Study Reports On Effects Of Performance Schedules On Event Ticket Sales

Description
A performance, in performing arts, generally comprises an event in which a performer or group of performers behave in a particular way for another group of people, the audience. Choral music and ballet are examples. Usually the performers participate in rehearsals beforehand. Afterwards audience members often applaud.

STUDY REPORTS ON EFFECTS OF
PERFORMANCE SCHEDULES ON
EVENT TICKET SALES

ABSTRACT
Event scheduling is one of many important decisions facing event marketers

in the entertainment industry (i.e., how should multiple performances be scheduled

across markets, across venues, and over time?). While there is ample research

examining the issues of costs and constraints associated with such a decision,

virtually no research exists to examine the impact of these decisions on consumer

demand. Hence, the objective of this dissertation is to examine how consumers

respond to event marketers' scheduling decisions.

First, a scheduling effect may arise from performances within a market.

When performances are scheduled closely in distance or time, their similarity in

venue locations or performance dates may result in a stronger relationship and

influence ticket sales. This relationship may have a positive effect on ticket sales

because the similarity could signal the quality of an event and suggest the desirability

of these performances. Thus, these performances attract more consumers and sell

more tickets. However, the relationship could be negative. When performances are




close in distance or time, they become direct substitutes and compete for consumer

patronage.

Another effect arises from an event distribution across markets. When an

event travels from one market to another and each market has a different performance

schedule, the word of mouth of this event may accumulate and carry over to later

markets. If so, market sales may be a good proxy of word of mouth. How well (or

poorly) an event sells in preceding markets may affect ticket sales in following

markets.

This dissertation consists of three essays to examine the abovementioned

scheduling effects. We contact a national ticket seller to acquire a dataset containing

ticket sales of a family event traveling across 42 markets. The first essay analyzes a

performance schedule in one metropolitan market and investigates the scheduling

effect on ticket sales. The second essay employs all performance schedules in 42

markets to study heterogeneous market responses and propose explanatory factors.

Finally, the third essay incorporates the distribution sequence of this event and

examines whether ticket sales in preceding markets have a carryover effect to

influence ticket sales in later markets.




















































Table of Contents




Table of Contents..........................................................................................................
ii List of Tables
.................................................................................................................v List of Figures
.............................................................................................................. vi 1 Introduction
............................................................................................................1
2 Essay 1: Scheduling to Sell: Examining the Impact of a Performance Schedule
on Event Ticket Sales.....................................................................................................8
2.1 Introduction ....................................................................................................
8 2.2 Literature Review and Conceptual Framework ...........................................
15
2.2.1 Airline and Movie Scheduling ..............................................................
15 2.2.2 Event Tickets ........................................................................................
17 2.2.3 Impact of Scheduling on Ticket Sales ..................................................
21 2.2.4 Conceptual Framework.........................................................................
25
2.3 Model Development..................................................................................... 28
2.3.1 Model Overview ...................................................................................
28 2.3.2 Scheduling Characteristics....................................................................
29 2.3.3 Number of Ticket Sales ........................................................................
30 2.3.4 Timing of Ticket Sales..........................................................................
34 2.3.5 Endogeneity in Performance Scheduling..............................................
38
2.4 Data Description........................................................................................... 39
2.4.1 Description of Events............................................................................
40 2.4.2 Description of Ticket Sales...................................................................
41 2.4.3 Covariate Specifications .......................................................................
44
2.5 Model Estimation and Benchmark Comparison .......................................... 46
2.5.1 Estimation .............................................................................................
46 2.5.2 Benchmark Comparison........................................................................
47
2.6 Results .......................................................................................................... 49
2.6.1 Number of Ticket Sales ........................................................................
49 2.6.2 Timing of Ticket Sales..........................................................................
51 2.6.3 Endogeneity in Performance Scheduling..............................................
53
2.7 Policy Simulation ......................................................................................... 54
2.7.1 Scenario 1: Geographic Change............................................................
54 2.7.2 Scenario 2: Temporal Changes .............................................................
55
2.8 Conclusions .................................................................................................. 56
2.8.1 Summary ...............................................................................................
56 2.8.2 Limitations and Next Steps...................................................................
57
Table and Figures .................................................................................................... 58
3 Essay 2: Heterogeneous Market Responses to Performance Schedules and Their
Explanatory Factors .....................................................................................................78
3.1 Introduction ..................................................................................................
78 3.2 Preliminary Analysis ....................................................................................
82 3.3 Literature Review and Conceptual Framework ...........................................
84
ii

3.3.1 Literature Review.................................................................................. 84
3.3.2 Conceptual Framework......................................................................... 85
3.4 Model Development..................................................................................... 88
3.4.1 Model Overview ...................................................................................
88 3.4.2 Scheduling Characteristics and the Number of Ticket Sales ................
88 3.4.3 Endogeneity in Performance Scheduling..............................................
89 3.4.4 Use of the HB Approach for Response Heterogeneity .........................
90
3.5 Data .............................................................................................................. 90
3.5.1 Definition of Markets............................................................................
91 3.5.2 Description of Performance Schedules across Markets........................
92 3.5.3 Covariate Specifications .......................................................................
94
3.6 Model Estimation and Benchmark Comparison .......................................... 97
3.6.1 Estimation .............................................................................................
97 3.6.2 Benchmark Comparison........................................................................
98
3.7 Results .......................................................................................................... 99
3.7.1 Heterogeneous Market Responses to Performance Schedules .............
99 3.7.2 Explanatory Factors for Market Heterogeneity ....................................
99 3.7.3 Endogenous Scheduling Decision.......................................................
101
3.8 Conclusions ................................................................................................ 101
3.8.1 Summary .............................................................................................
101 3.8.2 Limitations and Next Steps.................................................................
103
Tables and Figures ................................................................................................
104 4 Essay 3: Sequential Distribution of a Live Performance Event
.........................117
4.1 Introduction ................................................................................................
117 4.2 Literature Review and Conceptual Framework .........................................
121
4.2.1 Sequential Distribution .......................................................................
121 4.2.2 Conceptual Framework.......................................................................
125
4.3 Model Development................................................................................... 128
4.3.1 Overview.............................................................................................
128 4.3.2 Demand Equation: Market Sales ........................................................
129 4.3.3 Supply Equations: Overall Supply, Venue Usage, and Day Usage....
130 4.3.4 Variable Specifications .......................................................................
131 4.3.5 Model Summary..................................................................................
138
4.4 Data ............................................................................................................ 139
4.4.1 Touring Sequence ...............................................................................
140 4.4.2 Covariates in the Demand Model .......................................................
141 4.4.3 Covariates in the Supply Model..........................................................
144
4.5 Estimation and Results ............................................................................... 146
4.5.1 Model Estimation................................................................................
146 4.5.2 Results of Demand Equation ..............................................................
147 4.5.3 Results of Supply Equations ...............................................................
149 4.5.4 Correlated Demand and Supply ..........................................................
150
4.6 Conclusions ................................................................................................ 150
4.6.1 Summary .............................................................................................
150 4.6.2 Conclusion ..........................................................................................
151
Tables and Figures ................................................................................................ 153


iii

5 Conclusion..........................................................................................................165
5.1 Summary ....................................................................................................
165 5.2 General Discussions ...................................................................................
168 5.3 Contributions..............................................................................................
170 5.4 Limitation and Future Research .................................................................
170
Reference ...................................................................................................................172














































iv

List of Tables




Table 2-1: Description of Data Fields.........................................................................
58 Table 2-2: Summary of Ticket Sales ..........................................................................
59 Table 2-3: Descriptive Statistics of Covariates...........................................................
60 Table 2-4: Benchmark Models and Model Fit............................................................
61 Table 2-5: Results for the Number of Ticket Sales ....................................................
62 Table 2-6: Results for the Timing of Ticket Sales......................................................
63 Table 2-7: Results for Endogenous Performance Scheduling ....................................
64 Table 3-1: Summary of DMA markets .....................................................................
104 Table 3-2: Summary of Market Responses to Performance Schedules....................
105 Table 3-3: Venue Locations and their Associated DMAs ........................................
106 Table 3-4: Summary of Ticket Sales ........................................................................
107 Table 3-5: Descriptive Statistics of Covariates across Markets................................
108 Table 3-6: Descriptive Statistics of Market Characteristics .....................................
109 Table 3-7: Descriptive Statistics of Additional Scheduling Characteristics.............
110 Table 3-8: Sources of Heterogeneous Market Responses.........................................
111 Table 3-9: Results of Performance Schedule Model ................................................
112 Table 4-1: Descriptive Statistics of Covariates (in the log term)..............................
153 Table 4-2: Correlation Coefficient of Demand Covariates.......................................
154 Table 4-3: Correlation Coefficient of Dependent Variables.....................................
155 Table 4-4: Results of the Demand Model .................................................................
156 Table 4-5: Results of the Supply Model ...................................................................
157 Table 4-6: Correlation between Supply and Demand Models..................................
158





















v

List of Figures




Figure 2-1: Conceptual Framework of Spatial Decomposition ..................................
65 Figure 2-2: Model Overview ......................................................................................
66 Figure 2-3: Probability of Ticket Sales over Time .....................................................
67 Figure 2-4: Sales Distribution by Performances.........................................................
68 Figure 2-5: Sales Distribution by Days of Week ........................................................
69 Figure 2-6: Weekly Sales Pattern of a Performance...................................................
70 Figure 2-7: Heterogeneity in Sales Pattern Across Performances ..............................
71 Figure 2-8: Venue Locations and Driving Distances..................................................
72 Figure 2-9: Summary of Geographic Distance ...........................................................
73 Figure 2-10: Summary of Temporal Distance ............................................................
74 Figure 2-11: Impact of Geographic Density on Timing of Ticket Sales ....................
75 Figure 2-12: Effect of Schedule Changes on Ticket Sales .........................................
76 Figure 2-13: Effect of Schedule Changes on Timing of Ticket Sales ........................
77 Figure 3-1: Conceptual Framework of Heterogeneous Market Responses ..............
113 Figure 3-2: Example of a DMA and its county information.....................................
114 Figure 3-3: Locations of DMA Markets and Performing Sequence.........................
115 Figure 3-4: Heterogeneous Market Responses .........................................................
116 Figure 4-1: Conceptual Framework ..........................................................................
159 Figure 4-2: Illustration of Market Connectedness ....................................................
160 Figure 4-3: Overview of Model Development..........................................................
161 Figure 4-4: Venue Locations ....................................................................................
162 Figure 4-5: Touring Dates across Markets................................................................
163 Figure 4-6: Capacity-Filled Rate across Markets .....................................................
164




















vi

1 Introduction




Scheduling is one of many important decisions facing event marketers in the

entertainment industry. To maximize revenues in a national market, event marketers have to not

only make marketing mix decisions but also schedule performances across markets, across

venues, and over time. Hence, these scheduling decisions result in a performance schedule

within a market or across a national market for an event to perform in different venues and on

various days. In this dissertation, we define a performance schedule as a summary of

performances taking places in various venue locations and on different dates to examine

potential effects of this performance schedule on ticket sales at a performance level and across

markets.

Similar to airline and movie scheduling decisions, event marketers rely on costs and

constraints in their scheduling process. They need to comply with venue availability and seating

capacity to decide when to provide performances and how many performances to provide. They

can minimize the travel distance across markets if it is expensive to move from one market to

another. They can also shorten a performing period in a venue if the cost to rent a facility

outweighs the benefits of having performances for a long period.

While there is ample research examining the issues of costs and constraints associated

with such scheduling decisions, virtually no research exists to examine the impact of these

decisions on consumer demand. In other words, it is unclear to event marketers how consumers

in a market evaluate individual performances and how consumer inferences influence their

purchase decisions such as which performance to buy and when to buy. Hence, at the





1

performance level, consumers' evaluations about performances in a schedule may affect the

number of ticket sales of these performances and the pattern of these ticket sales over time.

It is important for event marketers to understand potential drivers for the number of ticket

sales sold and the pattern of these ticket sales over time. Once they know the effects of these

drivers, they will be able to estimate expected market demand and schedule performances

accordingly. In this way, they can avoid revenue losses from undersupply and minimizes costs

resulting from potential oversupply. Additionally, event ticket sales are often available for

purchases several months or weeks in advance, and these tickets are not sold at a constant rate

throughout the advance-selling period. If event marketers understand the drivers for the sales

rate, sales pattern can be easily established to monitor actual ticket sales over time and

potentially adjust the marketing strategy as the event approaches.

As such, this dissertation aims to investigate the impact of performance schedules on

ticket sales for a live performance event. Specifically, we propose two types of effects emerging

from the scheduling decisions. One type of effect is likely to exist among performances within a

market because of the way these performances are scheduled across venues and dates. For

example, performances scheduled closely in distance or time might signal the quality of an event,

the desirability of these venues or dates, or just the potential substitutes across venues or dates.

If consumers make any of these inferences and perceive performances to be more or less

favorable, the scheduling effect among performances within a market would influence how well

each performance sells and when ticket sales occur.

The other type of effect might develop across markets where an event performs one after

another. In other words, after an event performs in each market for a period, its word of mouth

may arise and cumulate over time. If the word of mouth travels across markets and consumers



2

have positive feedbacks, how well this event does in previous markets could influence ticket

sales in later markets. Because ticket sales in previous markets can capture the volume of word

of mouth to some extent, it is plausible to observe ticket sales in previous markets to affect sales

in later markets.

This dissertation consists of three essays to examine those possible scheduling effects

mentioned above. For this purpose, we acquired a dataset containing ticket sales of a family

event traveling across 42 markets. We start by characterizing a performance schedule in a single

market and investigating its impact on the number of ticket sales at a performance level and the

pattern of these ticket sales over time (i.e., essay one). From essay one, we conclude that

performances scheduled close to each other in terms of distance can experience more ticket sales,

and these tickets sell at a faster rate. On the other hand, performances scheduled close to each

other in terms of time tend to sell fewer tickets, but do not exhibit any significant changes in

their sale patterns. However, these results are established for one metropolitan market in our

dataset. Hence, we expand the level of analysis to all 42 markets in essay two to ensure

scheduling effects generalizable for this event and examine the heterogeneity across markets.

Essay two confirms consistent scheduling effects across markets and identifies explanatory

factors for the heterogeneity in effect sizes across markets. Finally, essay three proceeds to

investigate scheduling effects at a market level and examines whether an event performing

across markets affects ticket sales in these markets. Specifically, essay three reveals that markets

to which an event travels sell more tickets when event marketers disperse performance dates or

employ multiple venues in these markets. Additionally, these markets do not influence one

another on their ticket sales, but their venues within the same market have such an effect.

Although one may argue that the third essay does not have to be conducted after the first two



3

essays, we choose this sequence because we need to investigate the effect of a touring event

across markets after we can understand and control for the effect of a performance schedule

within a market.

The purpose of the first essay is to lay the foundation of this dissertation and to test

whether scheduling decisions influence ticket sales of performances within a market. We begin

by examining ticket sales at a performance level within a single market and differentiate between

performances based on a set of scheduling characteristics. We derive a set of scheduling

characteristics based on the venue locations and performance dates. According to these

scheduling characteristics, we measure how closely performances are scheduled in terms of

distance or time. A performance of a shorter geographic or temporal distance hence indicates its

similarity in venue location or performance date to other performances.

After examining ticket sales of these performances as a function of their distance

measures, we find that geographic and temporal distances between performances have different

effects on ticket sales. More specifically, a shorter geographic distance between performances

leads to more tickets sold and a faster sales rate for a performance. However, a shorter temporal

distance between performances just causes decreases in the number of ticket sales but does not

influence how fast tickets are sold.

Although it is not clear why consumers process geographic and temporal distances

differently, it is clear that they refer to the way performances are scheduled as a means to make

inferences about these performances. Their inferences about performances of a shorter

geographic distance could be regarding the quality of an event, the desirability of their associated

venues, or others. As a result, these performances sell more tickets and attract consumers to

purchase tickets early. On the other hand, their inferences about performances of a shorter



4

temporal distance could be the high substitutability within a shorter period. Therefore, these

performances compete for consumer patronage and suffer from sales cannibalization.

While the first essay demonstrates the significant effects of geographic and temporal

distances on ticket sales, the results are for one market only. Yet, event marketers often need to

make scheduling decisions for more than one market. It is not clear whether the results in this

first essay are consistent across markets. For this reason, the objective of the second essay is to

use all performance schedules of the same event to investigate heterogeneous market responses

and identify explanatory factors.

To achieve this objective, we follow the same approach as in essay one and analyze all

performance schedules. For performances within their associated market, we characterize them

by their venue locations and performance dates and compute their geographic and temporal

distances to other performances. Then, for each market, we model ticket sales of performances

as a function of their distance measures to understand whether the heterogeneity exists in market

responses. We then model these market specific parameters as a function of their market

characteristics such as market population and additional scheduling characteristics such as travel

sequence along the distribution to explain any differences across markets.

Our results show that market responses to performance schedules are heterogeneous and

can be explained by market and additional scheduling characteristics. Specifically, when a

market has a bigger population, the effects of days of week and baseline attractiveness are

attenuated. Moreover, after an event travels to more markets that are geographically adjacent to

a focal market, the focal market is less responsive to its baseline attractiveness and temporal

schedule. Finally, a current market in a late distribution sequence tends to respond more

favorably to a Sunday performance.



5

Results in essay two hence suggest a possibility that markets where an event travels one

after another may be dependent. In other words, how following markets respond to their

temporal schedule depends on how many geographically adjacent markets an event has visited.

Another possibility is that there may be another means of integrating participating markets along

a touring event such that ticket sales of preceding markets might directly influence ticket sales of

following markets (rather than through the response parameters and geographically adjacent

markets). If so, it is important to incorporate the temporal sequence in an event distribution and

study the impact of preceding markets on following ones.

The primary objective of essay three, therefore, is to examine the impact of a sequentially

distributed event across markets. Additionally, we consider the endogeneity between supply and

demand for an event in case expected market demand influences event marketers' scheduling

decisions and their schedule further affect ticket sales in a market.

To achieve this objective, we model the supply and demand for an event simultaneously.

We model ticket sales of each market as a function of its performance schedule and the

sequential distribution of this event. In addition to modeling the supply and demand

simultaneously to account for the endogeneity, we use three variables to present the scheduling

influences on market demand and employ the spatially weighted approach to incorporate

different release timing and ticket sales of preceding markets in an event tour.

Our results show that a market experiences more ticket sales when event marketers

disperse performance dates or book multiple venues in this market. Moreover, we show that the

sequentially distributed event has an effect on ticket sales. However, this effect is significant

across venues of the same market but not across markets. When an event performs in more than





6

one venue, its ticket sales in a preceding venue carry over to a later venue and influence its

overall market sales.

The organization of this dissertation is as follows. Chapter 1 introduces the issues of

scheduling facing event marketers and presents a general overview of each essay. Chapters 2, 3,

and 4 discuss the three essays, respectively, in depth. Finally, Chapter 5 provides a brief

summary of each essay, integrates essential results, and points out limitations and future

directions to conclude this dissertation.








































7

2 Essay 1: Scheduling to Sell: Examining the Impact of a Performance


Schedule on Event Ticket Sales




2.1 Introduction

Scheduling is one of many important decisions facing event marketers in the

entertainment industry. Besides decisions regarding marketing activities (e.g., pricing and

promotions), event marketers have to schedule performances across markets, across venues, and

over time. Typically, they rely on costs and constraints in their scheduling process (Etschmaier

and Mathaisel 1985; Lohatepanont and Barnhart 2004; Eliashberg et al 2007) and use pricing,

advertising, and days of week to describe how well an event can sell (Weinberg and Shachmut

1978; Putler and Lele 2003; Leslie 2004) or when ticket sales occur (Moe and Fader 2009).

