freedman et al., 1988). This method is of particular usefulness
for studies using a retrospective design, because it helps to reduce the well known memory decay
and hindsight bias. Third, we conducted face-to-face interviews with the entrepreneurs and tried to
verify independent variables as well as dependent variables.
However, our study also has its limitations. First and most important, our study is retrospective
in nature. Although we use the above describe techniques to gain reliable information about the
venture creation process from the entrepreneur, we cannot completely rule out memory decay and
hindsight bias. In one extreme case, there was a time span of 20 years from the first steps into the
venture creation process until our interview. Second, we use self-reported measure of the number of
employees as dependent variable. Thus we suffer from the self-report bias. However, we checked
for reliability of the data using secondary information of a business information provider. Market
value of the start-up or turnover would be more appropriate dependent variables, which
unfortunately are inaccessible for our dataset consisting of very young and small enterprises. Third,
concerning the independent variables, we also relied on information of only one member of a start-
up team. We checked the reliability of the respondent information by interviewing an additional
member of the entrepreneurial team. Regardless whether these efforts confirm the overall reliability
of our social capital use variables, we still miss disaggregated information on the use of weak and
strong ties for the other team members.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
32

Table 1: Independent social capital variables for predicting venture success
Independent variable Operationalization
Social capital use
Strong ties
(Interviewee)
We asked the solo-entrepreneur or the interviewee of a start-up team if he received advice, support, or help from a third party free or for less than the
usual charge during the venture creation process. More precisely we asked: How many people from the circle of the closest friends and family
members ...
1) ... have helped to write the business plan? 2) ... have supported the project with experience in the specific industry? 3) ... have conveyed contacts
to potential customers? 4) ... brought knowledge and experience needed for the development of products and services? 5) ... brought knowledge and
experience needed for producing products / delivering services? 6) ... have helped the project with contacts to potential investors and lenders? 7) ...
have helped in marketing and promotion? 8) ... have helped the project with their contacts to the administration and policy or their reputation? 9) ...
have helped by the refinement of the business idea?
However, we do not use the mere number of received advises. Instead, dummy variables for each field were created, indicating whether the
entrepreneurs use social capital at all. The measure of help from strong ties is then the count of fields with received help, support or advice.
Weak ties
(Interviewee)
Count of fields with received help support or advice (same procedure as with strong ties) from the circle of acquaintances. Acquaintances were defined
as people the entrepreneur knew and could have talk when meeting on the street.
Overall social capital
(Interviewee)
Count of fields with received help support or advice (same procedure as with strong ties) from either the circle of acquaintances or the circle of the
closest friends and family members.
Overall social capital
(Team)
In case of a start-up team, we additionally asked the interviewee if the other team members received advice, support or help from a third party in the
nine respective fields. To ensure answerability of the questions, these are only binary items whether the other members used social capital. The
measure of overall social capital is an aggregation of the help received by the interviewee and the other team members. We compute for overall
social capital the count of fields with received help, support or advice across all members of the start-up team.
Any social capital
(Interviewee)
Dummy: 1=Use of social capital in any of the nine different categories; otherwise=0; data at the interviewee level.
Any social capital
(Team)
Dummy: 1=Use of social capital across all members of the start-up team in any of the nine different categories; otherwise=0.
Social capital traditional
Knowing other
managers and
business owners
Dummy: 1=Knowing other managers and business owners from the first steps into the venture creation process until the start of the first business year;
otherwise=0; data at the venture level.
Encouragement and
social support
Dummy: 1=Received encouragement and social support in the venture creation process until the start of the first business year; otherwise=0, data at the
interviewee level.
Public advice Dummy: 1=Received advise from public institutions for different activities in the venture creation process until the start of the first business year;
otherwise=0; data at the venture level.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
33