While there is ample research examining the issues of costs and constraints associated

with such scheduling decisions, virtually no research exists to examine the impact of these

decisions on consumer demand. In other words, it is unclear to event marketers how consumers

in a market may evaluate a performance schedule of an event and how consumer inferences

influence their purchase decisions such as which performance to buy and when to buy. Hence, at

the performance level, consumers' evaluations about performances in a schedule may affect the

number of ticket sales of these performances and the pattern of these ticket sales over time.

From event marketers' perspective, they need to understand potential drivers for ticket

sales in terms of the number of ticket sales and the pattern of these ticket sales over time. Once

they know how these drivers influence market demand, they can estimate expected market

demand accordingly and schedule performances to meet this market demand. In this way, they





8

can avoid revenue losses from undersupply and prevent decreases in profitability due to

oversupply.

On the other hand, event ticket sales are often available for purchases several months or

weeks in advance, and these ticket sales do not occur at a constant rate throughout an entire

advance-selling period. If event marketers understand drivers for tickets selling at a different

rate, they can portray the sales pattern as a benchmark and monitor actual ticket sales over time.

Consequently, once event marketers find an actual pattern deviating from the benchmark, they

can take actions in time.

In general, scheduling decisions affect the maximum number of tickets that an event can

sell. When event marketers schedule a live performance event, they often allocate multiple

performances across markets, across venues, and over time. Although the number of

performances and the capacities of chosen venues constrain the maximum number of tickets an

event can sell, empirical evidence shows that it is rare for the demand to exceed supply in this

industry. Therefore, one possible impact of scheduling decisions is to constrain the maximum

possible of ticket sales for an event although the supply is usually well beyond the actual demand.

Scheduling decisions might also influence consumer responses in a market. In other

words, when consumers realize performances are scheduled in various venue locations and on

different dates, they may try to rationalize why event marketers schedule performances in this

way and then make inferences about these performances. If so, consumers could formulate

different preferences for these performances to choose one performance to attend and purchase

tickets at their desired time. At a performance level, consumer responses influence how well

individual performances sell and when ticket sales of these performances occur.





9

Therefore, the objective of this essay examines the effects of scheduling characteristics of

performances on ticket sales. Specifically, we use venue locations and performance dates as the

scheduling characteristics of each performance, and we investigate whether performances

scheduled closely in distance or time experience a different number and timing of ticket sales.

We define the timing of ticket sales as tickets sold at different times in an advance-selling

period, and earlier or later timing of ticket sales suggests ticket sales occurred in the earlier or

later advance-selling period. In other words, if scheduling characteristics have an effect,

performances scheduled close in distance or time would experience more (or fewer) ticket sales.

Their ticket sales would occur earlier (or later) than those scheduled farther apart in an advance-

selling period, ceteris paribus.

One possible effect is to see performances scheduled close in distance or time

experiencing more ticket sales and earlier timing of sales than those scheduled farther apart. For

example, if event marketers want to signal the desirability of some venue locations or

performance dates, they could allocate more performances to those specific venues or dates. In

this way, consumers would perceive performances scheduled close in distance or time to be more

attractive (due to the similar scheduling characteristics) and assign higher utilities to these

performances. As a result, these performances could sell more tickets and experience earlier

timing of sales than other performances.

Another possible effect is to observe performances scheduled farther apart in distance or

time experiencing more ticket sales and earlier timing of sales than those scheduled nearby. In

other words, when consumers have higher uncertainty about whether they can attend an event in

a particular venue at a specific time, event marketers could sparsely allocate performances across

venues and dates. In this way, consumers have more alternatives and higher flexibility regarding



10

when and where to attend. Hence, the chance for them to attend this event increases, and

performances scheduled farther apart will be able to sell more tickets and experience earlier

timing of sales. In contrast, performances scheduled nearby merely substitute one another within

certain venues or dates. Consumers do not have to decide which performance they want to buy

and can delay their purchase timing. Hence, these closely scheduled performances compete

against consumer patronage and cannibalize ticket sales. To sum up, scheduling characteristics

might have two possible but contradictory effects on ticket sales. We allow both possibilities

and examine the effects of scheduling characteristics empirically.

Our modeling objective is to measure the scheduling characteristics of each performance

and study the impact of these scheduling characteristics on the number and timing of ticket sales.

We consider the possibility that consumers evaluate venue locations and performance dates

differently. Thus, we differentiate the effect of scheduling across venues from the effect of

scheduling across dates and then investigate these separately effects. Specifically, we refer to the

previous effect as the effect of geographic scheduling or the effect of a geographic schedule and

the later effect as the effect of temporal scheduling or the effect of a temporal schedule.

First, to measure the scheduling characteristics of performances, we characterize each

performance in a schedule of an event by its venue location and performance date. Then, we

compute the geographic and temporal distances between performances to understand how

closely (or distantly) performances are scheduled across venues and dates. For example,

performances of a shorter geographic or temporal distance to others are relatively closer to other

performances than performances of a longer geographic or temporal distance.

Second, to examine the number of ticket sales across performances, we consider the

possibility that some consumers might evaluate the venue locations and performance dates in a



11

schedule but eventually do not attend. To account for consumers who make purchases and those

who miss out the opportunity to attend, we specify the number of ticket sales in the form of sales

share within a potential target market. Then, we examine the share of each performance and the

non-buyer segment within this potential market. We extend the competing destination model

proposed by Fotheringham (1988) and model the share of each performance and the non-buyer

segment as a function of the geographic and temporal distances between performances. By

doing so, we can understand whether scheduling characteristics influence ticket sales at a

performance level. In addition, using sales shares of individual performances and the population

size in a target market as the number of potential buyers, we can obtain the number of ticket

sales at a performance level. We can also obtain a market penetration rate by taking the sum of

sales shares across performances.

Third, to examine the timing of ticket sales across performances, we first consider a

general pattern of ticket sales for a performance. That is, a performance sells fewer tickets in the

beginning of its advance-selling period and obtains more sales over time with the most arriving

in the later period or the week of the performance. Although this is a general pattern over time,

each performance still has a different sales rate. Some performances experience ticket sales

occurred early (i.e., earlier timing of ticket sales) but others experience ticket sales arrived later

(i.e., later timing of ticket sales). To account for variations in sales rate across performances, we

employ a Weibull hazard model to capture the timing of sales over time for individual

performances. We further model the sales rate of each performance as a function of its

geographic and temporal distances to other performances to understand whether these scheduling

characteristics explain the heterogeneity in sales rate.





12

Finally, we consider a possible endogeneity in scheduling decisions. Since the live

performance industry has been established and event marketers have scheduled for a variety of

events, event marketers may have incorporated their experiences into a scheduling process. If so,

a performance schedule is endogenously determined. For example, event marketers might have

scheduled more performances on weekends across all venues because they know these

performances have higher performance attractiveness. It is also likely that they have scheduled

performances based on the responses they expect in this market. Specifically, they may have

scheduled performances closely in distance or time or farther apart, because they know

consumers prefer performances of such scheduling characteristics. In case such an endogeneity

exists in the scheduling process, we control for this possibility in our model development.

We contact a national ticket seller to obtain a dataset of a live performance event and use

its ticket sales to examine the impact of its scheduling characteristics on ticket sales. Although

this event performed across several markets, we use the performances in the New York

metropolitan market as a subset. The reason is that performances scheduled in this market have

richer variations in venue locations and performance dates. In short, this event had 70

performances across four venues in the New York metropolitan market and performed between

March and June 2004.

Our results indicate that the effect of geographic scheduling differs from the effect of

temporal scheduling on the number and timing of ticket sales. Performances scheduled closely

across venues not only sell more tickets but also sell tickets at a faster rate. In contrast,

performances sparsely scheduled across dates sell more tickets but do not have an impact on the

timing of sales.





13

Our explanation for the observed effect of geographic scheduling is that event marketers

may attempt to signal the desirability of some venues by scheduling more performances in those

venues. Although the desirability of these venues may also be owing to population around these

venues and consumers' shorter travel distance to these venues, we control for this possibility in

our benchmark models and still find a significant effect of geographic scheduling. Therefore, in

contrast with performances scheduled in distant venues, performances scheduled in nearby

venues signal higher desirability or popularity to consumers. As a result, more consumers are

interested in these performances and are more willing to purchase tickets earlier.

On the other hand, our explanation for the observed effect of temporal scheduling is that

event marketers try to accommodate consumers' uncertain preferences to performance dates by

scheduling performances sparsely across dates. In this way, performances on dispersed dates (or

of a longer temporal distance) provide consumers higher flexibility and further sell more tickets.

In contrast, performances within a short time span (or of a shorter temporal distance) substitute

one another and cannibalize ticket sales.

In addition to the impact of scheduling characteristics on ticket sales, our results also

indicate that there exists some endogeneity in the scheduling process. Event marketers consider

how attractive performances are when they schedule performances across dates. However, our

results show that event marketers have not yet incorporated the effects of geographic and

temporal scheduling when they allocate performances across venues and dates.

The organization of this essay is as follows. We first review past works relevant to

scheduling and event ticket sales. Then, we present our conceptual framework and model

development. After a detailed data description, we provide our results and discuss possible

rationale behind the scheduling effects. We also conduct two policy simulations to show how re-



14

allocating performances to a different venue or date would result different number and timing of

ticket sales. Finally, we conclude this essay with limitations and next steps.




2.2 Literature Review and Conceptual Framework

2.2.1 Airline and Movie Scheduling

Because scheduling a live performance event is an important yet understudied research

stream, we search literature in other contexts where scheduling is also critical to managers. We

find airline and movie scheduling literature a good fit because managers have a common

objective to schedule a series of flights, screens, or performances to meet the market demand.

Therefore, we discuss studies in airline and movie scheduling in turn.

Airline Scheduling

Airline scheduling is a complex system. It involves demand estimation, pricing for

different segments, flight scheduling for various routes, fleet assignments for individual flights,

crew scheduling, aircraft rotation, flight gate assignments, and many other decisions (Etschmaier

and Mathaisel 1985; Dobson and Lederer 1993; Jarrah et al 2000; Lohatepanont and Barnhart

2004; Dorndorf et al 2007). Therefore, any small changes require a series of adjustments in the

entire system.

Traditionally, airline scheduling has been a constrained-optimization decision.

Researchers use historical data to estimate demand and consider the expected demand to

construct flight schedules (Dobson and Lederer 1993; Lohatepanont and Barnhart 2004). After

schedule constructions, other departments evaluate proposed schedules to set airfares, assign

aircrafts, and make other operational related decisions (Etschmaier and Mathaisel 1985; Dobson

and Lederer 1993; Jarrah et al 2000; Dorndorf et al 2007). Finally, they examine associated



15

profits and revise flight schedules to ensure profit maximization. Therefore, in this iterative

decision process, scheduling is primarily constraint-driven. An airline managers' objective is to

maximize profitability while minimizing operational costs within feasible boundaries.

The similarity between airline scheduling and performance scheduling is the common

scheduling nature. Airline managers and event marketers have to decide when and where flights

or performances have to take place. Their conceptual objective is the same because they aim to

launch a schedule to extract the most demand in a given market. However, the demand in the

airline schedule is either treated as exogenous (McGill and van Ryzin 1999), based on historical

data (Etschmaier and Mathaisel 1985), or dependent on price and departure and arrival times

(Dobson and Lederer 1993). Researchers assume that dropping flights always leads to losses in

revenues (Lohatepanont and Barnhart 2004) and have not yet investigated how scheduling

density (e.g., frequencies of flights) influences ticket demand.

Movie Scheduling

In the movie industry, movie scheduling takes place after movie distributors release

movies to exhibitors. The primary task that exhibitors perform is to allocate a number of screens

within a theater to meet the local demand for this movie (Swami, Eliashberg, and Weinberg 1999;

Eliashberg et al 2009). Compared with advertising effect on box office revenues, movie

scheduling is a relatively new research direction in this industry (Eliashberg, Elberse, and

Leenderss 2006).

When it comes to the implementation of movie scheduling, exhibitors have to select

movies that might contribute higher revenues because they have a limited number of screens in a

theater. They usually start with estimating demand for a variety of movies and then select a

smaller set of movies to play (Swami et al 1999; Eliashberg et al 2007; Eliashberg et al 2009).



16

After they choose movies of interest, they allocate available screens to these movies (Elberse and

Eliashberg 2003). Although the general principle is that the longer exhibitors play a movie, the

more revenues they get, the decreasing demand over time and the contract with distributors also

determine how long a movie shows in a theater (Swami et al 1999). Finally, exhibitors refer to

box office revenues in a previous week, movie genres, days of week, and times of day to revise

their scheduling decision on a weekly basis (Elberse and Eliashberg 2003; Eliashberg et al 2007).

Movie scheduling is similar to airline scheduling in the sense that both contexts heavily

rely on the operational constraints, and profitability maximization is the top priority. It is also

similar to performance scheduling because within these contexts the purpose is to serve local

demand by offering movies or performances at various days of week or times of day. However,

researchers in movie scheduling usually assumes demand to be exogenous (Swami et al 1999;

Eliashberg et al 2007; Eliashberg et al 2009) or influenced by marketing activities (Elberse and

Eliashberg 2003). They have not yet considered the competition between theaters (Eliashberg et

al 2006) or the impact of scheduling density on box office revenues.

To sum up, the focus of airline and movie scheduling is constraint optimization and profit

maximization. Demand is often assumed exogenous and influences scheduling decisions.

Whether these scheduling decisions influence demand deserves further investigation. Therefore,

the objective of this essay is to examine the impact of scheduling on ticket sales in the context of

a live performance event. Next, we review current research in event tickets to understand

existing drivers for ticket sales before we discuss how scheduling could affect ticket sales.

2.2.2 Event Tickets

Live performance events typically refer to concerts, musicals, or circus acts, etc. that

perform live in front of an audience. Because an event often provides multiple performances



17

across venues and dates, understanding how well each performance can sell is an important issue

for event marketers and researchers. Hence, we review relevant works and discuss factors that

influence the number and timing of ticket sales.

Number of Ticket Sales

Identifying drivers of ticket sales has been a common topic studied in marketing,

economics, and performing arts literature. Researchers have used product related drivers,

consumer characteristics, and seasonality to explain consumer attendance (Weinberg and

Shachmut 1978; Currim, Weinberg, and Wittink 1981; Venkatesh and Mahajan 1993; Reddy,

Swaminathan, and Motley 1998; Putler and Lele 2003; Leslie 2004). According to the number

of events involved in the drivers, we further classify product-related drivers into (1) assortment-

related drivers, (2) event-related drivers, and (3) performance-related drivers. We discuss these

drivers and their importance in turn.

Assortment-related drivers often refer to factors related with a bundle of events. In other

words, this type of drivers exists when multiple events are grouped together in a product offering.

Researchers have shown that different bundle size, event types in a bundle, and associated

seating benefits can attract varying degrees of demand because consumers have heterogeneous

preferences to genres (e.g., operas, musicals), language types (e.g., Italian, English), and

willingness to pay (Currim, Weinberg, and Wittink 1981; Havlena and Holak 1988; Venkatesh

and Mahajan 1993). On the other hand, event-specific drivers refer to information of a specific

event (e.g., pricing or critics' reviews for a Broadway show). While genre, pricing, and

advertising are important for all types of events (Weinberg and Shachmut 1978; Weinberg 1986;

Reddy et al 1998; Corning and Levy 2002; Putler and Lele 2003; Leslie 2004), previews and

critics' reviews are more common for Broadway shows or theatrical events (Reddy et al 1998;



18

Corning and Levy 2002). Because a venue manager's objective is to increase ticket sales within

a venue, they usually achieve their objective by bundling various events in a subscription

package or scheduling a variety of events to attract consumer attendance. Therefore, the first

two types of drivers are important from a venue manager's perspective.

Performance-specific drivers, on the other hand, do not limit the number of events

needed but focus on the lower level of characteristics such as days of week or times of day

(Weinberg and Shachmut 1978; Corning and Levy 2002; Putler and Lele 2003; Leslie 2004). In

contrast with the first two types of drivers, this type of drivers is important to event marketers,

especially when they promote a single event that tours across venues and dates. In other words,

when an event has multiple performances across venues and dates, the assortment-related drivers

are not applicable to a single event. The event-related drivers are important yet pricing and

advertising are often planned at a market level and result in a constant effect across all

performances. Consequently, event marketers can only rely on days of week and times of day as

descriptive drivers to differentiate ticket sales of multiple performances.

The fourth type of driver is consumer characteristics. They often refer to consumers'

income levels, willingness to pay, driving distances to venues, and tastes for genres (Moore 1966;

Currim et al 1981; Venkatesh and Mahajan 1993; Leslie 2004). Although this type of drivers

allow event marketers and venue managers to understand consumer preferences better, it is

relatively difficult for event marketers to identify their potential consumers, especially when an

event travels to a new market and there is no previous consumer information available to event

marketers. The last type of driver is seasonality. It generally refers to the season (i.e., spring,

summer, fall, and winter) that events or performances takes place and is commonly used as a

control variable (Weinberg and Shachmut 1978; Weinberg 1986; Corning and Levy 2002).



19

As such, although there are five types of descriptive drivers for event tickets, there are

not plenty of drivers useful for event marketers to understand variations in ticket sales at a

performance level. Therefore, it is important for researchers to investigate additional drivers to

explain such a variation.

Timing of Ticket Sales

To attend an event, consumers have to purchase tickets no later than its performance date.

Throughout an advance-selling period, their purchase timing may range from very early (i.e.,

advance purchase) to the last minute (i.e., spot purchase). Historically, there are few studies in

event ticket purchases. However, there are many in other contexts such as airline ticket

purchases. Thus, we refer to studies in other contexts to discuss firms' motivation to advance

sell and consumers' motivation to advance purchase tickets for an event.

Generally, advance selling is common in the service-related industry or in a long lead-

time manufacturing industry. Although it is not necessary to charge lower prices in an advance-

selling period (Xie and Shugan 2001), firms still tend to use a two-stage pricing (i.e., charge

discounted rate in the early market but a regular rate in the spot market) as the primary tool to

attract consumers' early purchases and secure some demand well in advance (Desiraju and Xie

1999; Shugan and Xie 2000; Cachon 2004; McCardle, Rajaram, and Tang 2004; Tang et al

2004). Two good examples of advance selling are that, first, a venue manager offers a bundle of

events at a lower rate to attract early arrivals of subscription ticket sales (Currim, Weinberg, and

Wittink 1981; Havlena and Holak 1988; Venkatesh and Mahajan 1993) and, second, an airline

company charges a cheaper airfare to attract leisure travelers' advance purchases (Weatherford et

al 1993; Gallego and van Ryzin 1994; Talluri and van Ryzin 2004).





20

Regarding consumers' motivation to advance purchase, extant literature has suggested

various reasons for consumers' early versus spot purchases. In addition to reservation prices,

consumers' uncertainty toward the consumption state also determines their purchase timing

decisions (Desiraju and Shugan 1999; Shugan and Xie 2000). Specifically, they tend to

procrastinate when they have higher uncertainty about whether they can attend an event in the

future. In contrast, they tend to purchase early when they are more certain to attend in the future.

Other psychological drivers include consumption utility and personal characteristics. For

example, consumers may want to savor their vacation experience better by paying earlier (Prelec

and Loewenstein 1998). Their tendency of being an innovator in their group versus being a

follower also affects their purchase timing decision. Innovators tend to purchase earlier and

influence followers in the later period (Moe and Fader 2002).

Although pricing has been a major factor to affect consumers' purchase timing, a recent

study by Moe and Fader (2009) illustrated a need to re-evaluate the impact of pricing on the

timing of ticket sales. Specifically, they examined the timing of ticket sales across different

price tiers in the context of event tickets and found that consumers who purchase in advance are

not affected by the price discounts or face values of tickets. This result is very different from

airline tickets. Perhaps it is because there are no so-called "business" or "leisure" buyers in the

context of event tickets. Hence, the reason for consumers to advance purchase event tickets is

not clear and deserves further investigation.

2.2.3 Impact of Scheduling on Ticket Sales

The objective of this essay is to examine the impact of scheduling on ticket sales of

performances of the same event. Because performances are scheduled with different frequencies

across venues and dates, the similarity in these scheduling characteristics varies across



21

performances. We refer to literature in context effect, signaling, retail location, and distribution

services for possible effects of these scheduling characteristics.

Context Effect

Context effect has been extensively studied by behavioral literature (Huber, Payne, and

Puto 1982; Huber and Puto 1983; Simonson 1989) where researchers investigate how

alternatives of dominated or dominating attributes influence consumer choices. In general, this

stream of literature proposes violation of proportionality (Luce 1959). Researchers examine

situations when products of similar attributes are more attractive (i.e., attraction effect) and when

they are substitutable (i.e., substitution effect) and where alternatives in the middle level of

attributes are more favorable (i.e., compromise effect) (Huber et al 1982; Huber and Puto 1983;

Simonson 1989). In other words, when consumers have uncertain preferences to product

attributes, they would choose alternatives based on various reasons (Simonson 1989). A

dominating alternative may have a higher choice share under the attraction effect although it may

have a lower share under the substitution effect (Huber at al 1982; Huber and Puto 1983).

However, it is also likely that consumers prefer the new added alternative that has compromised

attributes under the compromise effect.

The relevance between the context effect and the scheduling effect is that similarity

between alternatives (i.e., performances in this case) could influence consumer perception and

choice decisions. As consumers pay more attention to alternatives that share a similar attribute

level (Huber et al 1982), they might focus on evaluating performances in the same or near

venues (or on the same or near dates) and find these performances more attractive or substitutive.

At the aggregate level, the similarity in these scheduling characteristics could further determine

how well these performances sell. On the other hand, performances of compromised attributes



22

(e.g., in a preferred venue but on a less preferred date or vice versa) might also sell differently

from other dominating or dominated performances.

Signaling

Signaling has been studied in marketing to address the issue of product quality. The

assumption for signaling to work is under the separating equilibrium (Chu and Chu 1994) that

manufacturers are credible and have high transaction costs to signal (Moorthy and Srinivasan

1995). Therefore, credible manufacturers can use money-back guarantees (Moorthy and

Srinivasan 1995) or an extended warranty (Padmanabhan and Rao 1993; Lutz and Padmanabhan

1995; Soberman 2003) to signal the quality of their product. They can also sell their products in

reputable retailers for consumers to infer the reputation of manufacturers, especially when their

reputation is not directly observable to consumers (Chu and Chu 1994; Purohit and Srivastava

2001).

We relate signaling with performance scheduling because it is likely that event marketers

want to signal the performing quality of an event to a market. Because sending a false signal can

be expensive (e.g., incremental costs for multiple performances and revenue losses from empty

seats), we assume event marketers are credible. They could increase the number of

performances in a market to signal event popularity. They could also allocate these

performances densely in some venues or on particular dates to suggest popularity or desirability

of these venues or dates. As a result, depending on which signal event marketers want to send,

they will schedule performances differently. After consumers receive the signal and believe the

credibility, they could adjust their preferences and make purchase decisions accordingly.








23

Retail Location

In the retail industry, store locations influence consumers' shopping destination and store

choices (Fotheringham 1988). Therefore, collocating or keeping some distance away from

primary competitors has been an important issue in retail location literature (Mazzeo 2002;

Vitorino 2007; Zhu and Singh 2009). Although some studies show that shorter geographic

distance between retailers leads to direct competition and decreases in store profitability (Watson

2005; Orhun 2005; Seim 2006; Thomadsen 2007; Zhu and Singh 2009; Zhu, Singh, and

Manuszak 2009), other studies indicate benefits for retailers to locate closely (Mazzeo 2002;

Vitorino 2007; Zhu, Singh, and Dukes 2007). For example, retailers collocating in a shopping

center provide consumers a larger product assortment (across stores) such that these retailers can

attract more consumers to the shopping center (Vitorino 2007; Zhu et al 2007). Motels, on the

other hand, collocate in a highway exit to facilitate consumer search and attract more traffic

(Mazzeo 2002).

The relevance between retail location and performance scheduling is that event marketers,

like retailers, have to consider how far in distance or time they should keep performances apart

to avoid substitution within the same event (i.e., cannibalization). On the other hand, event

marketers might also consider scheduling performances closely enough to provide more

alternatives or signal the popularity to attract more demand. Therefore, if the substitution

between performances outweighs the collocating synergy, performances scheduled closely could

suffer fewer ticket sales and slow sales arrival (because consumers can always wait until the last

minute). Otherwise, densely scheduled performances would experience more ticket sales and

faster sales arrival.





24

Distribution Services

In addition to abovementioned spatial differentiation in retail location, retailers also try to

differentiate themselves from other competitors by improving their distribution services

(Betancourt 2004). Distribution services generally refer to the extent of services that retailers are

able to deliver to consumers. These services include product assortment, assurance of product

delivery at consumers' desired time or in the desired form, spatial accessibility between stores

and consumer residences, and so on (Betancourt 2004). For example, retailers can provide a

larger assortment of products, extend business hours, or open more store locations to enhance

their distribution services.

In the live performance industry, similarly, both venue managers and event marketers

may aim to enhance their distribution services. To accommodate consumers who have different

tastes, venue managers may improve their assortment by scheduling a variety of events in their

venues. On the other hand, event marketers may consider consumers who have state uncertainty

about to which venue they want to go and which date they can attend. In this case, they might

schedule performances in multiple venues and disperse performance dates to allow consumers to

attend at their own convenience. In other words, if event marketers schedule performances

sparsely across venues and dates, these performances could accommodate more consumers at

different times and in different venues. In this way, sparsely scheduled performances will sell

more than densely scheduled performances.

2.2.4 Conceptual Framework

Although there may be several reasons to explain event marketers' scheduling decisions

and consumers' decision process, this information is unfortunately unobservable to researchers.

Hence, we can only use the abovementioned literature to speculate potential scheduling effects.



25

To sum up, if event marketers want to signal quality, they will increase the number of

performances and schedule these performances closely in distance or time to attract more

consumers. Then, consumers will perceive these performances to be more popular.

Consequently, more consumers will attend these performances and these consumers will be more

likely to purchase tickets in advance. On the other hand, if event marketers schedule

performances to enhance their distribution services, they will schedule performances across

multiple venues and disperse performance dates farther apart. In this way, performances

scheduled farther apart are able to accommodate more consumers and sell more tickets. Yet, it is

still possible for consumers to procrastinate given their uncertainty for the consumption state. As

such, based on different streams of literature, we can anticipate different scheduling mechanisms

and consumer responses.

However, if event marketers do not have a specific scheduling strategy but schedule

performances to comply with operational constraints such as venue availability and seating

capacity, their scheduling process is similar to airline and movie scheduling. Then, the impact of

scheduling could be positive or negative. According to the retail location literature, event

marketers may expect performances in close distance or time to have a substitutive relationship

and cannibalize ticket sales. They may also expect a collocation synergy between performances

to attract more demand. From consumers' perspective, they may make their own inferences

about these performances based on different contexts. According to the attraction effect, they

may perceive performances of similar scheduling characteristics to be more attractive. Hence,

these performances will sell more tickets and these ticket sales will arrive earlier. In contrast,

consumers may perceive these performances to be highly substitutable (i.e., substitution effect)





26

and delay their purchase timing. If so, these performances will sell less and sell more slowly

than do those of dissimilar scheduling characteristics.

However, event marketers may not just simultaneously schedule performances densely

(or sparsely) across venues and dates. They may sometimes schedule performances densely in

certain venues to signal venue popularity yet disperse performance dates to accommodate

consumers' uncertainty of attendance timing. Similarly, they may schedule performances

densely on certain dates as popular leisure activities but allocate these performances in several

distant venues to increase spatial accessibility. Consequently, if event marketers have separate

objectives and schedule accordingly, consumers will find performances scheduled closely in

distance (or time) but distantly in time (or distance). In this way, performances have different

scheduling characteristics across venue locations and performance dates, and consumers will

evaluate a geographic and temporal schedule separately. Hence, the effect of geographic

scheduling may differ from the effect of temporal scheduling. We allow this possibility and

empirically test these scheduling effects.

On the other hand, to study the impact of performance schedules on ticket sales, we also

have to control for the attractiveness of performances on different days of week and the potential

endogeneity between scheduling decisions and expected market response. In other words, if

event marketers have some knowledge about how a market responds to a performance schedule

and then use this knowledge to schedule performances, the performance schedule will be

endogenously set and the scheduling impact will be biased. In case the endogeneity exists, we

propose to examine the effect of performance schedule on ticket sales and control for the

endogeneity simultaneously. Figure 2-1 below summarizes our conceptual framework.

Figure 2-1: Conceptual Framework



27

2.3 Model Development

2.3.1 Model Overview

To test the potential impact of scheduling, our modeling objective is to measure the

scheduling characteristics of each performance and study the impact of these scheduling

characteristics on the number and timing of ticket sales. Thus, our model development consists

of four steps. First, we measure the scheduling characteristics to capture the similarity or

dissimilarity in venue locations and performance dates across performances. Second, we

examine the number of ticket sales across performances. Because it is possible that some

consumers evaluate the venue locations and performance dates but do not attend (i.e., non-

buyers), we incorporate the impact of scheduling characteristics on the size of non-buyer

segment. In this way, event marketers can understand how much market potential they have

captured and how much they have missed out. Third, we examine the timing of ticket sales

across performances. Because each performance sells tickets at a different rate and experience

different timing of ticket sales in an advance-selling period, it is important to capture

heterogeneous sales patterns and explain the differences. Finally, we consider a possible

endogeneity between performance scheduling and market response. If event marketers know the

effects of scheduling on the number of ticket sales, they could allocate performances based on

the positive or negative effect and expected performance attractiveness. Under this situation,

performance scheduling is endogenous with market response (Manchanda, Rossi, and

Chintagunta 2004). It is important to control for this endogeneity to ensure unbiased model

results. Figure 2-2 below summarizes our model development and we discuss each modeling

element in turn.

Figure 2-2: Model Overview



28

2.3.2 Scheduling Characteristics

To capture the similarity or dissimilarity in scheduling characteristics of performances,

we refer to a performance schedule of an event and differentiate between performances based on

their venue locations and performance dates. We create two measures to represent the

scheduling similarity in this performance schedule to understand how performances are

scheduled closely or distantly across venues and dates.

Specifically, we take the inverse geographic distance (in miles) between performances as

the geographic density measure and the inverse temporal distance (in days) between performance

dates as the temporal density measure (Fotheringham 1988). In this way, performances

scheduled in the same or proximate venues will have a higher value in geographic density to

represent similarity in the geographic schedule. Performances scheduled on the same or near

dates will have a higher value in temporal density to show similarity in the temporal schedule.

Therefore, our specifications for the density measures are as follows:

J
(1)




(2)
GEO




TMP

J
1




1

1


,

J
1
miles





1
J 1 , 1 days

where GEO
j
is the geographic density for performance j (j=1,2,.., J), TMP
j
is the temporal

density for performance j, miles
jj'
represents the geographic distance between venues of

performance j and j' (j=j'), and days
jj'
represents the temporal distance between performance

dates of j and j'.

To compute the distance between venue locations and performance dates, we use driving

distance (in miles) between the venues of j and j' as miles
jj'
. We also specify miles
jj'
=1 for



29

performances in the same location to avoid the denominator equal to zero. In addition, we use

the absolute value of distance (in days) between performances j and j' as days
jj'
. However, we

specify the denominator as (1+days
jj'
) in equation (2) to avoid performances on the same date

having a zero temporal distance.

Therefore, with respect to a target performance j, after taking its average (inverse)

geographic and temporal distance to other performances, GEO
j
and TMP
j
suggest its average

geographic and temporal density. The higher GEO
j
and TMP
j
of this performance, the closer this

performance is to other performances. As such, this performance is densely scheduled around

other performances and has higher similarity in venue locations and performance dates.

2.3.3 Number of Ticket Sales

To examine the number of ticket sales across performances and understand how much

market potential event marketers miss out, we apply a competing destination model by

Fotheringham (1988) and specify the share of each performance and the non-buyer segment as a

function of scheduling characteristics. By doing so, we can understand whether geographic and

temporal scheduling influence ticket sales at a performance level. In addition, using sales shares

of individual performances and the population size in a target market, we can obtain the number

of ticket sales expected at a performance level. We can also obtain a market penetration rate by

summing sales shares across performances.

Competing Destination Model

Among various extensions of the logit model, we consider the competing destination

model proposed by Fotheringham (1988) as a good alternative. The competing destination

model extends the traditional logit model by releasing the property of independence from

irrelevant alternatives (IIA) (Luce 1959; McFadden 1974). It examines consumers' spatial



30

choice set as a function of geographic distance between stores. Then, the composition of the

spatial choice set further influences consumers' store choices. If stores of shorter geographic

distance have higher chance to be in consumers' choice set, these stores will attract more

consumers and have higher choice shares. However, if stores of shorter geographic distance

have a lower chance to be in consumers' choice set, these stores will substitute one another and

have lower choice shares. The specification of the competing destination model is as follows

(Fotheringham 1988):

exp
(3)

¿
J
?
exp

?
?


where P
ij
denotes the probability that consumer i shops in retail outlet j, V
ij
represents the

deterministic utility of retailer j to consumer i, and l j M is the likelihood that retailer j is in

consumer's spatial choice set. After aggregating P
ij
across consumers, P
j
represents the market

share of a retailer j in a studied market of interest (González-Benito 2005).

Moreover, to measure the likelihood of spatial choice set, Fotheringham specified the

likelihood as a function of average inverse geographic distance between retail stores

(Fotheringham 1983; Fotheringham 1988) and empirically test the role of geographic distance:

u
J
1 w
?

(4)
J 1 d
?

?
?


where d
jj'
is the geographic distance between a target store j and a competing store j', w
j'
is the

weight for the competing store j', and u is the parameter indicating the role of geographic

distance. More specifically, if u> 0, stores of shorter geographic distance to other stores will

have higher chance to be included in consumers' choice set. If u< 0, in contrast, stores will have



31

lower chance to be included. Finally, if u= 0, geographic distance does not affect the

composition of consumers' spatial choice set.

Extension of Competing Destination Model

To examine the separate effects of geographic and temporal scheduling, we extend the

competing destination model by incorporating the geographic and temporal density values and

allowing separate parameter values for these scheduling characteristics. In addition, we include

the non-buyer segment in a market as another alternative for potential buyers. In this way, we

can understand how scheduling characteristics affect the sales share of performances and the size

of non-buyer segment. Our adaption is as follows:

exp
(5)
1
¿
J
?
exp
?
? ?

where P(j) denotes the sales share of performance j, V
j
represents the attractiveness of this

performance (which we will discuss later), GEO
j
and TMP
j
are the geographic and temporal

density values of performance j, and parameters u
1
and u
2
represent the scheduling effects.

If u
1
or u
2
> 0, geographic or temporal scheduling has a positive effect. Performances of

similar venue locations or performance dates will enjoy higher sales share. In contrast, if u
1
or u
2


< 0, geographic or temporal scheduling has a negative effect. Performances of similar venue

locations or performance dates will substitute one another and suffer from sales cannibalization.

However, if u
1
or u
2
= 0, scheduling has no impact on sales share. Moreover, we can use the

population size in a target market (which we will discuss in the data section), POP, to calculate

the expected number of ticket sales for any performance: Sales j POP P j . We can also

obtain the market penetration rate by summing sales share across performances i. e. , ¿
J
Pj


and understand the size of non-buyer segment as 1 ¿
J
Pj.


32

To measure and control the effect of performance attractiveness (V
j
), event ticket

literature has suggested various drivers for ticket sales that can be a good proxy for attractiveness.

However, because we focus on analyzing multiple performances of the same event, only

performance-related drivers are applicable. Therefore, we specify V
j
as a function of days of

week indicators (Friday, Saturday, and Sunday). The reason for us to choose these three days of

week indicators is that past studies indicate that performances on those days have higher

attractiveness (Corning and Levy 2002; Putler and Lele 2003). Hence, we specify performance

attractiveness as a control covariate for the number of ticket sales and incorporate a random error

term for unobserved attractiveness:

(6) V o o FRIDAY o SATURDAY o SUNDAY c where c ~N 0, o

where o
0
reflects the baseline attractiveness, o
1
, o
2
, and o
3
suggest the effects of days of week on

incremental performance attractiveness for a Friday, Saturday, or Sunday performance, and E[V
j
]

represents the expected performance attractiveness.

To sum up, we adapt the competing destination model to understand the effects of

geographic and temporal scheduling on the sales share of performance and the size of non-buyer

segment. We also control for the performance attractiveness due to the days of week effects.

Although a linear regression or spatial model can also examine the number of ticket sales across

performances, our model specification is more appropriate than a regression or spatial model. A

linear regression is commonly used in event tickets literature (Moore 1966; Weinberg and

Shachmut 1978; Weinberg 1986; Reddy et al 1998; Corning and Levy 2002). However, it

cannot examine the sales share of each performance and the non-buyer segment at the same time

In other words, a linear regression does not allow us to understand how much of the market

performances have captured and how much they have left untapped. In contrast, our proposed



33

model can accomplish all of these limitations of a linear regression model. In comparison to a

spatial model, the model proposed in this dissertation specifically measures the effects of

performance schedules as drivers of ticket sales and not just modeling the spatial correlation

between performances (Bradlow et al 2005).

2.3.4 Timing of Ticket Sales

To examine the timing of ticket sales across performances, we first consider a typical

sales pattern for a performance. In general, a performance starts selling tickets 12 weeks prior to

its performing date. It usually sells fewer tickets in the beginning of its advance-selling period

and obtains more sales over time with the most arriving in the later period or the week of the

performance. Given this typical pattern, however, each performance still has a different sales

rate. Some performances experience ticket sales arrived earlier (i.e., earlier timing of ticket sales)

but others experience ticket sales arrived later (i.e., later timing of ticket sales).

Figure 2-3 below illustrates three patterns of ticket sales in an advance-selling period.

First, the solid line in Figure 2-3 (Case 1) is one common pattern, where consumers have low

probability to purchase well in advance. As time passes, the probability of a ticket transaction

slowly increases and peaks at the week of performance. However, there are some situations

where consumers expect performances to be of greater performance attractiveness or higher

popularity. As a result, they are more willing to purchase earlier and result in more ticket sales

arriving in the middle of an advance-selling period, as shown in the dotted line of Figure 2-3

(Case 2). Yet, there is another case when consumers think performances of lower performance

attractiveness and/or of higher substitutability. In this instance, they do not want to commit early

and wait until the week (or the day) of a performance. Therefore, ticket sales for such a





34

performance are very low in the entire advance-selling period and only peak in the spot market.

The broken line in Figure 2-3 (Case 3) represents this pattern.