Table 2: Control variables
Independent variable Operationalization
Human capital
Number of team
members
Count of all team members who were actively involved in the venture creation process until the start of the first business year +ownership of a part of
the venture.
Variety of functional
background
Count of categories with working experience prior the first steps into the venture creation process across all team members (Six categories:
1=Management, 2=Marketing/Sales/Promotion, 3=Accounting/Controlling/Financing, 4=Engineering/R&D, 5=Production, 6=Personnel); data at the
venture level.
Leadership experience Count of years with experience in executive positions prior the first steps into the venture creation process across all team members; data at the venture
level.
Entrepreneurial
experience
Count of companies (registered in the commercial register) prior to the first steps into the venture creation process across all team members; data at the
venture level.
Others
Service company Dummy: 1=Company offers mainly services; otherwise=0.
Innovativeness Dummy: 1=Conducting R&D in the venture creation phase and the first three years of business was a major activity for the start-up; otherwise=0.
Start-up capital Financial capital (equity +debt) at the start of the first business year, Categorical variable: 1=1.000 Euro or less, 2=more than 1.000 Euro till 10.000
Euro, 2=more than 1,000 Euro till 10,000 Euro, 2=more than 1,000 Euro till 10,000 Euro, 3=more than 10,000 Euro till 50,000 Euro, 4=more than
50,000 Euro till 100,000 Euro, 5=more than 100,000 Euro till 250,000 Euro, 6=more than 250,000 Euro till 500,000 Euro, 7=more than 500,000
Euro.
Time dummies Start-up year, 4 dummy variables: 1) start-up prior to 1994, 2) start-up between 1994 and 1997, 3) start-up between 1998 and 2000, 4) start-up between
2000 and 2006.
Industry dummies NACE, 1-digit: 1) Chemical industry, metalworking industry, engineering, 2) Electrical engineering, fine mechanics, optics, 3) Information and
communication technology, R&D, services, 4) Miscellaneous.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
34
Table 3: Use of social capital between solo entrepreneurs and entrepreneurial teams

Solo
entrepreneurs
(mean values)
Entrepreneurial
teams
(mean values)
Wilcoxon-Mann-Whitney test
a

Chi-square test
b


Social capital use



2.920 (0.004) *** Overall social capital IL
c

VL
3.0
3.0
2.3
2.7
1.244 (0.210)
4.167 (0.041) ** Any social capital IL
VL
0.76
0.76
0.68
0.73
0.800 (0.371)
Social capital traditional
1.165 (0.281) Knowing other managers
and business owners
IL
VL
0.58
0.58
0.53
0.61
0.482 (0.488)
0.001 (0.971) Encouragement and social
support
d

IL
VL
0.52
0.52
0.52


0.015 (0.903) Public advice IL
VL
0.42
0.42
0.42
0.44
0.185 (0.667)
Number of observations

182 274

Note:
a
Wilcoxon-Mann-Whithney test on overall social capital use with prob >|t| in parentheses;
b
Chi-square test any social
capital use and on social capital traditional with prob >|z| in parentheses;
c
data in first row on interviewee level (IL), data in
second row on the venture level (VL), for solo entrepreneurs both levels are identical;
d
encouragement and social support is
based on the interviewees response only; *** (**,*) denote a significance level of 1% (5%, 10%);

Table 5: The differential use of social capital
Dependent variable: Any social capital use
a
Solo entrepreneurs Entrepreneurial teams
Venture level Interviewee level
(1) (2) (3)
Social capital traditional
Knowing other managers and business 0.601*** 0.841*** 0.861 ***
Human capital and controls
Number of team members ----- -0.088 0.325 **
Variety of functional background
0.221 -0.360** -0.054
Leadership experience
-0.592*** 0.330* 0.322 *
Entrepreneurial experience
0.211 -0.125 -0.334
Service company
0.496** -0.135 0.244
Innovativeness
-0.379* 0.428** 0.172
Start-up capital
0.144 -0.067 0.115
Time dummies / Industry dummies No/No No/No No/No
Constant 1.453*** 1.234*** -1.537 ***
Chi
2
35.701 47.673 41.487
Pseudo R
2
0.182 0.148 0.142
Number of observations 182 274 274
a
Logistic regressions; *** (**,*) denote a significance level of 1% (5%, 10%)

Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
35
Table 4: The effect of social capital use
Dependent variable: Number of employees in the third year of operation
a

All Start-up projects Entrepreneurial teams
Venture level Interviewee level
Solo entrepreneurs
Venture level Interviewee level
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11)
Social capital use
Social capital (Team) 0.01 ----- ----- ----- ----- ----- ----- 0.03 -0.02 ----- -----
Social capital (Interviewee) ----- 0.03 ----- 0.10 0.10 ----- ----- ----- ----- ----- -----
Weak ties (Interviewee) ----- ----- 0.03 ----- ----- 0.18** 0.16** ----- ----- 0.01 -0.02
Strong ties (Interviewee) ----- ----- -0.06 ----- ----- -0.12 -0.11 ----- ----- 0.02 0.02
Social capital traditional
Knowing other managers and
business owners
0.02 0.01 0.02 -0.05 -0.05 -0.05 -0.05 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.05
Encouragement and social support 0.07 0.06 0.08 0.04 0.04 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.08 0.05 0.70
Public advice 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.09 0.09 0.05 0.05 -0.09 -0.10 -0.09 -0.10
Human capital and controls
Number of teammembers 0.03 0.04 0.02 ----- ----- ----- ----- -0.01 -0.02 -0.01 -0.02
Variety of functional background 0.18*** 0.18*** 0.18*** 0.04 0.05 0.01 0.02 0.18*** 0.17** 0.17** 0.16**
Leadership experience 0.04 0.04 0.03 0.27*** 0.27*** 0.24*** 0.24*** -0.09 -0.08 -0.08 -0.06
Entrepreneurial experience -0.07 -0.07 -0.07 -0.15** -0.15** -0.17** -0.17** -0.07 -0.06 -0.07 -0.06
Service company 0.01 0.01 0.01 -0.02 -0.02 -0.01 0.01 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.07
Innovativeness -0.04 -0.04 -0.04 -0.08 -0.07 -0.06 -0.05 -0.02 -0.03 -0.02 -0.03
Start-up capital 0.32*** 0.32*** 0.33*** 0.24*** 0.25*** 0.25*** 0.26*** 0.38*** 0.39*** 0.38*** 0.38***
Time dummies / Industry dummies Yes/Yes

Yes/Yes Yes/Yes

No/Yes No/Yes No/Yes No/Yes Yes/Yes Yes/Yes Yes/Yes Yes/Yes
Interaction terms




Variety of functional background x
Overall social capital
-----

----- -----

----- 0.12 ----- ----- ----- 0.15*** ----- -----
Variety of functional background x
Weak ties (Interviewee)
-----

----- -----

----- ----- ----- 0.08 ----- ----- ----- 0.14**
Constant 1.97***

1.97*** 1.97***

1.72*** 1.72*** 1.70*** 1.70*** 2.05*** 2.03*** 2.05*** 2.05***
Alpha 0.91

0.91 0.91

0.68 0.67 0.64 0.64 0.91 0.89 0.91 0.89
Chi
2
108.8

109.0 110.9

67.60 69.63 74.27 75.18 74.56 81.12 74.57 80,13
Pseudo R
2
0.04

0.04 0.04

0.06 0.06 0.07 0.07 0.04 0.05 0.04 0.05
Number of observations 456

456 456

182 182 182 182 274 274 274 274
a
Negative binomial regression; *** (**,*) denote a significance level of 1% (5%, 10%)
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
36

Figure 1: The moderating effect of teams’ variety of functional background
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
37
Appendix A: Descriptive Statistics and Intercorrelation Matrix for Solo entrepreneurs