Figure 2-3: Pattern of Ticket Sales Over Time

Weibull Hazard Model

Although performances usually follow a similar pattern as seen in Figure 2-3 (Case 1),

there still exists variability of sales pattern among performances (e.g., Case 2 and Case 3 in

Figure 2-3). To account for variations in sales rate across performances, we need a model that is

flexible enough to capture various sales patterns and examine the performance-specific sales

rates. Hence, we specify a Weibull hazard model to fit the timing of ticket sales because of its

flexibility in capturing various sales patterns, as shown in Figure 2-3. A Weibull hazard process

has the following properties:

(7)




1 1

where, with respect to a performance j, h
j
(t) is the instantaneous hazard rate for a ticket purchase

made at time t given this transaction has not yet been made, S
j
(t) is the survival rate for a ticket

purchase that has not yet occurred up to time t, and F
j
(t) is the cumulative probability for sales to

arrive over time. More specifically, ì
j
is the slope parameter for performance j to represent how

fast ticket sales arrive (ì
j
>0), and c
j
is the shape parameter to capture an overall pattern of ticket

sales (c
j
>0).

For any discrete time t (e.g., week) in an advance-selling period, the probability of a

ticket purchase becomes:




35

(8) 1

However, ticket sales in the context of a live performance event have to arrive no later

than the performance date. We adjust the probability of a ticket purchase in the spot market (i.e.,

the week of the performance) as follows:

(9) 1

where T
j
is the number of advance selling weeks for performance j.

In addition, because we often observe seasonality (e.g., Thanksgiving, Christmas, etc.) or

marketing activities in an advance-selling period, we can include a time-varying covariate to

control for resulting sales bumps. Therefore, we rewrite equations (7), (8), and (9) as follows:

(10)


exp 1


1 exp 1


exp 1


exp 1 1 1


exp 1


where X
jt
is a time-varying covariate or seasonality indicator and |
j
is its associated parameter.

Consequently, the timing of ticket sales for each performance changes with its parameters ì
j
, c
j
,

and |
j
.







36

Heterogeneity in Sales Patterns

To capture and explain the heterogeneity in sales pattern, we further specify the sales rate

of each performance as a function of its geographic and temporal density measures. We also

include two control covariates to ensure unbiased effects of these scheduling characteristics. The

first covariate is the length of advance-selling period because Moe and Fader (2002, 2009) found

that sales tend to arrive more slowly under a longer advance-selling period. In addition, because

consumers may purchase tickets much earlier when they expect performance to be more

attractive, we incorporate the expected performance attractiveness as the second control

covariate. Consequently, we specify the Weibull parameters (ì
j
and c
j
) and the covariate effect

(|
j
) to follow the multivariate normal distribution. We take the log transformation for the

Weibull parameters to ensure positive values:

(11) log
log ~ ,



where

E

whereµ
j
is the vector of expected Weibull parameters and covariate effect, GEO
j
and TMP
j
are

the geographic and temporal density measures in equations (1) and (2), T
j
is the number of

advance selling weeks for performance j, E[V
j
] is the expected performance attractiveness in

equation (6), and¸
0

1

2

3
, and¸
4
are the vectors of parameters for these covariates.

Therefore, using the parameter results in equation (11), event marketers can understand why

some performances experience earlier timing of ticket sales while other experience later timing

of ticket sales.




37

2.3.5 Endogeneity in Performance Scheduling

Finally, we consider a possible endogeneity in scheduling decisions. Since the live

performance industry has been established and event marketers have scheduled for a variety of

events, event marketers might have incorporated their experiences into a scheduling process. In

other words, how densely event marketers allocate performances across venues may be

dependent on the effect of geographic scheduling, and how densely event marketers allocate

performances across dates may be dependent on the effect of temporal scheduling. Moreover, it

is also likely that event marketers increase the total number of performances and schedule those

on weekend to increase the performance attractiveness. If so, the geographic and temporal

density values vary with the scheduling impact and the expected performance attractiveness.

To control for this type of endogeneity, we refer to a modeling approach proposed by

Manchanda et al (2004). In their research of pharmaceutical detailing, they mentioned that sales

representatives visit various doctors with different frequencies, and sales representatives

determine the frequencies based on how many prescriptions a doctor writes without any detailing

and how strong the effect of detailing is if they visit this doctor. They pointed out the

endogeneity between the decision of detailing and the effect of detailing, and further proposed a

model to correct this endogeneity.

In other words, they specified the expected prescription volume from a doctor as a

function of its baseline volume, the magnitude of detailing, and the detailing effect:


(12) ln



1



1


where ln is the expected volume of prescription, is the baseline prescription volume,


Det is the frequency of office visits, and is the effect of detailing.



38

To model the endogenous detailing behavior, they specify the expected value of detailing

ln as a function of the baseline prescription volume and the effect of detailing:


(13) ln
1 1

In this way, if detailing is indeed endogenous, the parameter ¸
1
or ¸
2
will be significantly

different from zero, and the endogeneity between detailing and its effect is under control.

To control for the possible endogenous scheduling behaviors, we take the same modeling

approach as Manchanda et al (2004). We specify geographic and temporal density measures

(GEO
j
and TMP
j
) as a function of expected performance attractiveness (E[V
j
] in equation 6), and

the effects of scheduling characteristics (u
1
and u
2
in equation 5). Because GEO
j
and TMP
j
in

equation (1) and (2) are between 0 and 1, we take the logit transformation for these density

measures and specify them following the multivariate normal distribution:

(14) logit
~ ,
logit

where


E


As such, if scheduling decisions are indeed endogenous and reflect on the density

measures, the parameters|
1
or|
2
will be significantly different from zero and this endogeneity

will be taken into account.




2.4 Data Description

We contact a national ticket seller to obtain a dataset of live performance events.

Because of the confidentiality agreement with our data provider, we cannot disclose our data



39

provider or the names of events. However, we will describe the nature of the events and the

behaviors observed in the dataset.

In this dataset, there were two events touring across several cities in the U.S. Each event

had a different number of performances in a city and lasted for a different period. For each

performance, we observe its venue location and performance date. In addition, we also have

detailed information regarding when tickets were purchased, for how much money, at which

price levels, and through which channels. Moreover, we are also able to observe the pattern of

ticket sales because transactions were recorded at a daily level. Table 2-1 provides a detailed

description of each field in our data set, which contains abundant information about the live

performance event and has many research opportunities for marketing researchers.

Table 2-1: Description of Variables in the Dataset

2.4.1 Description of Events

The events we have in the dataset are two popular family events. They are live

entertainments that targets on families with young children. In general, there are several types of

family events such as children's music and theater (e.g., The Wiggles and Dora the Explorer

Live!), circus (e.g., Ringling Brothers and Barnum & Baileyand UniverSoul Circus), ice shows

(e.g., Disney on Ice series), magic shows (e.g., Xtreme Magic and Steve Wyrick ), and so on.

They usually travel across the U.S. or stay in a local market such as Las Vegas. The family

events we have are within the abovementioned categories.

For the two events we have, one sold 2.2 millions of tickets between January and June

2004 and travelled across 50 cities on 245 dates for 449 performances. The other sold 0.8

millions of tickets between January and May 2004 and travelled across 17 cities on 85 dates for

157 performances. The reason for the sales discrepancy is that one event had multiple



40

performing groups touring across cities simultaneously while the other had only one group

performing in our observed time span. Although these two events travelled to numerous cities

during their tours and had three cities in common (i.e., Jacksonville, FL; Miami, FL; Phoenix,

AZ), these events did not perform in those cities at the same time but at least 2.5 months apart.

Therefore, we assume there was no direct competition between these events to affect ticket sales.

Although both events are representative in terms of their ticket sales and the number of

performances, we take only one event in this dissertation to keep the event attractiveness

constant and examine merely the scheduling effect on ticket sales. In this way, once we confirm

a significant scheduling effect, we can further incorporate the renown of different events as an

extension. As such, we choose the event that had more performances. Among 50 cities that this

event toured, we also find some cities were within the same metropolitan markets (e.g., New

York and other metropolitan markets). This observation suggests that the event had multiple

stops in some markets and had higher variations in both geographic and temporal schedules.

Hence, we further select performances in the New York metropolitan market
1
and examine the

impact of geographic and temporal schedules on ticket sales in essay one. In summary, this

event had performances in Continental Arena in East Rutherford, NJ, Nassau Coliseum in

Uniondale, NY, Madison Square Garden in New York, NY, and Sovereign Bank Arena in

Trenton, NJ, respectively between March and June 2004 for 70 performances.

2.4.2 Description of Ticket Sales

Because a dataset of event tickets is not commonly available in marketing, we first

examine ticket sales by price levels and channel types to describe how much money people

usually pay and through which channel. Then, we examine the distribution of ticket sales across




1



We follow the Census Bureau data to define the boundary of a metropolitan market.
41
performances to understand how many tickets each performance sells and when ticket sales

arrive.

Ticket Sales by Price Levels

We first aggregate ticket sales by price levels and performances to examine any different

sales distributions across price levels. On average, the admission fees to a performance

(including face value, facility fees, and service charges) are $30.44 and there are about six price

tiers for consumers to choose. Although seating quality in a venue determines the price levels,

83% of ticket sales are contributed by mid-priced levels (i.e., price levels 2, 3 and 4) with

average price ranges from $20 to $50.

Specifically, price level 3 (mean price=$25.31, std= 3.66) represents 50% of ticket sales,

and price level 4 (mean price= $20.02; std= 3.17) and price level 2 (mean price= $50.16; std=

6.89) contribute 21% and 12% of ticket sales, respectively. In addition, we find the average

admission fees are relatively equal across venues and days of week. In other words, price

variations are within a performance (via price levels) but not across venues or days of week.

Ticket Sales by Channel Types

Next, we aggregate ticket sales by channel types and performances to examine ticket

sales across channels. Although consumers can purchase tickets through any of the six available

channels (i.e., primary box office, secondary box office, Hermes (automatic phone), Internet,

outlet, and phone), we find majority of ticket sales are made through the primary box office

(62% of ticket sales), following by the Internet (22% of ticket sales) and a ticket outlet (11% of

ticket sales). A possible reason for a primary box office to be a dominating channel choice is

that consumers do not have to pay for the convenience charges when they buy tickets in a box

office.



42

Ticket Sales by Performances

We also aggregate ticket sales across performances. As Figure 2-4 shows, a performance

on average sells 8,316 tickets but has its standard deviation being 3,525. Upon a closer look of

the sales distribution by days of week (based on performance dates), we find that weekend

performances tend to have more ticket sales than weekdays. Yet, the variation of ticket sales on

the same day of week is still prominent. The boxplot in Figure 2-5 summarizes the sales

distributions by days of week and indicate a clear variation even on the same day of week. For

example, a Friday performance sells 8,112 tickets on average but has a big standard deviation of

2,509, and a Saturday performance has average ticket sales of 9,552 but has the standard

deviation being 3,808. According to Figure 2-5 and the observation that each performance has

similar price levels, it is convincing that there must be additional factors to explain the variations

in ticket sales. Although one can argue that ticket sales are due to venue capacities, we find the

sizes of capacity in the four venues are similar and there are no sold out for any performance.

Hence, we do not consider the impact of venue capacity on ticket sales in this essay.

Figure 2-4: Sales Distribution by Performances

Figure 2-5: Sales Distribution by Days of Week

Finally, we aggregate daily ticket sales into weekly sales to examine the sales pattern for

each performance. On average, ticket sales arrive up to 15 weeks prior with the range between

11 and 19 weeks. Table 2-2 presents the ticket sales across performances and the breakdown of

weekly sales throughout an advance-selling period in Table 2-2. On average, a performance sells

8,316 tickets with 24% of sales arrived one month prior, 33% of sales arrived 2 to 4 weeks prior,

and 42% of sales arrived in the week of performances. Figure 2-6 shows a sales pattern for a

randomly chosen performance and it is a common pattern in our dataset. However, given this


43

similar pattern across performances, some performances experience ticket sales much earlier

than other performances (e.g., 59% vs. 3% of total sales arrived in the early stage) yet other

performances do not have as many ticket sales arrived in the last week (e.g., 75% vs. 11% of

total sales arrived in the spot stage). The boxplot in Figure 2-7 demonstrates the heterogeneity in

the timing of ticket sales across performances throughout an advance-selling period.

Table 2-2: Summary of Ticket Sales


Figure 2-6: Weekly Sales Pattern of a Performance


Figure 2-7: Heterogeneity in Timing of Ticket Sales across Performances

2.4.3 Covariate Specifications

Before we estimate the proposed model, there are several covariates not directly provided

in the dataset that require our attention. They are the geographic and temporal density measures

(GEO
j
and TMP
j
), the days of week indicators (FRIDAY
j
, SATURDAY
j
, SUNDAY
j
), the

estimated population size in the target market (POP), the length of advance-selling period (T
j
),

and the time-varying covariate (X
jt
). We discuss and specify these covariates in turn.

To compute the density measures, we first refer to venue locations and use the Google
TM


maps to find the driving distance (in miles) between venues. The numbers in Figure 2-8 indicate

the venue locations in the New York metropolitan market and represent the travel sequence

across venues. In addition, the numeric values between venues represent the mileage between

venues (i.e., mile
jj'
). We summarize the geographic distance between venues and the number of

performances in each venue in Figure 2-9 and follow equation (1) to calculate the geographic

density for each performance. Next, we refer to performance dates to calculate the temporal

distance (in absolute values) between performances (day
jj'
). According to the performance dates




44

and their temporal distance to others in Figure 2-10, we apply equation (2) to compute the

temporal density for every performance.

Figure 2-8: Venue Locations and Driving Distances


Figure 2-9: Summary of Geographic Distance


Figure 2-10: Summary of Temporal Distance

To compute the days of week indicators, we refer to performance dates to identify on

which days of week performances take place (i.e., FRIDAY, SATURDAY and SUNDAY).

Although some performances are scheduled on the same date, unfortunately our data does not

indicate time of day for the performances.

Next, we compute the population size in the target market (POP). Given that the event

targets families with young children, we define the target market as the population of families

with children under 10 years old. To compute the market size, we refer to the U.S. Census

Bureau for the 2000 data to find the total number of families with children under 18 years old

and the percentage of all children who are under 10 years old. We multiply these two numbers

to get the family population with children under 10 years old and then multiply the average

family size to get the population size in the target market. According to these calculations, there

are 4,082,615 potential consumers in the New York metropolitan market. We use this market

size and ticket sales across all performances to find the market penetration rate to be 14%, which

means the non-buyer segment represents 86% of the target market.

To measure the number of advance selling weeks (T
j
in equation 11) as a control

covariate, we compute the difference between the first sale date and the performance date for

each performance. Then, we divide this number by seven to convert the advance-selling period




45

to weeks. Although tickets may be available for sales prior to the first sale date, we think our

approach a good proxy given very few sales arrived in the early selling period.

Finally, because we observe Christmas within the advance-selling period for some

performances, we incorporate a time-varying indicator (X
jt
) in equation (10) to control for a

possible pre-Christmas shopping and resulting sales bumps. For each performance j, we code

X
jt
=1 if the advance selling week t is consistent with the pre-Christmas shopping week (i.e., 7

days prior to Christmas). Otherwise, X
jt
=0. Table 2-3 summarizes the descriptive statistics of

covariates.

Table 2-3: Descriptive Statistics of Covariates



2.5 Model Estimation and Benchmark Comparison

2.5.1 Estimation

We choose the Bayesian statistics approach to estimate the number of ticket sales, the

timing of ticket sales, and the endogeneity in a performance schedule simultaneously. We

specify appropriate and diffuse priors for our parameters in the WinBUGS program and estimate

the model over 40,000 iterations. After checking the convergence criteria, we check the

autocorrelation plots for all covariates, discarded 30,000 iterations for burn-in, and use the

remaining iterations as the posterior distribution. We specified the prior distribution of

parameters below:

Priors for modeling the number of ticket sales:

~ 6,10 For the baseline performance attractiveness

~ 0,100 For the effects of days of week (where i=1, 2,3)

~ 0,100 For the effect of scheduling characteristics (where i=1, 2)

~ 0.1,0.1 For the variance of the performance attractiveness


46

Priors for modeling the timing of ticket sales:

~N 0, 100 For the Weibull parameters and the covariate effect
(where i=0, 1, 2, 3, 4 and k= 0, 1, 2, 3)

~Weibull I , 3 For the variance-covariance of the Weibull parameters and the covariate
effect

Priors for modeling the endogeneity in performance schedule:

~N 0,100 For the expected geographic and temporal density values
(where i=0, 1, 2 and k= 1, 2)

~Weibull I , 2

2.5.2 Benchmark Comparison

Before presenting our model results, we specify benchmark models to compare with our

proposed model to rule out alternative explanations for our proposed scheduling effects. First,

because the central focus of our modeling efforts is to examine the impact of scheduling

characteristics, one ideal benchmark model is to exclude any scheduling effect but only

incorporate performance attractiveness (i.e., Benchmark 1). Second, some venue locations are

more popular than others. For example, a venue in the New York city might be more attractive

than another venue in Uniondale. Therefore, we consider the second benchmark that

incorporates the venue-specific indicator variables. Finally, Population density around the venue

locations could also explain ticket sales. In other words, event marketers may schedule more

performances in a specific venue because the population density in this venue is high and the

scheduling decision is simply to meet potential market demand in this venue. To rule out this

alternative explanation, we extend our proposed model by including the population density

around each venue location of performances as another explanatory variable (i.e., Benchmark 3).

We estimate our proposed and benchmark models to compare the model fit using the

deviance information criteria (i.e., DIC, Spiegelhalter et al 2002):

47

(15) 2


where is the deviance evaluated at the posterior means and pD is the effective number of

parameters in a model, calculated as the difference between the posterior deviance and the

deviance of the posterior mean.

Table 2-4 summarizes the model fit across the benchmark and proposed models.

According to the DIC reported for every model, we find that incorporating the scheduling effect

is definitely superior. Although adding city effects improves the DIC from 157,134 (Benchmark

1) to 156,459 (Benchmark 2), city effects cannot explain the ticket sales as well as does the

proposed model (DIC= 156,221). Moreover, we find our proposed model has a similar fit to

Benchmark 3 (DIC=156,220). Although Benchmark 3 has a smaller DIC value by one unit,

Ntzoufras (2009, p.220) suggests that a model performs better than another does if the DIC

difference is greater than 2. Therefore, we conclude that our proposed model is as good as

Benchmark 3.

Finally, we compare the parameter results between these two models and find significant

and consistent effects of scheduling characteristics on ticket sales. Although the third benchmark

model also shows that the population density and travel distance from consumers' residences to

venues is relevant, results in this benchmark model still indicate a significant geographic effect.

In other words, although consumers may prefer a venue nearest to them, it is still very likely that

consumers are willing to travel to a farther venue that has a stronger association with a leisure

activity (Okada 2005).

Therefore, we are confident that there are scheduling effects to influence consumer

decisions and ticket sales across performances. We discuss the parameter results and their

implications in the next section.



48

Table 2-4: Benchmark Models and Model Fit



2.6 Results

2.6.1 Number of Ticket Sales

Table 2-5 summarizes our parameter results for the number of ticket sales. First, we find

that performances on Saturday and Sunday have higher attractiveness to increase ticket sales

than those on other days of week (o
2
= 0.35; o
3
= 0.34). This result is consistent with prior

literature (Corning and Levy 2002; Putler and Lele 2003) and shows the importance of

controlling for performance attractiveness when examining the impact of scheduling

characteristics.

Second, we find that scheduling indeed influences how many tickets each performance

can sell. When performances are scheduled closely in venues and have a shorter geographic

distance to other performances, they attract more consumers and sell more tickets (u
1
= 0.32).

Additionally, when performances are scheduled sparsely along a time span and have a longer

temporal distance to others, they attract more consumers and sell more tickets (u
2
= -0.14).

Because the geographic and temporal density measures have different effects on ticket sales,

these results suggest that consumers evaluate geographic and temporal schedules separately and

have different responses.

Table 2-5: Results for the Number of Ticket Sales

As we mentioned earlier, event marketers' scheduling and consumers' decision making

are both unobserved processes to researchers. Hence, we can only speculate possible underlying

mechanisms based on prior literature and our results. One way to interpret different consumer

responses to geographic and temporal schedules is that event marketers have several objectives

when they schedule performances. These objectives influence their scheduling decisions and

49

consumers' reactions. For example, their objectives may be to signal venue popularity and

enhance assurance of product delivery at the desired time. If so, they will schedule performances

closely in venues of interest yet sparsely across performance dates. From consumers'

perspective, after they see such geographic and temporal schedules, they receive the signal of

venue popularity and find the flexibility in attendance timing. Then, they shape their preferences

to favor performances of such scheduling characteristics and further influence their purchase

decisions. As a result, these performances sell more tickets than other performances.

Alternatively, event marketers may not have a predetermined scheduling strategy in mind.

The geographic and temporal schedules are the consequences of constrained optimization. If so,

consumers will make their own inferences about these performances. For consumers who do not

have specific preferences to venue locations and performance dates, they might evaluate

performances differently based on different contexts. For instance, they may find an event

highly associated with some venues because these venues are close to each other and offer more

performances. Due to the similar venue locations and shorter geographic distance between

venues, these venues may catch consumers' attention better and become consumers' preferred

venues when consumers attend an event. Performances in these venues hence share this

common advantage to attract more consumers and sell more tickets.

On the other hand, consumers may perceive an event highly associated with some days of

week because many performances are scheduled around those days. Therefore, these days of

week would catch more attention and become more salient when consumers consider when to

attend. However, consumers usually have uncertainty for the future and prefer a wider range of

dates for selections. Closely scheduled performances at any time could merely substitute one

another and suffer from sales cannibalization.



50

According to these two interpretations, one implication for event marketers is that they

should keep their scheduling strategy (if they indeed have such a strategy) to schedule

performances densely in venue locations but sparsely across performance dates. Even if they do

not have such a strategy but only practice constrained optimization, our results provide them

another useful scheduling implication. That is, they should incorporate the scheduling effects

(i.e., a positive geographic effect but a negative temporal effect) into their decision process as

new constraints to find the most optimal solution.

2.6.2 Timing of Ticket Sales

Table 2-6 describes the parameter estimates and indicates that geographic density and the

number of advance selling weeks have significant effects on the Weibull parameters (¸
11
= -7.56;

¸
12
= 0.93). Because the objective of this paper is to examine the scheduling effect while

controlling for the number of advance selling weeks, we discuss the geographic effect on the

timing of ticket sales more in details.

Table 2-6: Results for Timing of Ticket Sales

However, it is less straightforward to observe the net effect of geographic density on the

timing of ticket sales based on the parameter results. We proceed to simulate performances of

different levels of geographic density to visually show their effects on the timing of ticket sales.

Therefore, Figure 2-11 presents three hypothetical performances of different levels of geographic

density but of the same performance attractiveness. The solid line illustrates the expected timing

of ticket sales resulting from geographic density being the mean value observed in our dataset

(GEO). The two dashed lines show the expected timing of ticket sales for two performances

where their geographic density values are one standard deviation higher or lower than the mean,

respectively. We can observe from Figure 2-11 that once the geographic density increases by



51

one standard deviation from the mean (GEO +1SD), the cumulative ticket sales after 12 weeks of

advance selling increase from 11% to 25% of its expected total amount. In contrast, when the

geographic density decreases by one standard deviation from the mean (GEO -1SD), only 7%

arrived after 12 weeks. Therefore, we conclude that performances in densely scheduled venues

have shorter geographic distance to other performances such that they sell tickets at a faster rate

than those of longer geographic distance.

Figure 2-11: Impact of Geographic Density on Timing of Ticket Sales

Our intuition for this result is that venues where these performances are closely scheduled

share the similarity in venue locations and geographic density. These venues can catch

consumers' attention and lead to an attraction effect. In other words, even after controlling for

performance attractiveness, consumers still think performances in these venues more attractive.

As a result, they are willing to purchase tickets much earlier.

The implication of this result is that event marketers can monitor when and how fast

ticket sales arrive based on the geographic density information across performances. They can

use the expected timing of ticket sales as benchmark measures to compare with realized sales. In

this way, they can be aware of possible sales deviation in an advance-selling period rather than in

the week of performance. Additionally, it is also important for operational and financial

planning because event marketers can adjust their concession and security throughout an

advance-selling period to make sure a performance is not over or under staffed. Moreover, they

can have a better knowledge with the cash flows based on the expected timing of ticket sales.

Regarding the sales bump as a result of pre-Christmas shopping effect (|
j
), we find that

geographic density, number of advance selling weeks, and expected performance attractiveness

all contribute positive effects (¸
13
= 4.84; ¸
33
= 0.97; ¸
43
= 2.45). Yet, temporal density does not



52

have such an effect. In other words, performances of higher attractiveness tend to experience

earlier timing of ticket sales. The attractiveness comes from the expected individual

performance attractiveness (due to the days of week effect) and the geographic density. Because

performances of shorter geographic distance are perceived more attractive even after controlling

for individual performance attractiveness, these performances are more salient to consumers as

Christmas gifts
2
.

2.6.3 Endogeneity in Performance Scheduling

As we have mentioned, the scheduling decision is likely endogenous and dependent on

expected performance attractiveness or effects of geographic and temporal scheduling. As such,

the results discussed above are only managerially meaningful if we accommodate the potential

endogenous scheduling decisions. Table 2-7 indicates some evidence about the endogeneity in

performance scheduling. Specifically, event marketers consider the expected performance

attractiveness when designing a temporal schedule (|
12
= 0.26). When they expect a performance

to be more attractive, they schedule more performances similar to this one. Consequently, there

are more performances scheduled temporally close to each other, resulting in higher temporal

density. However, event marketers neither incorporate performance attractiveness when

designing a geographic schedule, nor do they incorporate the geographic and temporal effects.

This result implies that event marketers may primarily rely on performance attractiveness in their

scheduling decision whether they are aware of the scheduling effects.

Table 2-7: Results for Endogenous Performance Scheduling







2
We considered other covariates, such as the cumulative sales of earlier performances, but found that it had no
significant impact on the timing of ticket sales.
53

2.7 Policy Simulation

To demonstrate the scheduling effects on ticket sales, we conduct a policy simulation by

varying the geographic schedule (Scenario 1) or temporal schedule (Scenario 2) to compare with

the current setting. To make a fair comparison and restrict a new schedule within the same

geographic and temporal range, we only re-allocate one performance, keep the rest unchanged,

and evaluate the differences in ticket sales for the target performance as well as the entire market.

2.7.1 Scenario 1: Geographic Change

According to results of the number of ticket sales, performances generate more sales

volume when they are scheduled in the same or proximate venues and have a higher geographic

density. Hence, in Scenario 1 we reschedule a performance from Venue 2 (Nassau Coliseum) to

Venue 3 (Madison Square Garden) in Figure 2-9, the most densely scheduled venue in our

dataset. As a result, geographic density of this performance increases. We also keep the same

performance date to ensure unchanged performance attractiveness and temporal density.

Figure 2-12 presents the impact of schedule changes on ticket sales. After relocating a

performance from Nassau Coliseum to Madison Square Garden, its ticket sales increase from

5,102 to 7,132, resulting in a difference of 2,031 tickets (which is 24% of average ticket sales per

performance). On the other hand, the overall market sales increase from 532,285 under the

existing schedule to 535,424 tickets in Scenario 1. Note that the 3,140 increases in market sales

are greater than 2,031 increases in a target performance. This increase in market sales provides

the evidence of market expansion. Hence, a geographic schedule after minor changes can attract

more consumers to the rescheduled performance and increase the market penetration.

Figure 2-12: Effect of Schedule Changes on Ticket Sales





54

Relocating the target performance to a different venue also changes the timing of ticket

sales. Under the modified schedule, the cumulative ticket sales of the target performance reach

60% of total sales after 12 weeks, yet the same performance only sells 28% under the original

schedule. Figure 2-13 shows that weekly sales of this performance arrive at a different rate and

results in different patterns. This implies that any monitoring or benchmarking of early ticket

sales needs to incorporate the geographic density in a schedule.

Figure 2-13: Effect of Schedule Changes on Timing of Ticket Sales

2.7.2 Scenario 2: Temporal Changes

According to our results from studying the number of ticket sales, the second learning is

to disperse performance dates to accommodate more consumers and increase ticket sales.

Therefore, in Scenario 2, we reschedule the same target performance in Scenario 1 to two weeks

earlier. Yet, we keep its venue location and day of week constant. In this way, this target

performance has the same level of performance attractiveness and geographic density, yet with a

lower level of temporal density.

In contrast with Scenario 1 where we see substantial changes in the number and timing of

ticket sales, we observe much smaller changes in Scenario 2. This is consistent with the smaller

parameter values for temporal density compared to those for geographic density (see Table 2-5

and Table 2-6). Specifically, ticket sales for the rescheduled performance increase very slightly

by 385 tickets under the modified temporal schedule and the difference in total sales in the

market is also quite small (772 tickets). Figure 2-12 also shows minimal differences in the

percentage of tickets sold in the first 12 weeks. Hence, these results imply that geographic

scheduling is more important than temporal scheduling. A geographic schedule has a greater

influence on the number and timing of ticket sales than does a temporal schedule.



55

2.8 Conclusions

2.8.1 Summary

In the live entertainment industry, scheduling performances and estimating ticket demand

are two primary tasks facing event marketers. Because these tasks have been treated as two

independent problems by event marketers and marketing researchers, this essay aims to bridge

performance scheduling and demand estimation by examining the potential impact of scheduling

on ticket sales.

According to different streams of literatures, we find that it is possible to see closely

scheduled performances selling more than distantly scheduled performances, yet it is also

possible to see the opposite effect. Therefore, we allow these two possibilities and empirically

test the effect of scheduling characteristics on the number and timing of ticket sales. Specifically,

we characterize performances of the same event by their venue locations and performance dates.

Using their scheduling characteristics, we construct two density measures (i.e., geographic and

temporal density) to capture how close in distance or time performances are scheduled to each

other. Then, we model the number and timing of ticket sales as a function of these density

measures. In addition, we also control for a possible endogeneity in case event marketers

incorporate market responses in their scheduling process.

We contact a national ticket seller to obtain a dataset of a live performance event and use

its ticket sales to examine the impact of its scheduling characteristics on ticket sales. This event

had 70 performances across four venues in the New York metropolitan market and performed

between March and June 2004.

Our results indicate that performances of different scheduling characteristics sell

differently in terms of their number and timing of ticket sales. Specifically, we find that the



56

effect of geographic scheduling differs from the effect of temporal scheduling. Performances

scheduled closely in distance not only sell more tickets but also sell tickets at a faster rate. In

contrast, performances scheduled sparsely in time sell more tickets but do not have an impact on

the timing of sales.

Our explanation for the observed effects is that event marketers may schedule

performances to signal the desirability of venues and accommodate consumers' uncertain

attendance timing. In this way, performances in the desired venues and along a wider temporal

stretch are more attractive to consumers (even after we have controlled the individual

performance attractiveness).

2.8.2 Limitations and Next Steps

Although this essay shows significant effects of geographic and temporal scheduling on

ticket sales, the results are for one market only. However, event marketers often need to make

scheduling decisions for more than one market. Thus, it is not clear whether the results in essay

one hold in other markets. Hence, the objective of essay two is to use all performance schedules

of the same event to investigate heterogeneous market responses and identify explanatory factors.

We discuss essay two in the next chapter.



















57

Table and Figures

Table 2-1: Description of Data Fields
Category in the Data Fields
Event
Identification number
Performance date
Venue location
Transaction types



Sales date
Channel types



Price levels
Price paid



Daily tickets
Description
Name of event
Used to differentiate repeat performances of the same event
Month-Date-Year
Name of a venue and its location (City and State)
Indicate individual purchases, group purchases, school
purchases and so on
Month-Date-Year
Six channel types: Primary Box Office, Secondary Box Office,
Hermes (Automatic phone), Internet, Outlet, and Phone.
Label of price levels
Indicates the face value, facility charges, service charges, and
the total price paid
Number of tickets sold



























58

Table 2-2: Summary of Ticket Sales
Mean Std Dev Min Max
Total Ticket Sales 8,316 3,525 1,827 15,810

Ticket Sales by Stage
Early Sales 24% 14% 3% 59%
(one month prior)
Late Sales 33% 9% 15% 53%
(2-4 weeks prior)
Spot Sales 42% 14% 11% 75%
(performance week)










































59

Table 2-3: Descriptive Statistics of Covariates
Description Mean Std Dev Min Max
GEO Geographic Density 0.368 0.185 0.128 0.540
TMP Temporal Density 0.118 0.022 0.063 0.144
FRIDAY Friday performance 0.157 0.367 0 1
SATURDAY Saturday performance 0.300 0.462 0 1
















































SUNDAY
T
Sunday performance
Number of advance-selling weeks











































60
0.286
15
0.455
2.044
0
11
1
19
Table 2-4: Benchmark Models and Model Fit
Benchmark Model Proposed Model
1 2 3
Performance attractiveness
City effects
Population around venues
Model Fit
DIC 157,134 156,459 156,220 156,221












































61

Table 2-5: Results for the Number of Ticket Sales
Parameter Description Median (STD)
Scheduling Effect
u
1
Effect of geographic density 0.32 (0.05)**
u
2
Effect of temporal density -0.14 (0.05)**


Expected performance attractiveness: E[V
j
]
o
0
o
1
o
2
o
3


o
2
Baseline value of event
Friday effect
Saturday effect
Sunday effect


Variance of performance attractiveness
-6.32
0.15
0.35
0.34


5.45
(0.12)**
(0.13)
(0.12)**
(0.13)**


(1.02)

** significant at the 95% highest posterior density


































62

Table 2-6: Results for the Timing of Ticket Sales
Parameter Description Median (STD)
Weibull slope parameter: log(ì
j
)
¸
01
¸
11
¸
21
¸
31

¸
41
Intercept
Effect of geographic density
Effect of temporal density
Number of advance-selling weeks
Expected performance attractiveness
3.11
-7.56
0.67
-1.08
-0.63
(3.62)
(2.20)**
(2.99)
(0.21)**
(0.77)
Weibull shape parameter: log(c
j
)
¸
02

¸
12

¸
22

¸
32

¸
42
Intercept
Effect of geographic density
Effect of temporal density
Number of advance-selling weeks
Expected performance attractiveness
-0.64
0.93
0.23
0.05
-0.16
(1.03)
(0.24)**
(0.98)
(0.02)**
(0.17)
Time-varying pre-Christmas shopping effect:|
j
¸
03

¸
13
¸
23
¸
33
¸
43
Intercept
Effect of geographic density
Effect of temporal density
Number of advance-selling weeks
Expected performance attractiveness
2.09
4.84
1.63
0.97
2.45
(3.24)
(2.51)*
(3.04)
(0.28)**
(0.81)**


Variance-covariance matrix: ¿
1

log(ì
j
) log(c
j
) |
j
log(ì
j
) 17.38 -1.3 -11.49
log(c
j
) 0.13 0.77
| 12.58
** significant at the 95% highest posterior density
* significant at the 90% highest posterior density
















63

Table 2-7: Results for Endogenous Performance Scheduling
Parameter Description Median (STD)
Expected geographic density: m
1
|
01
Intercept 0.18 (0.91)
|
11
Expected performance attractiveness 0.22 (0.15)
|
21
Effect of geographic density 0.04 (0.97)


Expected temporal density: m
2
|
02
Intercept -0.61 (0.75)
|
12
Expected value of performance 0.26 (0.12)**
|
22
Effect of temporal density -0.03 (1.01)


Variance-covariance matrix: ¿
2

m
1
m
2
m
1
0.36 0.07
m
2
0.06

** significant at the 95% highest posterior density






























64

Figure 2-1: Conceptual Framework of Spatial Decomposition



Scheduling Characteristics:
Geographic
Density



Geographic
Effect
Temporal
Density



Temporal
Effect


Endogeneity


Attractiveness of
Individual Performances


Ticket Sales:
(1) Number of Tickets Sold
(2) Timing of Ticket Sales




































65

Figure 2-2: Model Overview



Scheduling Characteristics
(Geographic and Temporal Density)









Number of Ticket Sales Timing of Ticket Sales







































66

Figure 2-3: Probability of Ticket Sales over Time
1
0.9 0.8 0.7
0.6 0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0










Advance Selling Week
Case 1
Case 2
Case 3

































67

P
r
o
b
a
b
i
l
i
t
y


Figure 2-4: Sales Distribution by Performances


12



10



8



6



4



2
Mean =8315.70
Std. Dev. =3525.
329
N =70
0
0.00 5000.00 10000.00 15000.00 20000.00
sales


























68

F
r
e
q
u
e
n
c
y


Figure 2-5: Sales Distribution by Days of Week

18000

16000

14000

12000

10000

8000

6000

4000

2000

0
Monday Tuesday Wednesday Thursday Friday Saturday Sunday
































69

T
i
c
k
e
t

S
a
l
e
s


Figure 2-6: Weekly Sales Pattern of a Performance
7000 6000
5000 4000
3000 2000
1000
0



Advance Selling Week (t)






































70

T
i
c
k
e
t

s
a
l
e
s


Figure 2-7: Heterogeneity in Sales Pattern Across Performances

80%
70% 60%
50% 40%
30% 20%
10%
0
%
1 month prior 2?4 weeks prior last week
Advance Selling Period



































71

%

o
f

t
o
t
a
l

t
i
c
k
e
t

s
a
l
e
s


Figure 2-8: Venue Locations and Driving Distances



1
46
16
29








2
67 3
67
90



4 Note: distance in miles
Source: Google Maps
Note: the number in Figure 2-8 indicates the sequence that the event travelled.
That is, the event went to Venue 1, 2, 3, and 4, respectively.


