Note: * denote a significance level of 5%

Variable Mean Sd (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13)
(1) Number. of employees 3rd year 6.77 11.56 - - - - - - - - - - - - -
(2) Overall social capital (Interviewee) 2.98 2.45 0.00 - - - - - - - - - - - -
(3) Any social capital (Interviewee) 0.76 0.43 0.05 0.67* - - - - - - - - - - -
(4) Weak ties (Interviewee) 2.02 2.18 0.09 0.78* 0.51* - - - - - - - - - -
(5) Strong ties (Interviewee) 1.36 2.01 -0.09 0.59* 0.38* 0.04 - - - - - - - - -
(6) Knowing other managers and business owners 0.58 0.50 0.02 0.26* 0.26* 0.19* 0.16* - - - - - - - -
(7) Encouragement and social support 0.52 0.50 0.05 0.41* 0.34* 0.26* 0.33* 0.24* - - - - - - -
(8) Public advice 0.42 0.50 0.12 0.21* 0.07 0.25* 0.03 -0.06 0.13 - - - - - -
(9) Variety of functional background 3.02 1.74 0.04 -0.05 0.02 0.06 -0.15 0.07 -0.07 -0.00 - - - - -
(10) Leadership experience 6.73 7.67 0.28* -0.11 -0.25* 0.04 -0.15* -0.02 -0.13 0.03 0.28* - - - -
(11) Entrepreneurial experience 0.18 0.48 -0.07 0.07 0.04 0.11 -0.05 -0.03 -0.06 -0.10 0.11 0.15 - - -
(12) Service company 0.48 0.50 -0.14 0.19* 0.25* 0.12 0.12 0.20* -0.04 0.02 -0.05 -0.21* 0.04 - -
(13) Innovativeness 0.29 0.45 -0.01 -0.10 -0.20* -0.07 -0.05 -0.07 -0.09 0.03 0.09 0.19* 0.12 -0.12 -
(14) Start-up capital 3.18 1.40 0.23* -0.05 -0.01 -0.02 -0.04 -0.06 -0.10 0.12 0.17* 0.13 0.08 -0.22* 0.13
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
38
Appendix B: Descriptive Statistics and Intercorrelation Matrix for Entrepreneurial Teams



Note: * denote a significance level of 5%
Variable Mean Sd (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16)
(1) Number of employees 3rd year 9.12 14.84 - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
(2) Overall social capital (Team) 2.71 2.51 0.04 - - - - - - - - - - - - -
(3) Overall social capital (Interviewee) 2.30 2.32 0.05 0.91* - - - - - - - - - - - -
(4) Any social capital (Team) 0.73 0.45 -0.10 0.66* 0.60* - - - - - - - - - - -
(5) Any social capital (Interviewee) 0.68 0.47 -0.06 0.66* 0.69* 0.89* - - - - - - - - - -
(6) Weak ties (Interviewee) 1.74 2.12 0.04 0.78* 0.84 0.50* 0.57* - - - - - - - - -
(7) Strong ties (Interviewee) 0.80 1.46 0.03 0.50* 0.61* 0.34 0.38* 0.08 - - - - - - - -
(8) Knowing other managers and business owners 0.61 0.49 -0.01 0.41* 0.41* 0.33 0.36* 0.33 * 0.26* - - - - - - -
(9) Encouragement and social support 0.52 0.50 0.10 0.36* 0.35* 0.24* 0.24* 0.30 * 0.20* 0.34*
(10) Public advice 0.44 0.50 -0.07 0.10 0.13* 0.13 0.14* 0.12 0.07 -0.00 -0.00 - - - - - - -
(11) Number of team members 2.77 0.90 -0.03 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.07 0.07 -0.02 0.07 0.05 0.05 - - - - - -
(12) Variety of functional background 4.33 1.64 0.14* 0.04 0.04 -0.07 -0.04 0.01 0.07 0.04 -0.12 -0.12 0.11 - - - - -
(13) Leadership experience 16.8117.74 0.07 0.08 0.12 0.06 0.08 0.14 * 0.00 0.06 0.07 0.07 0.32* 0.32* - - - -
(14) Entrepreneurial experience 1.13 1.78 0.01 -0.01 -0.04 -0.04 -0.02 0.01 -0.08 -0.03 -0.14* -0.14* 0.28* 0.28* 0.39* - - -
(15) Service company 0.49 0.50 -0.05 -0.01 0.02 -0.03 -0.02 0.01 0.02 0.06 -0.05 -0.05 -0.15* -0.09 -0.03 -0.05 -
(16) Innovativeness 0.34 0.47 0.00 0.09 0.05 0.04 0.05 0.02 0.06 -0.03 0.09 0.03 0.16* 0.10 0.03 0.80 -0.15*
(17) Start-up capital 3.31 1.34 0.32* 0.04 0.04 -0.02 0.01 0.05 0.00 0.01 0.07 0.07 0.06 0.23* 0.18* 0.17* -0.13* 0.18 *
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
Table 6: Summary of results
Results
Hypotheses
All start-up
projects
Solo
entrepreneurs
Entrepreneurial
team
H1: Solo entrepreneurs and entrepreneurial
teams differ in social capital use
Supported
H2: Overall social capital positive for
performance
Not supported Not supported Not supported
H3: Strong ties positive for performance Not supported Not supported Not supported
H4: Weak ties positive for performance Not supported Supported Not supported
H5: Human capital variety moderating the
effect of overall social capital on performance
Not tested Not supported Supported
H6: Human capital variety moderating the
effect of weak ties on performance
Not tested Not supported Supported
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
40
References