72

Figure 2-9: Summary of Geographic Distance


40
35
Madison Square
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
Garden



Continental
Arena







Nassau Coliseum




Sovereign Bank
Arena
0 10 20 30 40 50 60
Average distance to other venues (in miles)


































73

N
u
m
b
e
r

o
f

p
e
r
f
o
r
m
a
n
c
e
s

i
n

a

v
e
n
u
e


Figure 2-10: Summary of Temporal Distance
70

60

50

40

30

20

10

0
2/23/2004 3/14/2004 4/3/2004 4/23/2004 5/13/2004 6/2/2004 6/22/2004
Performance date





































74

d
a
t
e
s

(
i
n

d
a
y
s
)


A
v
e
r
a
g
e

d
i
s
t
a
n
c
e

t
o

o
t
h
e
r

p
e
r
f
o
r
m
a
n
c
e



Figure 2-11: Impact of Geographic Density on Timing of Ticket Sales


0.16
0.14 0.12

0.10
0.08
Cumulative ticket sales= 25%



mean GEO +1 SD
0.06
0.04

0.02
0.00

Cumulative ticket sales= 11%
mean GEO
mean GEO ?1 SD


Cumulative ticket sales= 7%
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17
Advance Selling Week



































75

%

o
f

t
o
t
a
l

t
i
c
k
e
t
s


Figure 2-12: Effect of Schedule Changes on Ticket Sales


3500
+3140
3000
2500
+2031
2000
1500 1000
500
0















+385














+772
Scenario 1 Scenario 2

target performance market sales

Current Schedule:
Target performance=5,102 Market sales=532,285






























76

C
h
a
n
g
e
s

i
n

T
i
c
k
e
t

S
a
l
e
s


Figure 2-13: Effect of Schedule Changes on Timing of Ticket Sales

18
%
16
%
14
%
12
%
10
%
8
%
6
%
4
%
2
%
0
%

Cumulative ticket sales= 60% of total





Cumulative ticket sales= 28% of total
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Advance Selling Week

current scenario 1 scenario 2























%

o
f

T
o
t
a
l

S
a
l
e
s

A
r
r
i
v
e
d












77

3 Essay 2: Heterogeneous Market Responses to Performance Schedules and


Their Explanatory Factors




3.1 Introduction

In the first essay, we characterize multiple performances of a single event by their venue

locations and performance dates to understand how their geographic and temporal scheduling

characteristics influence their ticket sales. Using ticket sales of a live performing event in the

New York metropolitan market, we find that the effect of geographic scheduling differs from the

effect of temporal scheduling. Performances scheduled in nearby venues not only sell more

tickets but also sell tickets at a faster rate. In contrast, performances scheduled distantly in time

sell more tickets but do not have an impact on the timing of sales.

However, event marketers often need to make scheduling decisions for more than one

market. Although our finding in essay one has rich implications for event marketers, it is unclear

whether event marketers can apply this finding to all markets. For example, the event analyzed

in essay one had 70 performances in four venues for 32 days in the New York metropolitan

market. However, when it travelled to other markets such as Norfolk, Virginia, it had 19

performances in two venues for 10 days. It also had 21 performances in one venue for 10 days in

the Atlanta area. Thus, performance schedules can vary across markets and these schedules may

not have the same effect on ticket sales across markets. Even if a schedule is the same across

markets, these markets may not respond to their schedule identically. This limitation in essay

one hence motivates our second essay to examine the effect of performance schedules across

markets.





78

Although several studies in the event tickets literature examine descriptive drivers for

event ticket sales, very limited research focuses on examining heterogeneous market responses

(Moore 1966; Weinberg and Shachmut 1978; Havlena and Holak 1988; Reddy et al 1998).

Hence, the objective of essay two is to use all performance schedules of the same event to

investigate heterogeneous market responses and identify explanatory factors. It is important

because events do not always go to the same set of markets when they are on tour. A long

lasting event may go on tour several times and travels to a different set of markets each time.

Hence, once the heterogeneity in market responses and explanatory drivers are known, event

marketers could infer a likely response in a new market or select markets for touring based on

expected market responses.

To accomplish our research objective, we first conduct a preliminary analysis to analyze

all performance schedules and examine their impact on the number of ticket sales. After

applying the model developed in essay one to the entire dataset and estimating market responses

iteratively across markets, we find that the effect of geographic scheduling differs from the effect

of temporal scheduling and this difference is consistent across markets. In terms of the

geographic scheduling, performances scheduled in close venues sell more ticket sales than

sparsely scheduled ones, but this result only hold for markets that use multiple venues.

Regarding the temporal scheduling, in contrast, performances scheduled distantly in time sell

more than the densely scheduled ones.

Although we find consistent scheduling effects from the preliminary results, we also

observe the market responses are of different magnitudes. In other words, some markets are

more responsive to geographic (temporal) schedules than other markets. To identify the factors

that explain these differences across markets, we extend the model developed in essay one to not



79

only examine market-specific response parameters but also investigate observed and unobserved

heterogeneity via the hierarchical Bayesian approach. In addition, we also control for the

possible endogeneity in the performance scheduling process. Among several marketing

characteristics, we choose the size of market population as the first explanatory factor. We also

examine characteristics of a touring event to understand whether participating markets that are

adjacent to each other and the order that an event travels across affect the magnitude of

scheduling effects.

We use the same family event mentioned in essay one and analyze all of its performance

schedules in the dataset to test our model. Because this event sequentially performed 449 times

in 50 cities in the U.S. domestic market between January and June 2004, we aggregate these 50

cities to 42 designated market areas (which will be discussed in detail in the data section). As a

result, there are six markets where the event performed in multiple venues yet all 42 markets

have some variations in their temporal schedules.

Our results show that market and additional scheduling characteristics can both explain

the differences across market responses. First, when a market has a bigger population, the

effects of days of week and baseline attractiveness are attenuated. Our explanation is that

usually there are more events offered to a bigger market than to a smaller one. Consumers in a

bigger market may be used to seeing several competing events offered simultaneously and

having a variety of events to choose from. Hence, they are less responsive to an event no matter

on which day of week it may be on as compared to consumers in a smaller market.

Second, we find the additional scheduling characteristics can partly explain

heterogeneous market responses. With respect to a current market, after an event travels to more

of its geographically adjacent markets, the current market is less responsive to its baseline



80

attractiveness and temporal schedule. A possible reason is that after an event has gone to more

geographically adjacent markets, its newness wears out but its reputation might accumulate over

time. As a result, consumers may refer to other measures such as word of mouth to make their

purchase decisions rather than refer to the baseline attractiveness and its temporal schedule.

Moreover, after an event perform in several markets (whether these markets are adjacent

or not), a market in which an event performs later tends to respond more favorably to a Sunday

performance. Our explanation is that after an event has lasted longer and gone to more markets,

its reputation, or word of mouth, accumulates over time (Reddy et al 1981) even though its

newness may wear out. Because a Sunday performance tends to be the last performance in a

market (at least in the case of our dataset), consumers might think Sunday as their "last

opportunity" to enjoy this event before it leaves for another market. As a result, a market in a

later temporal sequence has a stronger Sunday effect.

We also find that the nature of performance schedules is endogenous. Different from

essay one that endogeneity is found only in a temporal schedule, we find in essay two that

geographic and temporal schedules are both done endogenously after we pool all performances

across markets for analysis. When event marketers expect high performance attractiveness, they

schedule more performances in all venues and tend to allocate those performances around

weekends or along a limited time span. As a result, on average, performances have a shorter

geographic and temporal distance to others and have higher density values. Moreover, when

event marketers understand that consumers prefer performances on dispersed dates because of

uncertain timing of attendance, they decrease the number of weekend performances and/or

disperse performance dates. Consequently, performances in a temporal schedule have lower





81

temporal density values. Since we have accounted for this endogeneity in the estimation process,

the results we present here are unbiased.

The rest of essay two is organized as follows. First, we conduct a preliminary analysis

using all performances observed across markets to show heterogeneous market responses to

performance schedules. Second, we review extant literature to find possible reasons for

heterogeneity and propose our conceptual framework. In the next section, we present the

modeling structure extended from the first essay and discuss the dataset in details. After the

model estimation and benchmark comparison, we present our results and conclude this essay

with limitations and next steps.




3.2 Preliminary Analysis

As described in essay one, a family event went to 50 cities on 245 dates for 449

performances between January and June 2004 (see §2.4.1 Description of Events for more details).

Among which, several cities are within the same metropolitan area and show richer variations in

geographic and temporal schedules. To test whether markets have heterogeneous responses to

their performance schedules, we conduct a preliminary analysis to run the model in equations (5),

(6), and (14) for one market at a time and examine their market specific parameters.

More specifically, we use the designated market area (DMA) to aggregate 50 cities into

42 markets (see the data section for full descriptions) and summarize the market information in

Table 3-1. As Table 3-1 shows, we sort markets by their first performance date and assign a

unique market identification number. Every market has its information listed regarding its first

and last performance dates, number of performances, length of performing period, and venue

usage. Hence, for performances within a market, we characterize these performances by their



82

venue locations and performance dates. Then, we follow the equations (1) and (2) in essay one

to compute their geographic and temporal density and understand how densely or sparsely these

performances are scheduled. Consequently, for each market, we model ticket sales of its

performances as a function of their density measures and performance attractiveness while

controlling for a possible endogeneity in performance scheduling.

Table 3-1: Summary of Performance Schedules across Markets

After iteratively estimating the model across 42 markets, we find that the days of week

represent performance attractiveness and increase ticket sales (o
0
ranges from -3.82 to -8.23; o
1


ranges from 0.10 to 0.95; o
2
ranges from 0.24 to 1.48; o
3
ranges from 0.13 to 1.09). Moreover,

the effect of geographic scheduling differs from the effect of temporal scheduling. Performances

scheduled in nearby venues sell more tickets than those scheduled in distant venues (u
1
ranges

from 0.92 to 4.29). However, this result only holds for markets that use multiple venues. On the

other hand, performances scheduled dispersed across dates sell more than the those scheduled

close in time (u
2
ranges from -0.04 to -2.92). We summarize these market-specific parameters in

Table 3-2.

Table 3-2: Summary of Market Responses to Performance Schedules

According to our preliminary analysis, we confirm consistent yet heterogeneous market

responses to performance schedules. To understand why market responses are different, we

review extant literature that suggests potential explanatory factors for this heterogeneity.












83

3.3 Literature Review and Conceptual Framework

3.3.1 Literature Review

Consumers are different individuals and their preferences and decisions often differ from

one another. However, as the proverb says, "birds of a feather flock together." It is very

common to observe consumers who have similar tastes living in similar areas and making similar

purchase decisions. Accordingly, when marketers offer a variety of products to consumers, they

often expect heterogeneous consumer responses across zip codes, counties, states, or

metropolitan markets.

Heterogeneity in the unit of analysis is commonly studied in marketing and the entities

include individual consumers, products, firms, markets, and countries. For example, consumers

who have different demographic characteristics or live in different zip codes make different

choices regarding automobiles (Yang and Allenby 2002), book formats (i.e., Print vs. PDF; Jank

and Kannak 2005), or adoptions of online grocer (Choi, Hui, and Bell 2009). Their shopping

behaviors also differ across product types (e.g., motels of high, medium, or low quality, Mazzeo

2002; department stores of upscale, midscale, or discount, Vitorino 2007), store formats (e.g.,

supermarkets, hypermarkets, and discount stores, González-Benito 2005; discounted or regular

retailers, Zhu et al 2007), and brand names (e.g., Wal-mart, K-mart, Target, Zhu and Singh 2009;

Zhu et al 2009). Besides examining the heterogeneity at an individual level, researchers can also

summarize consumer responses across zip codes (Yang and Allenby 2002; Jank and Kannan

2005), metropolitan statistical areas (Zhu and Singh 2009), or countries (Elberse and Eliashberg

2003) to study heterogeneity at an aggregate level.

One way to account for heterogeneity in empirical analyses is to specify individual-

specific parameters (Corning and Levy 2002; González-Benito 2005; Mazzeo 2002; Vitorino



84

2007; Moe and Fader 2009; Zhu and Singh 2009; Zhu et al 2009). For example, Corning and

Levy (2002) specified venue-specific parameters when examining ticket sales across venues to

understand whether consumers of those venues have different responses to product offerings. In

the retail locations, Mazzeo (2002) specified type-specific effects of spatial competition to study

whether motels of low, medium, or high quality types have different spatial effects on

profitability. In addition, Zhu and Singh (2009) used brand-specific parameters to examine

asymmetric competition effects among Wal-mart, K-mart, and Target.

Although heterogeneity has been extensively studied in many contexts, most of prior

studies in the event tickets literature have not yet examined heterogeneous market responses. In

other words, researchers assume the effects of days of week, prices, and promotions are

homogeneous across venues, events, or performances (Moore 1966; Weinberg and Shachmut

1978; Havlena and Holak 1988; Reddy et al 1998). Although Corning and Levy (2002) and Moe

and Fader (2009) are the two exceptions where Corning and Levy (2002) allowed parameters to

be venue specific and Moe and Fader (2009) specified parameters varied with events and price

tiers, they did not identify explanatory factors for their proposed heterogeneity. Given that we

have found the heterogeneous market responses in the preliminary analysis, the objective of

essay two is to identify explanatory factors to explain the differences across markets.

3.3.2 Conceptual Framework

In our conceptual framework, we first discuss possible market characteristics that may

explain differences across markets. Then, we discuss characteristics of a touring event that may

provide context dependent reasons for response heterogeneity.








85

Market Characteristics

When the analysis is made at a market level rather than at an individual level, the first

issue is to define what a market is. Depending on the context of interest, a market can be a

metropolitan statistical area (MSA; Zhu et al 2007), a designated market area defined by A.C.

Nielsen (DMA; Carlyle, Slater, and Chakroff 2008), or a retail trade area (Bronnenberg and Mela

2004). Then, researchers try to find the market characteristics that may explain the difference to

some extent.

In general, metropolitan areas are assumed more similar to other MSAs than to rural

areas, and the similarity or differences may be due to the population size, population density,

income, education, household size, household values, commute time to work, etc. (Mazzeo 2002;

Vitorino 2007; Zhu et al 2007; Zhu and Singh 2009; Zhu et al 2009). For this reason, we

propose that market characteristics can explain the heterogeneous market responses in our

preliminary analysis.

Additional Scheduling Characteristics

We refer to additional scheduling characteristics as characteristics of a touring event. For

example, one characteristic is that its performing group travels from one market to another.

Because this distribution mechanism follows the sequential distribution approach (Elberse and

Eliashberg 2003; Bronnenberg and Mela 2004), we think sequential distribution literature may

provide context dependent characteristics to explain why consumers in different markets react to

performance schedules differently.

Extant works in sequential distribution have focused on the effect of geographic

adjacency on market adoption (Bronnenberg and Mela 2004) and the effect of release timing on

box-office revenues (Elberse and Eliashberg 2003). When Bronnenberg and Mela (2004)



86

studied the spatial evolution of a new product adoption across markets, they found manufacturers

tend to enter markets that are geographically adjacent to a current market. In other words, the

initial market serves as a lead market and its lead market effect rolls out sequentially to

geographically adjacent markets.

On the other hand, the release timing in the distribution also influences how well a

product sells. For example, Elberse and Eliashberg (2003) studied motion pictures to investigate

the issue of release timing between the U.S. market and foreign markets. Although they only

examined the effect of release timing between the initial market and following foreign markets

rather than the effect of release timing along the entire sequence, they still found that shortening

the time lag between two markets increases the revenues of a later market.

Therefore, the sequential distribution literature has traditionally discussed the roles of

geographic adjacency and release timing as important covariates. Whether the geographic

adjacency and release timing in the distribution explains different market responses still remains

unknown and deserves further investigation. Similarly, a live performance event follows a

temporal sequence to travel across markets. Each market along the sequence has different

release timing and some of these markets are geographically adjacent to one another. It is

important to evaluate its geographic adjacency and temporal sequence to understand whether

these additional scheduling characteristics explain different markets responses to performance

schedules. Therefore, we incorporate market characteristics and additional scheduling

characteristics to explain different market responses across markets.

In short, we summarize our conceptual framework in Figure 3-1. Similar to essay one,

we examine the impact of geographic and temporal scheduling on the number of ticket sales and

control for the performance attractiveness through its days of week. In addition, we also control



87

for the possible endogeneity in performance scheduling. Finally, we examine whether and how

market and additional scheduling characteristics explain response heterogeneity across markets.

Figure 3-1: Conceptual Framework



3.4 Model Development

3.4.1 Model Overview

Our model development consists of four steps. First, we use the geographic and temporal

density measures to capture the scheduling characteristics of performances in their associated

markets and understand how densely or sparsely these performances are scheduled. Second,

within each market, we specify market-specific parameters and model ticket sales at a

performance level as a function of these density measures and performance attractiveness. Third,

we control for a possible endogeneity between performance schedules and expected market

responses. Finally, we employ a hierarchical Bayesian (HB) approach to incorporate the

heterogeneity in market responses. Among these four steps, the first three steps are adapted from

essay one, yet the fourth step is the model extension in essay two.

Although the HB approach is not the only method to study heterogeneous market

responses and the latent class analysis (Kamakura and Russell 1989) may be another appropriate

alternative, we choose the HB approach because it can accommodate unobserved heterogeneity

across markets (Rossi and Allenby 2003) in addition to the heterogeneity explained by market

characteristics and additional scheduling characteristics.

3.4.2 Scheduling Characteristics and the Number of Ticket Sales

To begin with, we refer to equations (1) and (2) in essay one to capture the scheduling

characteristics by their geographic and temporal density for all performances in their markets.




88

Then, we refer to equation (5) to rewrite the sales share of performances (and the share of non-

buyers) within a market with market-specific parameters:

exp
(16)



where
1
¿
J exp
? ?

o o FRIDAY o SATURDAY o SUNDAY c ; c ~N 0, o

where P
m
(j) is the sales share of performance j in market m, V
jm
is its performance attractiveness

(which is a function of days of week), GEO
jm
and TMP
jm
represent the geographic and temporal

density measures, and o
0m
, o
1m
, o
2m
, o
3m
, u
1m
, and u
2m
are market specific parameters. Therefore,

among J
m
performances in market m, their parameters are homogeneous within a market but

heterogeneous across markets. Using the population size in a target market (POP
m
) and the sales

share of a performance, we can calculate the expected ticket sales of a performance (i.e.,

), the market penetration rate of this event (i.e., ¿ ), and the


size of non-buyer segment (i.e., 1 ¿ ).


3.4.3 Endogeneity in Performance Scheduling

Next, we account for a possible endogeneity in performance scheduling by revising

equation (14) as follows:

logit
(17) E where ~ 0, , 1,2
logit

where E[V
jm
] is the expected performance attractiveness of performance j in market m, u
1m
, and

u
2m
represent the effects of geographic and temporal scheduling, and
0
,
1
, and 2are the

parameters of interest. When 1or 2is significant, scheduling is endogenous but has been

taken into account. Note that the specification of equation (17) is the same as equation (14)



89

except that we specify an independent relationship between geographic and temporal density. In

this way, when an event performs in a single venue within a market and only has variation in its

temporal schedule, we can directly drop GEO
jm
in equations (16) and (17) and just investigate a

possible endogeneity in temporal scheduling.

3.4.4 Use of the HB Approach for Response Heterogeneity

Finally, we take the HB approach to explain differences of response parameters across

markets and specify these market-specific parameters as a function of their unobserved

heterogeneity and observed market characteristics and additional scheduling characteristics:




(18) where ~ 0, , 1,2,3,4,5,6




whereA
m
is a 6-by-1 vector that contains the market-specific parameters (o
0m
, o
1m
, o
2m
, o
3m
, u
1m
,

and u
2m
) in equation (16), X
m
is a k-by-1 vector that includes market characteristics and

additional scheduling characteristics,| is a 6-by-k matrix that represents the effects for these

characteristics, and is a vector of random errors for the unobserved heterogeneity.




3.5 Data

We contact a national ticket seller to obtain a dataset of two family events and analyze

ticket sales for one event in this dissertation (see §2.4.1 for more information about this event).

In short, this event sequentially performed 449 times in 50 cities in the U.S. domestic market

between January and June 2004. In essay one, we only used ticket sales in the New York

metropolitan market. In essay two, we analyze all performances in the dataset to investigate

heterogeneity in market responses.