Aldrich, H.E. & Martinez, M.A. (2001), Many are Called, but Few are Chosen: An
Evolutionary Persepctive for the Study of Entrepreneurship, in: Entrepreneurship
Theory and Practice, Vol. 25(4), 41-56.
Aldrich, H.E. & Ruef, M. (2006), Organizations Evolving, Second Edition, London,
Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications.
Anderson, A.R.; Park, J . & J ack, S. (2007), Entrepreneurial Social Capital: Conceptualizing
Social Capital in New High-tech Firms, in: International Small Business Journal, Vol.
25(3), 245-272.
Baker, T. & Nelson, R.E. (2005), Creation Something from Nothing: Ressource Construction
through Entrepreneurial Bricolage, in: Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 50(3),
329-366.
Batjargal, B. (2007), Internet Entrepreneurship: Social Capital, Human Capital and
Performance of Internet Ventures in China, in: Research Policy, Vol. 36(5), 605-618.
Baum, J .A.C.; Calabrese, T. & Silverman, B.S. (2000), Don’t go it Alone: Allicance Network
Composition and Startups’ Performance in Canadian Biotechnology, in: Strategic
Management Journal, Vol. 21(3), 267-294.
Baum, J .R.; Locke, E.A. & Smith, K.G. (2001), A Multidimensional Model of Venture
Growth, in: Academy of Management Journal, Vol. 44(2), 292-303.
Belli, R.F.; Lee, E.H.; Stafford, F.P. & Chou, C. (2004), Calendar and Question-List Survey
Methods: Association between Interviewer Behaviors and Data Quality, in: Journal of
Official Statistics, Vol. 20(2), 185-218.
Belli, R.F.; Shay, W.L. & Stafford, F.P. (2001), Event history calendars and question list
surveys, in: Public Opinion Quarterly, Vol. 65(1), 45-74.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
41
Bhave, M.P. (1994), A Process Model of Entrepreneurial Venture Creation, in: Journal of
Business Venturing, Vol. 9(3), 223-242.
Bourdieu, P. (1986), The Forms of Capital, in: Richardson, J .G. (eds.), Handbook of Theory
and Research for Sociology of Education, New York: Greenwood Press, 241-258.
Bourgeon, L. (2007), Staffing Approach and Conditions for Collective Learning in Project
Teams: The Case of New Product Development Projects, in: International Journal of
Project Management, Vol. 25(4), 413-422.
Bunnis, S. & Kelly, D.R. (2008), The Unknown becomes the Known‘: Collective Learning
and Change in Primary Care Teams, in: Medical Education, Vol. 42(12), 1185-1194.
Burt, R. (1992), Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competitions, Harvard University
Press, Cambridge, Mass.
Burt, R.S. (2000), The Network Structure of Social Capital, in: Sutton, R.I.; Staw, B.M.
(eds.), Research in Organizational Behavior, Greenwich: J AI Press, Vol. 22, 345-423.
Caspi, A.; Moffitt, T.E.; Thornton, A.; Freedman, D.; Amell, J .W.; Harrington, H.; Smeijers,
J . & Silva, Phil A. (1996), The Life History Calendar: A Research and Clinical
Assessment Method for Collecting Retrospective Event-History Data, in: International
Journal of Methods in Psychiatric Research, Vol. 6, 101-114.
Chandler, G.N.; Honig, B. & Wiklund, J . (2005), Antecedents, Moderators and Performance
Consequences of Membership Change in New Venture Teams, in: Journal of Business
Venturing, Vol. 20(5), 705-725.
Chowdhurry, S. (2005), Demographic Diversity for Building an Effective Entrepreneurial
Team: Is it Important?, in: Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 20(6), 727-746.
Cohen, W.M. & Levinthal, D.A. (1990), Absorptive Capacity: A New Perspective on