90

3.5.1 Definition of Markets

Among 50 venues in the dataset, some venues are in the same MSAs, some are the only

venues in their MSAs, and others are in rural areas (i.e., non-MSAs). To avoid information

losses after aggregating venues to MSAs, we aggregate venues by their designated market areas

(DMAs) for urban and rural cities. The definition and classification of DMAs are proposed by

Nielsen Media Research (Weiner 2000) where each DMA consists of several counties and

consumers in the same DMA receive the same TV broadcasting and media messages (Carlyle,

Slater, and Chakroff 2008). The advantage of aggregating data by DMAs is that, suppose

marketing activities for an event are planned at a DMA level, consumers within the same DMA

are potentially aware of this event even though they may live in a rural area far away from a

venue.

Hence, we refer to a website by the Truck Ads
®
(www.truckads.com) that disaggregates

the U.S. market into several DMAs and lists all individual counties within each DMA. Figure 3-

2 provides an example of the Orlando DMA in Florida. As the map shows, there are nine

counties within this DMA. According to the venue locations in our dataset (i.e., names of venues,

cities, and states), we can identify in which DMA a venue is and which counties are in this DMA.

As a result, we aggregate 50 venues into 42 DMAs in Table 3-3. Figure 3-3 also shows the

locations of these DMAs. Each shaded area represents a DMA and a number in a box is its

market identification number assigned in Table 3-1.

Figure 3-2: Example of a DMA and its county information


Table 3-3: Venue Locations and their Associated DMAs


Figure 3-3: DMA locations




91

3.5.2 Description of Performance Schedules across Markets

According to the DMAs and performance information in our dataset, we summarize the

temporal schedule in each market into Table 3-1 by its first and last dates, length of performing

period, total number of performances, and venue usage in a market. On average, there were

10.69 performances in a market, lasted for 5.79 days, and used 1.19 venues.

Temporal Sequence of the Event Distribution

In Table 3-1, we sort the temporal schedules by their first performance date and observe

the temporal sequence of the event distribution. In general, this event first performed in

Tallahassee in January (market ID= 1), Atlanta in February (market ID= 12), New York in

March (market ID= 16), St. Paul in May (market ID= 33), and Tucson in June (market ID = 42)
3
.

Table 3-1 also indicates a few incidences where two or three markets started performances on the

same date or one to two days apart. For instance, the event had performances in Providence

(market ID= 26) and Worcester (market ID= 27) between May 1 and May 9 while having

performances in La Crosse (market ID= 25) between May 4 and May 5. Therefore, it is likely

that there were up to three performing groups touring in the same period. Because we cannot

identify which groups performed in which markets, we assume that the performing quality is

constant across performing groups and do not affect how markets respond to their performance

schedules. Hence, we analyze all 42 markets together regardless of their performing groups.

Venue Usage of the Event across Markets

In terms of the venue usage across markets, among 42 DMAs, only six markets had more

than one venue in use. These markets were the Greenville-Asheville, Raleigh-Fayetteville,

Norfolk-Hampton, Champaign-Springfield, New York, and Philadelphia DMAs. Moreover,



3
This event kept on travelling after performing in Tucson. However, the performance schedules available in the
dataset were truncated up to June 2004. Thus, we examine the performance schedules of these 42 markets only.
92

except for the New York market that scheduled performances across four venues, the rest had

performances scheduled in two venues. We also find that the event did not always perform in

these venues consecutively within a market. Sometimes the event offered all performances in

one market and then left for a new market, but sometimes it offered a few performances in one

venue and then provided more after a period. Specifically, this event completed all scheduled

performances consecutively in the markets of Norfolk-Hampton, Champaign-Springfield, and

Philadelphia. However, in the market of Greenville-Asheville and Raleigh-Fayetteville, after the

event performed in one venue, it left for other markets and then came back three to four months

later. In the New York market, it performed in three venues consecutively, left for other markets,

and then returned seven weeks later.

Geographic Adjacency of Markets

Upon a closer look of these markets and their locations in Figure 3-3, we also find that

this event had an extensive tour in the East Coast and some of the Mid-West markets. Moreover,

this event sometimes went to near or adjacent markets but occasionally traveled to an isolated

market. For example, this event went to Orlando (market ID=2) and Tampa (market ID=3) in a

consecutive order but went to an isolated market in Tucson (market ID=42).

Descriptions of Ticket Sales

Table 3-4 summarizes the average ticket sales at a performance level and its total ticket

sales at a market level. Across all markets, a performance can sell an average of 3,825 tickets

with a standard deviation being 1,162 tickets. However, depending on in which market a

performance is, it can sell as many as 8,316 tickets in New York (market ID= 16) or as little as

585 tickets in Madison (market ID= 28). In terms of ticket sales at a market level, an event can

sell an average of 51,905 tickets with a standard deviation being 90,992. Although it seems that



93

markets that use multiple venues experience more ticket sales (e.g., New York and Philadelphia

are ranked as the top two best selling markets), markets of a single venue usage do not

necessarily sell less. For example, the event performed in only one venue in Atlanta (market

ID=12) had market sales ranked at the third place. Moreover, Miami is also a single venue DMA

but its market sales exceeded the DMAs of Greenville-Ashville (market ID=9) and Champaign-

Springfield (market ID=20). Because the focus of essay two is on sales at performance level and

response heterogeneity across markets, we will address the issue of market sales in essay three.

Table 3-4: Summary of Ticket Sales across Markets

3.5.3 Covariate Specifications

Before we estimate our model, we still have to measure geographic and temporal density

as scheduling characteristics, create the days of week indicators for performance attractiveness,

and compute the population size of the target markets. Moreover, we need to select market

characteristics and measure the geographic adjacency and temporal sequence for the additional

scheduling characteristics. Hence, we discuss each covariate in turn.

Geographic and Temporal Density Measures

First, we calculate the geographic density for performances in markets (GEO
jm
) where

more than one venue is used. These markets are Greenville-Asheville, Raleigh-Fayetteville,

Norfolk-Hampton, Champaign-Springfield, New York, and Philadelphia. We start with

identifying venue locations on the Google Maps to compute the geographic distance (in miles)

between venues in the same market. Then, we apply the equation (1) in essay one to compute

the geographic density for each performance. As a result, depending on in which market a

performance is, the average geographic density of a performance ranges between 0.368 and

0.556 with the average across markets being 0.476 and the standard deviation being 0.09.



94

Next, we use the equation (2) in essay one to calculate the temporal density for

performances in their associated markets (TMP
jm
). On average, a performance in a market has

its temporal density ranging from 0.118 to 0.667 with the average across markets being 0.476

and the standard deviation being 0.09. Table 3-5 provides the descriptive statistics of these

covariates.

Table 3-5: Descriptive Statistics of Covariates across Markets

Days of Week Indicators and Market Population

According to observed performance dates in the dataset, we further create the days of

week indicators (FRIDAY
jm
, SATURDAY
jm
, and SUNDAY
jm
) to measure performance

attractiveness. On average, a market has 17% of performances on Friday, 38% on Saturday, and

25% on Sunday. However, there are markets without any Friday, Saturday, or Sunday

performances, as shown in those blank cells in Table 3-5. We also summarize the descriptive

statistics of days of week covariates in Table 3-5.

To compute a population size (POP
m
) in a target market (i.e., family population with

children under 10 years of age) across all DMAs, we refer to the Census Bureau to collect

relevant population information at the county level and then aggregate the population size by

DMAs, the same approach used in essay one. As a result, the average population size in a target

market is 439,662 with a standard deviation being 647,091. Table 3-6 presents the summary

information of the population size in each DMA.

Table 3-6: Descriptive Statistics of Market Characteristics

Market Characteristics

In addition to population size in a target market, we consider population density, family

income, and average family size as other potential market characteristics to explain response



95

heterogeneity. Different from the extant literature, we choose the information at a family level

rather than at a household level because our event targets at families with young children. Hence,

we first download the U.S. 2000 Census data at the county level to match the counties of interest

in our 42 DMAs. Because the population size in each county differs, we weight the market

characteristics in each county by its population size to calculate the average value for each DMA.

Table 3-6 presents the summary statistics across these DMAs.

Additional Scheduling Characteristics

We consider two additional characteristics of a performance schedule to explain the

heterogeneity across markets. The first characteristic we examine reflects the order of markets

that appear in a schedule. The second is the number of geographically adjacent markets with

respect to a focal market. We refer to the previous covariate as the temporal sequence and the

later as geographic adjacency.

To measure the temporal sequence, we refer to Table 3-1 that sorts markets by their first

day of performance to check which market is in the earliest distribution timeline (Order=1).

Then, we go down the list to assign an increasing number to markets in a later distribution

timeline. For example, according to Table 3-1, Tallahassee is the first market and Orlando is the

second market. We assign Order
1
=1 and Order
2
=2. For markets that had the first performance

on the same date (e.g., Columbia and Greenville-Asheville), we assigned an equal rank to these

markets (i.e., Order
8
= Order
9
= 8). Table 3-7 summarizes the descriptive statistics of temporal

sequence across markets.

Table 3-7: Descriptive Statistics of Additional Scheduling Characteristics

According to the lead market effect (Bronnenberg and Mela 2004), markets that are

adjacent and adopt a new product first have an impact on adjacent markets that have not yet been



96

adopted. We follow this logic to measure the geographic adjacency among our participating

DMAs. Hence, we first refer to Figure 3-3 to locate these 42 DMAs and check which markets

are adjacent to one another. Then, we refer to the order of each market to count how many

adjacent markets an event went to before it arrives to a focal market. Finally, we use this number

to represent the extent of geographic adjacency of a participating market. As a result, an event

went to an average of 0.95 spatially adjacent markets before it goes to a focal market. Table 3-7

summarizes the descriptive statistics of geographic adjacency across markets
4
.

The purpose of essay two is to explain heterogeneous market responses and propose

explanatory factors. Thus, we use the same set of covariates in the HB approach in equation (18)

and choose the population size in a target market, the order of markets that an event travels, and

the number of geographically adjacent markets for a focal market. We also examined other

market characteristics as shown in Table 3-6. Although population density is another significant

explanatory factor, it has the same effect as the population size. On the other hand, we find the

average family income and family size cannot explain any response heterogeneity across markets.




3.6 Model Estimation and Benchmark Comparison

3.6.1 Estimation

We choose the hierarchical Bayesian approach to estimate the number of ticket sales,

heterogeneous market responses, and endogeneity in performance scheduling simultaneously.

We specify appropriate and diffuse priors for our parameters in the WinBUGS program and

estimate the model over 10,000 iterations. After checking the convergence criteria, we examine

the autocorrelation plots for all covariates, discard the first 5,000 iterations for burn-in, and use



4
We also count how many adjacent markets a focal market has regardless of when the event performed in these
markets. However, this alternative measure did not explain any of the response heterogeneity.
97

the remaining iterations as the posterior distribution. We specify the prior distributions of

parameters below:

Priors for modeling performance attractiveness:

o~ 0.1,0.1

Priors for modeling the heterogeneity in market responses:

~ 0,10 where k= 1, 2, 3, 4 and i=1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6

~ 0.1,0.1 where i=1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6

Priors for modeling the endogeneity in performance scheduling:

~N 0,10 where k= 0, 1, 2 and i=1, 2

~ 0,10 where k=1, 2

3.6.2 Benchmark Comparison

Before presenting our model results, we compare the model fit between the proposed and

benchmark models. Because our proposed model aims to explain the heterogeneous market

responses to performance schedules, we think a homogeneous model that does not account for

any heterogeneity to be an appropriate benchmark (i.e., Benchmark 1). In addition, we also

compare the proposed model with the preliminary analysis (i.e., Benchmark 2). After comparing

the model fit using the DIC measure (equation 15), we find that the DIC of the proposed model

is 5590.63. This fit measure is lower than the heterogeneous model without explanatory factors

(DIC=5613.94) and the homogeneous model (DIC=6927.14). Hence, our proposed model has

incorporated the market heterogeneity and explained the differences across markets.









98

3.7 Results

3.7.1 Heterogeneous Market Responses to Performance Schedules

According to the market-specific parameters, we find that markets respond to

performance schedules consistently. Although the effect sizes vary from markets to markets, all

expected values of parameters (i.e., effects of baseline performance attractiveness, days of week,

geographic density, and temporal density) are consistently positive or negative. Figure 3-4

visually presents these heterogeneous parameter values. Specifically, the parameter values of the

baseline performance attractiveness is consistently negative across markets (E[o
0m
] ranges from

-4.43 to -7.10) and performances on Friday, Saturday, or Sunday have incremental attractiveness

to generate more ticket sales (E[o
1m
] ranges from 0.08 to 0.39; E[o
2m
] ranges from 0.16 to 0.66;

E[o
3m
] rangers from 0.18 to 0.44).

Figure 3-4: Heterogeneous Market Responses

Moreover, markets have consistent responses to their geographic and temporal schedules.

For markets where multiple venues are in use, densely scheduled performances across venues

sell more tickets than sparsely scheduled performances (E[u
1m
] ranges from 0.81 to 2.13). In

contrast, sparsely scheduled performances along a time span sell more than densely scheduled

performances (E[u
2m
] ranges from -0.10 to -0.59). These results are consistent with results in

essay one and our preliminary analysis. Hence, we confirm the consistent (yet heterogeneous)

market responses to performance schedules.

3.7.2 Explanatory Factors for Market Heterogeneity

Our results in Table 3-8 report explanatory factors for the heterogeneity in market

responses. First, when a market has a bigger population, the effects of days of week and baseline

attractiveness are attenuated (|
11
= -0.25; |
12
= -0.03; |
13
= -0.05; |
14
= -0.02). Our explanation is that



99

usually there are more events offered to a bigger market than to a smaller one. Consumers in a

bigger market may be used to seeing several competing events offered simultaneously and have a

variety of events to choose. Hence, they are less responsive to an event (no matter on which

days of week it is) than are consumers in a smaller market.

Table 3-8: Explanatory Factors for Market Heterogeneity

Second, we find that additional scheduling characteristics can partly explain

heterogeneous market responses. With respect to a current market, after an event travels to more

of its geographically adjacent markets, the current market is less responsive to its baseline

attractiveness and temporal schedule (|
21
= -0.14; |
26
= 0.10). A possible reason is that after an

event has gone to more spatially adjacent markets, its newness wears out but its reputation might

accumulate over time. As a result, consumers may refer to other measures such as word of

mouth to make their purchase decisions rather than refer to the baseline attractiveness and its

temporal schedule.

Moreover, after an event follows its temporal sequence to perform in several markets

(whether these markets are adjacent or not), a current market in a late distribution sequence tends

to respond more favorably to a Sunday performance (|
34
=0.10). This result is also graphically

shown in Figure 3-4 (d). Our explanation is that after an event has lasted longer and gone to

more markets, its reputation or word of mouth accumulates over time (Reddy et al 1981) even

though its newness may wear out. Because a Sunday performance tends to be the last

performance in a market (at least it is the case in our dataset), consumers might think Sunday as

their "last opportunity" to enjoy this event before it leaves for another market. As a result, a

market in a later temporal sequence has a stronger Sunday effect.





100

3.7.3 Endogenous Scheduling Decision

We also find an endogeneity in performance schedules. Different from essay one where

only endogeneity is found in a temporal schedule, in essay two we find that geographic and

temporal schedules are both done endogenously after we pool all performances across markets

for analysis. When event marketers expect high performance attractiveness, they schedule more

performances in all venues (|
11
= 0.18) and tend to allocate those performances around weekends

or along a limited time span (|
12
= 0.84). As a result, on average, performances have a shorter

geographic and temporal distance to others and have higher density values. Moreover, when

event marketers understand that consumers prefer performances on dispersed dates because of

uncertain timing of attendance, event marketers decrease the number of weekend performances

and/or disperse performance dates (|
22
= 1.30). Consequently, performances in a temporal

schedule have lower temporal density values. Since we have accounted for this endogeneity in

the estimation process, the results we present here are unbiased. Table 3-9 summarizes the

results of the endogeneity in performance scheduling.

Table 3-9: Endogenous Performance Schedules



3.8 Conclusions

3.8.1 Summary

In the first essay, we observe multiple performances of a single event and examine them

by their venue locations and performance dates to understand how their geographic and temporal

scheduling characteristics influence their ticket sales. However, event marketers often need to

make scheduling decisions for more than one market. Although our finding in essay one has rich

implications for event marketers, it is unclear whether event marketers can apply this finding to




101

all markets. Hence, the objective of essay two is to use all performance schedules of the same

event to investigate heterogeneous market responses and identify explanatory factors.

To accomplish our research objective, we first conduct a preliminary analysis and find

consistent scheduling effects. However, we also observe the market responses are of different

magnitudes. To identify the factors that explain these differences across markets, we extend the

model developed in essay one to not only examine market-specific response parameters but also

investigate observed and unobserved heterogeneity via the hierarchical Bayesian approach.

Among several marketing characteristics, we choose the size of market population as the first

explanatory factor. We also use additional scheduling characteristics along the distribution of

this event to examine whether geographic adjacency between markets and temporal sequence

along the distribution affect the magnitude of scheduling effects.

We use the same family event mentioned in essay one and aggregate the 50 cities it

travelled to 42 designated market areas. Our results show that market characteristics and

additional scheduling characteristics can both explain the differences across market responses.

First, when a market has a bigger population, the effects of days of week and baseline

attractiveness are attenuated. Second, with respect to a current market, after an event travels to

more of its geographically adjacent markets, the current market is less responsive to its baseline

attractiveness and temporal schedule. Moreover, after an event follows its temporal sequence to

perform in several markets, a current market in a late distribution sequence tends to respond

more favorably to a Sunday performance. We also find an endogeneity in performance

schedules. Since we have accounted for this endogeneity in the estimation process, the results

we present here are unbiased.





102

3.8.2 Limitations and Next Steps

This essay examines heterogeneous market responses to performance schedules and

contributes to the event tickets literature by investigating explanatory factors. Results of this

essay provide a more generalizable scheduling guideline for event marketers and assist event

marketers in anticipating potential market response based on market characteristics and

additional scheduling characteristics.

However, the limitation of this essay is that we allow the additional scheduling

characteristics to explain the heterogeneity in market responses (i.e., parameter effects) but have

not yet directly examined whether additional scheduling characteristics in an event distribution

affect ticket sales across markets. As the sequential distribution literature suggests, preceding

markets tend to have some effects on later markets through their spatial adjacency (Bronnenberg

and Mela 2004) or time lag between release timing (Elberse and Eliashberg 2003). It is

important to examine whether sales in different markets are independent or not. We continue

discussing this issue in essay three.
