Learning and Innovation, in: Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 35(1), 128-152.
Coleman, J .S. (1988), Social Capital in the Creation of Human Capital, in: American Journal
of Sociology, Vol. 94 (Supplement: Organizations and Institutions), 95-120.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
42
Colombo, M.G. & Grilli, L. (2005), Founders’ Human Capital and the Growth of New
Technology-based Firms: A Competence-based view, in: Research Policy, Vol. 34(6),
795-816.
Cooper, A.C. & Bruno, A.V. (1977), Success among High-Technology Firms, in: Business
Horizons, Vol. 20(2), 16-22.
Cooper, A.C.; Gimeno-Gascon, F.J . & Woo, C.Y. (1994), Initial Human and Financial Capital
as Predictors of New Venture Performance, in: Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 9(5),
371-395.
Creditreform & Bureau van Dijk (2009), MARKUS database, retrieved J anuary 10, 2009,
from www.creditreform.de/Deutsch/Creditreform/Produkte_und_Leistungen/
Direktmarketing/Business_Marketing/MARKUS_Firmenprofile.jsp.
Davidsson, P. (2006), Nascent Entrepreneurship: Empirical Studies and Developments, in:
Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, Vol. 2(1), 1-79.
Davidsson, P. & Honig, B. (2003), The Role of Social and Human Capital among Nascent
Entrepreneurs, in: Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 18(3), 301–331.
Davidsson, P. & Wiklund, J . (2001), Levels of Analysis in Entrepreneurship Research:
Current Research Practice and Suggestions for the Future, in: Entrepreneurship Theory
and Practice, Vol. 25(4), 81-100.
Delmar, F. & Gunnarsson, J . (2000), How Do Self-Employed Parents of Nascent
Entrepreneurs Contribute?, in: Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research, Wellesley:
Babson.
Eisenhardt, K. & Schoonhoven, C.B. (1990), Organizational Growth: Linking Founding
Team, Strategy, Environment and Growth Among U.S. Semiconductor Ventures, 1978-
1988, in: Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 35(3), 504-529.
Elfring, T. & Hulsink, W. (2003), Networks in Entrepreneurship: The Case of High-
technology Firms, in: Small Business Economics, Vol. 21(4), 409-422.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
43
Ensley, M.D. & Pearce, C.L. (2001), Shared Cognition in Top Management Teams:
Implications for New Venture Performance, in: Journal of Organizational Behavior,
Vol. 22(2), 145-160.
Florin, J .; Lubatkin, M. & Schulze, W. (2003), A Social Capital Model of High-Growth
Ventures, in: Academy of Management Journal, Vol. 46(3), 374-384.
Freedman, D.; Thornton, A.; Camburn, D.; Alwin, D. & Young-DeMarco, L. (1988), The Life
History Calender: A Technique for Collecting Retrospective Data, in: Sociological
Methodology, Vol. 18, 37-68.
Fritsch, M. (2004), Entrepreneurship, Entry, and Peformance of New Businesses in Two
Growth Regimes: East and West Germany, in: Journal of Evolutionary Economics, Vol.
14(5), 525-542.
Fritsch, M. & Mueller, P. (2004), Effects of New Business Formation on Regional
Development over Time, in: Regional Studies, Vol. 38(8), 961-975.
Gartner, W.B. (1985), A Conceptual Framework for Describing the Phenomenon of New
Venture Creation, in: Academy of Management Review, Vol. 10(4), 696-706.
Gartner, W.B. (1988), “Who is an Entrepreneur?” Is the Wrong Question, in:
Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 12(4), 11-32.
Granovetter, M.S. (1990), The Old and The New Economic Sociology: A History and an
Agenda, in: Friedland, R. & Robertson, A. (eds.), Beyond the Market Place: Rethinking
Economy and Society, New York: Walter de Gruyter, 89-112.
Granovetter, M.S. (1973), The Strength of Weak Ties, in: American Journal of Sociology,
Vol. 78(6), 1360-1380.
Grupp, H. & Legler, H. (2000), Hochtechnologie 2000: Neudefinition der Hochtechnologie
für die Berichterstattung der technologischen Leistungsfähigkeit Deutschlands,
Karlsruhe/Hannover: Fraunhofer-Institut für Systemtechnik und Innovationsforschung
(ISI) und Niedersächsisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung (NIW).
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
44
Hayton, J .C. & Zahra, S.A. (2005), Venture Team Human Capital and Absorptive Capacity in
High Technology New Ventures, in: International Journal of Technology Management,
Vol. 31(3/4), 256-274.
Honig, B.; Lerner, M. & Raban, J . (2006), Social Capital and the Linkages of High-Tech
Companies to the Military Defense System: Is there a Signaling Mechanism, in: Small
Business Economics, Vol. 27(4-5), 419-437.
Kamm, J .B.; Schuman, J .C.; Seeger, J .A. & Nurick, A.J . (1990), Entrepreneurial Teams in
New Venture Creation: A Research Agenda, in: Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice,
Vol. 14(4), 7-17.
Kim, P.H. & Aldrich, H.E. (2005), Social Capital and Entrepreneurship, in: Foundations and
Trends in Entrepreneurship, Vol. 1(2), 55-104.
Lechler, T. (2001), Social Interaction: A Determinant of Entrepreneurial Team Venture
Success, in: Small Business Economics, Vol. 16(4), 263-278.
Lechner, C. & Dowling, M. (2003), Firm Networks: External Relationships as Sources for the
Growth and Competitiveness of Entrepreneurial Firms, in: Entrepreneurship & Regional
Development, Vol. 15(1), 1-26.
Liao, J . & Welsch, H. (2005), Roles of Social Capital in Venture Creation: Key Dimensions
and Research Implications, in: Journal of Small Business Management, Vol. 43(4), 345-
362.
Liao, J . & Welsch, H. (2003), Social Capital and Entrepreneurial Growth Aspirations: A
Comparison of Technology- and Non-technology-based Nascent Entrepreneurs, in:
Journal of High Technology Management Research, Vol. 14(1), 149-170.
Lin, N. & Dumin, M. (1986), Access to Occupations Through Social Ties, in: Social
Networks, Vol. 8(4), 365-385.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
45
Lumpkin, G.T., & Dess, G.G. (2001), Linking two dimensions of entrepreneurial orientation
to firm performance: The moderating role of environment and industry life cycle, in:
Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 16(5), 429-451.
Marsden, P.V. & Campbell, K.E. (1984), Measuring Tie Strength, in: Social Forces, Vol.
64(2), 482-501.
McCallister, L. & Fischer, C.S. (1978), A Procedure for Surveying Personal Networks, in:
Sociological Methods and Research, 7(2), 415-444.
Nahapiet, J . & Goshal, S. (1998), Social Capital, Intellectual Capital, and the Organizational
Advantage, in: The Academy of Management Review, Vol. 23(2), 242-266.
Politis, D. (2005), The Process of Entrepreneurial Learning: A Conceptual Framework, in:
Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 29(4), 399-424.
Presutti, M.; Boari, C. & Fratocchi, L. (2007), Knowledge Acquisition and the Foreign
Development of High-tech Start-ups: A Social Capital Approach, in: International
Business Review, Vol. 16(1), 23-46.
Renzulli, L.A. & Aldrich, H.E. (2005), Who Can You Turn to? Tie Activation within Core
Business Discussion Networks, in: Social Forces, Vol. 84(1), 323-341.
Ronstadt, R. (1988), The Corridor Principle, in: Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 3(1), 31-
40.
Samuelsson, M. & Davidsson, P. (2009), Does Venture Opportunity Variation Matter?
Investigating Systematic Differences Between Innovative and Imitative new Ventures,
in: Small Business Economics, Vol. 33(2), 229-255.
Schumpeter, J .A. (1934), The Theory of Economic Development, Cambridge: Harvard
University Press First published in German, 1912.
Shane, S.A. & Cable, D. (2002), Network Ties, Reputation, and the Financing of New
Ventures, in: Management Science, Vol. 48(3), 364-381.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
46
Shane, S.A. & Venkataraman, S. (2000), The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of
Research, in: Academy of Management Review, Vol. 25(1), 217–226.
Shepherd, D.A. & Krueger, N.F. (2002), An Intentions-Based Model of Entrepreneurial
Teams’ Social Cognition, in: Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 27(2), 167-
185.
Shepherd, D.A.; Douglas, E.J . & Shanley, M. (2000), New Venture Survival: Ignorance,
External Shocks, and Risk Reduction Strategies, in: Journal of Business Venturing, Vol.
15(5-6), 393-410.
Stam, E. & Schutjens, V. (2006), The Fragile Success of Team Startups, in: Groen, A.;
Oakey, R.P.; Sijde, P. van der; Kauser, S. (eds.): New Technology-based Firms in the
New Millennium, 5
th
Edition, Amsterdam, Elsevier, 219-233.
Teece, David J .; Pisano, G. & Shuen, A. (1997), Dynamic Capabilities and Strategic
Management, in: Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 18(7), 509-533.
Uzzi, B. (1997), Social Structure and Competition in Interfirm Networks: The Paradox of
Embeddedness, in: Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 42(1), 35-47.
Van der Gaag, M.P.J . & Snijders, T.A.B. (2005), The Resource Generator: Social Capital
Quantification with Concrete Items, in: Social Networks, Vol. 27(1), 1-29.
Van der Gaag, M.P.J . & Snijders, T.A.B. (2004), Proposals for the Measurement of individual
Social Capital, in: Flap, H., Völker, B. (eds.), Creation and Returns of Social Capital,
London: Routledge, 199-218.
Van der Vegt, G.S. & Bunderson, J .S. (2005), Learning and performance in Multidisciplinary
Temas: The Importance of Collective Team Identification, in: Academy of Management
Journal, Vol. 48(3), 532-547.
Van Gelderen, M.; Thurik, R. & Bosma, N. (2005), Success and Risk Factors in the Pre-
Startup Phase, in: Small Business Economics, Vol. 24(4), 365-380.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012
47
Vivarelli, M. (2004), Are All the Potential Entrepreneurs So Good?, in: Small Business
Economics, Vol. 23(1), 41-49.
Weick, K.E. & Roberts, K.H. (1993), Collective Mind in Organizations: Heedful Interrelating
on Flight Decks, in: Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 38(3), 357-381
West, G.P. III (2007), Collective Cognition: When Entrepeneurial Teams, Not Individuals,
Make Decisions, in: Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 31(1), 77-102.
Yli-Renko, H.; Erkko, A. & Sapienza, H.J . (2001), Social Capital, Knowledge Acquisition
and Knowledge Exploitation in Young Technology-Based Firms, in: Strategic
Management Journal, Vol. 22(6-7), 587-613.
Zahra, S.A.; Sapienza, H.J . & Davidsson, P. (2006), Entrepreneurship and Dynamic
Capabilities: A Review, Model and Research Agenda, in: Journal of Management
Studies, Vol. 43(4), 917-955.
Jena Economic Research Papers 2010 - 012

doc_972908018.pdf
 

Attachments

Back
Top