103

Tables and Figures
Table 3-1: Summary of DMA markets

Market First Last Number of Number of Number of
Market
ID Date Date Performances Show Dates Venues
1 Tallahassee 1/1 1/4 6 4 1
2 Orlando 1/2 1/4 6 3 1
3 Tampa 1/7 1/11 8 5 1
4 Miami 1/8 1/18 16 10 1
5 Jacksonville 1/14 1/18 9 5 1
6 Birmingham 1/21 1/25 10 5 1
7 Nashville 1/22 1/25 8 4 1
8 Columbia 1/28 2/1 9 5 1
9 Greenville-Asheville 1/28 6/13 19 10 2
10 Raleigh-Fayetteville 2/5 5/23 17 9 2
11 Richmond 2/11 2/16 11 6 1
12 Atlanta 2/12 2/22 21 10 1
13 Norfolk-Hampton 2/18 2/29 19 10 2
14 Cincinnati 2/25 2/29 9 5 1
15 Charlotte 3/3 3/7 11 5 1
16 New York 3/3 6/6 70 32 4
17 Wheeling 3/17 3/20 7 4 1
18 Louisville 3/24 3/28 7 5 1
19 Terre Haute 4/6 4/7 4 2 1
20 Champaign-Springfield 4/9 4/25 11 6 2
21 Carbondale 4/13 4/14 3 2 1
22 Philadelphia 4/14 5/2 31 16 2
23 Charleston 4/15 4/18 8 4 1
24 Albany 4/29 5/2 8 4 1
25 La Crosse 5/4 5/5 4 2 1
26 Providence 5/5 5/9 9 5 1
27 Worcester 5/5 5/9 8 5 1
28 Madison 5/7 5/9 6 3 1
29 Hartford 5/12 5/16 9 5 1
30 Dayton 5/13 5/16 7 4 1
31 Mankato 5/18 5/19 3 2 1
32 Rochester 5/19 5/23 8 5 1
33 St. Paul 5/21 5/23 6 3 1
34 Cedar Rapids 5/25 5/26 4 2 1
35 Hershey 5/26 5/31 9 6 1
36 Sedalia 5/29 5/31 5 3 1
37 Memphis 6/2 6/5 6 4 1
38 Evansville 6/3 6/6 6 4 1
39 Wilkes-Barre 6/9 6/13 8 5 1
40 North Little Rock 6/16 6/20 8 5 1
41 Macon 6/23 6/27 8 5 1
42 Tucson 6/24 6/27 7 4 1
Average (STD) 10.69 (10.81) 5.79 (4.97) 1.19 (0.55)



104

Table 3-2: Summary of Market Responses to Performance Schedules
Market ID o
0
o
1
o
2
o
3
u
1
u
2

1 -5.5 ** 0.3 1.32 ** 0.15 -1.8 **
2 -5.76 ** 1.19 ** 0.58 ** -0.79 **
3 -6.32 ** 0.75 ** 1.48 ** 0.88 ** -1.33 **
4 -6.97 ** 0.3 0.79 ** 0.61 ** -1.24 **
5 -5.96 ** 0.9 ** 1.33 ** 0.7 ** -1.69 **
6 -5.42 ** 0.62 ** 0.89 ** 0.22 -2.04 **
7 -5.99 ** 0.86 ** 1.42 ** 0.73 ** -1.4 **
8 -5.92 ** 0.95 ** 1.36 ** 0.59 ** -1.81 **
9 -7.17 ** 0.66 ** 0.94 ** 0.6 ** 0.96 ** -1.8 **
10 -6.16 ** 0.5 ** 0.81 ** 0.41 ** 4.29 ** -2.92 **
11 -5.66 ** 0.9 ** 1.3 ** 1.09 ** -2.38 **
12 -6.72 ** 0.24 0.5 ** 0.34 ** -1.2 **
13 -7.23 ** 0.54 ** 0.75 ** 0.48 ** 0.92 ** -0.84 **
14 -5.68 ** 0.4 * 0.91 ** 0.41 ** -1.74 **
15 -5.78 ** 0.69 ** 0.96 ** 0.53 ** -1.67 **
16 -8.23 ** 0.1 0.24 ** 0.2 ** 0.51 ** -1.16 **
17 -5.4 ** 0.94 ** 1.19 ** -2.22 **
18 -6.17 ** 0.56 * 1.21 ** 0.22 -1.18 **
19 -3.82 ** -2.22 **
20 -6.03 ** 0.40 ** 0.35 ** 2.09 ** -2.04 **
21 -4.43 ** -1.17 **
22 -7.18 ** 0.28 ** 0.37 ** 0.24 ** 0.99 ** -1.3 **
23 -5.68 ** 0.83 ** 1.27 ** 0.61 ** -1.8 **
24 -5.62 ** 0.89 ** 1.4 ** 0.79 ** -2.1 **
25 -4.79 ** -0.66 **
26 -5.63 ** 0.34 * 0.85 ** 0.27 * -1.71 **
27 -6.82 ** 0.53 ** 1.27 ** 0.71 ** -0.37 **
28 -6.1 ** 0.98 ** 0.29 -0.04
29 -5.86 ** 0.35 0.84 ** 0.29 * -1.32 **
30 -6.2 ** 0.7 ** 1.46 ** 0.9 ** -1.25 **
31 -3.83 ** -2.12 **
32 -6.19 ** 0.66 ** 1.34 ** 0.87 ** -1.41 **
33 -6.44 ** 1.05 ** 0.5 ** -0.59 *
34 -4.59 ** -0.98 **
35 -6.83 ** 0.45 ** 1.11 ** 0.71 ** -0.34 **
36 -6.35 ** 0.65 ** 0.77 ** 0.08
37 -6.13 ** 0.59 * 1.24 ** -1.08 **
38 -6.04 ** 0.35 1.16 ** 0.13 -0.88 **
39 -6 ** 0.51 ** 1.13 ** 0.6 ** -1.47 **
40 -6.06 ** 0.58 ** 1.19 ** 0.6 ** -1.51 **
41 -6.14 ** 0.48 * 1.22 ** 0.57 ** -1.34 **
42 -5.79 ** 0.54 ** 1.36 ** 0.82 ** -1.7 **
**: significant at the 95% highest posterior density
* : significant at the 90% highest posterior density










105

Table 3-3: Venue Locations and their Associated DMAs
Venue City State DMA Market
Pepsi Arena Albany NY Albany
Philips Arena Atlanta GA Atlanta
Bjcc Arena Birmingham AL
Birmingham
Southern Illinois University Carbondale IL Carbondale
Us Cellular Center Cedar Rapids IA Cedar Rapids
Assembly Hall Champaign IL Champaign-Springfield
Prairie Capital Convention Center Springfield IL Champaign-Springfield
Charleston Civic Center Charleston WV Charleston
Charlotte Coliseum Charlotte NC Charlotte
Us Bank Arena Cincinnati OH Cincinnati
Colonial Center Columbia SC Columbia
Ej Nutter Center Dayton OH Dayton
Roberts Municipal Stadium Evansville IN Evansville
Asheville Civic Center Asheville NC Greenville-Asheville
Bi-Lo Center Greenville SC Greenville-Asheville
Hartford Civic Center Hartford CT Hartford
Giant Center Hershey PA Hershey
Jacksonville Veterans Memorial Arena Jacksonville FL
Jacksonville
La Crosse Center Lacrosse WI Lacrosse
Louisville Gardens Louisville KY Louisville
Macon Centreplex Macon GA Macon
Alliant Energy Center Coliseum Madison WI Madison
Midwest Wireless Civic Center Mankato MN Mankato
Pyramid Arena Memphis TN Memphis
American Airlines Arena Miami FL Miami
Gaylord Entertainment Ctr Nashville TN Nashville
Continental Arena East Rutherford NJ New York
Madison Square Garden New York NY New York
Sovereign Bank Arena Trenton NJ New York
Nassau Coliseum Uniondale NY New York
Hampton Coliseum Hampton VA Norfolk-Hampton
Norfolk Scope Arena Norfolk VA Norfolk-Hampton
Alltel Arena North Little Rock AK North Little Rock
Td Waterhouse Centre Orlando FL Orlando
Boardwalk Hall Atlantic City NJ
Philadelphia Wachovia Spectrum
Philadelphia PA
Philadelphia
Dunkin' Donuts Center Providence RI Providence
Crown Center Of Cumberland Fayetteville NC Raleigh-Fayetteville
Rbc Center Raleigh NC Raleigh-Fayetteville
Richmond Coliseum Richmond VA Richmond
Blue Cross Arena Rochester NY Rochester
Mathewson Center Sedalia MO Sedalia
Xcel Energy Center St Paul MN St Paul
Tallahassee Leon County Civic Center Tallahassee FL Tallahassee
St Pete Times Forum Tampa FL Tampa
Hulman Center Terre Haute IN Terre Haute
Tcc Arena Tucson AZ Tucson
Wesbanco Arena Wheeling WV Wheeling
Wachovia Arena Wilkes-Barre PA Wilkes-Barre
Worcester Centrum Centre Worcester MA Worcester




106

Table 3-4: Summary of Ticket Sales
Ticket Sales per Performance
Market ID Market Market Sales
Mean STD Min Max
1 Tallahassee 2362 1236 1659 4858 14174
2 Orlando 4348 396 3893 4952 26088 3
Tampa 6660 2056 2644 9294 53277 4
Miami 5192 2499 2150 10635 83075 5
Jacksonville 5038 1148 3357 6766 45341 6
Birmingham 8072 2048 5237 11214 80720 7
Nashville 6359 1944 3897 9274 50869 8
Columbia 3571 1147 2511 5707 32136 9
Greenville-Asheville 3475 2306 800 7716 66024
10 Raleigh-Fayetteville 5481 3480 1376 12747 93171
11 Richmond 6355 1240 3863 7703 69901
12 Atlanta 6611 1908 2499 9969 138827
13 Norfolk-Hampton 5209 1433 3095 8093 98977
14 Cincinnati 7788 2501 2638 10228 70092
15 Charlotte 7457 2647 2935 11459 82030
16 New York 8316 3525 1827 15810 582099
17 Wheeling 1848 450 993 2469 12939
18 Louisville 2734 317 2326 3173 19137
19 Terre Haute 3031 422 2545 3563 12124
20 Champaign-Springfield 1045 527 491 1910 11500
21 Carbondale 3182 1321 1838 4478 9546 22
Philadelphia 4497 2182 1548 8915 139421
23 Charleston 4407 651 3434 5442 35258
24 Albany 6489 1489 3456 8084 51914
25 La Crosse 907 219 603 1096 3629 26
Providence 5088 1065 2803 6216 45795
27 Worcester 3233 995 1521 4838 25864
28 Madison 585 210 278 914 3508 29
Hartford 5137 1258 2768 6925 46237
30 Dayton 2704 614 2011 3669 18928
31 Mankato 869 321 646 1237 2608 32
Rochester 2314 588 1472 3322 18513
33 St. Paul 1855 337 1516 2324 11130
34 Cedar Rapids 2037 287 1689 2356 8149 35
Hershey 758 147 574 982 6825 36
Sedalia 1088 203 855 1304 5442 37
Memphis 3135 321 2624 3539 18811
38 Evansville 972 429 507 1780 5834 39
Wilkes-Barre 2921 933 2018 4583 23369
40 North Little Rock 2879 827 2044 4281 23029
41 Macon 1183 369 735 1691 9461 42
Tucson 3465 824 2437 4379 24257
51905
Market average 3825 1162 2098 5712 (STD= 90992)









107

Table 3-5: Descriptive Statistics of Covariates across Markets
Market FRIDAY SATURDAY SUNDAY GEO TMP Population of
ID Mean STD Mean STD Mean STD Mean STD Mean STD Target Market
1 0.167 0.41 0.500 0.55 0.167 0.41 0.539 0.14 104326
2 0.167 0.41 0.500 0.55 0.333 0.52 0.611 0.11 477402 3
0.125 0.35 0.375 0.52 0.250 0.46 0.470 0.11 578505 4
0.125 0.34 0.375 0.50 0.250 0.45 0.299 0.04 741879 5
0.222 0.44 0.333 0.50 0.222 0.44 0.476 0.10 282479 6
0.200 0.42 0.300 0.48 0.200 0.42 0.470 0.07 321845 7
0.250 0.46 0.375 0.52 0.250 0.46 0.530 0.09 430888 8
0.222 0.44 0.333 0.50 0.222 0.44 0.476 0.10 169819 9
0.211 0.42 0.316 0.48 0.263 0.45 0.482 0.03 0.232 0.05 344151
10 0.235 0.44 0.353 0.49 0.176 0.39 0.492 0.09 0.245 0.05 463117
11 0.182 0.40 0.273 0.47 0.273 0.47 0.457 0.10 183972
12 0.190 0.40 0.286 0.46 0.286 0.46 0.307 0.04 1074597
13 0.211 0.42 0.316 0.48 0.263 0.45 0.497 0.03 0.296 0.04 345541
14 0.111 0.33 0.333 0.50 0.222 0.44 0.463 0.08 435717
15 0.182 0.40 0.273 0.47 0.273 0.47 0.473 0.07 466459
16 0.157 0.37 0.300 0.46 0.286 0.46 0.368 0.18 0.118 0.02 4100325
17 0.286 0.49 0.429 0.53 0.520 0.11 53729 18 0.143
0.38 0.429 0.53 0.143 0.38 0.470 0.13 298428
19 0.667 0.00† 66486 20 0.273 0.47 0.545 0.52 0.182 0.40
0.461 0.05 0.318 0.06 156173 21 0.667 0.14 155322 22 0.129 0.34 0.290 0.46
0.258 0.44 0.556 0.17 0.221 0.03 1321626 23 0.250 0.46 0.375 0.52
0.250 0.46 0.530 0.09 211135 24 0.250 0.46 0.375 0.52
0.250 0.46 0.530 0.09 225057 25 0.667 0.00† 86726 26 0.111
0.33 0.333 0.50 0.222 0.44 0.463 0.08 287211
27 0.125 0.35 0.375 0.52 0.250 0.46 0.470 0.11 1126579
28 0.167 0.41 0.500 0.55 0.333 0.52 0.611 0.11 147178
29 0.111 0.33 0.333 0.50 0.222 0.44 0.463 0.08 463979
30 0.143 0.38 0.429 0.53 0.286 0.49 0.532 0.12 240286
31 0.667 0.14 17074 32 0.125 0.35 0.375 0.52 0.250 0.46
0.470 0.11 186215 33 0.167 0.41 0.500 0.55 0.333 0.52
0.611 0.11 802661 34 0.667 0.00† 140908 35 0.111 0.33 0.333 0.50
0.222 0.44 0.438 0.11 316530 36 0.400 0.55 0.400 0.55
0.567 0.09 423202 37 0.167 0.41 0.500 0.55 0.506 0.13 347835
38 0.167 0.41 0.500 0.55 0.167 0.41 0.539 0.14 128297
39 0.125 0.35 0.375 0.52 0.250 0.46 0.470 0.11 227157
40 0.125 0.35 0.375 0.52 0.250 0.46 0.470 0.11 230179
41 0.125 0.35 0.375 0.52 0.250 0.46 0.470 0.11 109799
42 0.143 0.38 0.429 0.53 0.286 0.49 0.532 0.12 174998
Market
Average 0.172 0.40 0.382 0.51 0.250 0.46 0.476 0.09 0.476 0.09 439662
Note:
1. Markets without any observations in days of week are shown in blank cells.
2. Markets without any variation in their geographic schedules are shown in blank cells.
† Performances in market 19, 25, and 34 had equal temporal distance to other performances in the same market.


108

Table 3-6: Descriptive Statistics of Market Characteristics
Market Characteristics N Mean STD Min Max
POP
m
Population of target market 42 439662 647091 17074 4100325
POP_Density
m
Population density (in the log term) 42 5.717 0.85 3.787 7.615
Income
m
Family income (in the log term) 42 10.594 0.15 10.260 10.883
Family_Size
m
Average family size 42 3.028 0.09 2.857 3.276
















































109

Table 3-7: Descriptive Statistics of Additional Scheduling Characteristics
Additional Scheduling Characteristics N Mean STD Min Max
ADJ
m
Number of geographically adjacent 42 0.95 1.00 0 4
markets performing prior to a focal
market
ORDER
m
Distribution order in the temporal 42 21.43 12.3 1 42
sequence















































110

Table 3-8: Sources of Heterogeneous Market Responses
Parameter Description Median (Std Dev)
Effect of Baseline performance attractiveness: E[o
0m
]
|
01
Intercept -4.30 (0.21)**
|
11
Population size in a target market -0.25 (0.06)**
|
21
Num. of geographically contiguous markets -0.14 (0.09)*
|
31
Num. of preceding markets in temporal sequence -0.12 (0.16)

Effect of Friday performances: E[o
1m
]
|
02
Intercept 0.31 (0.73)**
|
12
Population size in a target market -0.03 (0.01)**
|
22
Num. of geographically contiguous markets 0.00 (0.03)
|
32
Num. of preceding markets in temporal sequence 0.03 (0.06)

Effect of Saturday performances: E[o
2m
]
|
03
Intercept 0.51 (0.07)**
|
13
Population size in a target market -0.05 (0.01)**
|
23
Num. of geographically contiguous markets 0.01 (0.02)
|
33
Num. of preceding markets in temporal sequence 0.06 (0.05)

Effect of Sunday performances: E[o
3m
]
|
04
Intercept 0.21 (0.07)**
|
14
Population size in a target market -0.02 (0.01)**
|
24
Num. of geographically contiguous markets 0.00 (0.03)
|
34
Num. of preceding markets in temporal sequence 0.10
(0.05)**

Effect of Geographic density: E[u
1m
]
|
05
Intercept 1.22 (0.85)*
|
15
Population size in a target market -0.18 (0.32)
|
25
Num. of geographically contiguous markets -0.25 (1.19)
|
35
Num. of preceding markets in temporal sequence 0.86 (1.53)

Effect of Temporal density: E[u
2m
]
|
06
Intercept -0.61 (0.15)**
|
16
Population size in a target market 0.04 (0.04)
|
26
Num. of geographically contiguous markets 0.10
(0.06)**
|
36
Num. of preceding markets in temporal sequence 0.09 (0.11)
* significant at the 90% highest posterior density
** significant at the 95% highest posterior density







111

Table 3-9: Results of Performance Schedule Model
Parameter Description Median (Std Dev)
Expected geographic density: m
1
|
01
Intercept -0.06 (0.47)
|
11
Expected performance attractiveness 0.18 (0.06)**
|
21
Effect of geographic density 0.09 (0.14)

Expected temporal density: m
2
|
02
Intercept 3.35 (0.27)**
|
12
Expected value of performance 0.84 (0.05)**
|
22
Effect of temporal density 1.30 (0.18)**
** significant at the 95% highest posterior density








































112

Figure 3-1: Conceptual Framework of Heterogeneous Market Responses




Scheduling Characteristics:
(1) Geographic (2) Temporal Attractiveness of
Density Density Performances






Geographic
Effect






Temporal
Effect






Days of Week
Effects




Market
Characteristics

Touring
Characteristics


At a performance level:
number of ticket sales






























113

Figure 3-2: Example of a DMA and its county information






















































114

Figure 3-3: Locations of DMA Markets and Performing Sequence






















































115

Figure 3-4: Heterogeneous Market Responses
(a) Expected baseline effect: E[o
0
] (b) Expected Friday effect: E[o
1
]












(c) Expected Saturday effect: E[o
2
] (d) Expected Sunday effect: E[o
3
]












(e) Expected geographic effect: E[u
1
] (f) Expected temporal effect: E[u
2
]

























116

4 Essay 3: Sequential Distribution of a Live Performance Event




4.1 Introduction

When and where to schedule performances are two of the most important decisions

facing event marketers in the live entertainment industry. When event marketers schedule a tour

for an event, they have to design a performance schedule within each participating market and

determine an overall travel sequence across markets. Therefore, their scheduling decisions are

within and across markets and may have different effects on ticket sales.

In the first two essays, we have shown the effect of within-market scheduling and

identified explanatory factors for heterogeneous market responses. Specifically, we find that

venue locations in a geographic schedule influences ticket sales differently from do performance

dates in a temporal schedule. Densely scheduled performances across venues sell more tickets,

yet densely scheduled performances across times sell fewer tickets. Moreover, the population

size, geographic adjacency between markets, and temporal sequence in an event distribution can

explain heterogeneous market responses to some extent.

Because essays one and two have studied the effect of within-market scheduling and left

the impact of across-market scheduling unknown, essay three examines an event distribution

across markets and its impact on market sales. Specifically, an event distribution involves

scheduling across markets. Event marketers first decide a touring sequence at one time. Then, a

performing group follows this sequence to travel from one market to another. This group

performs in one market at a time, provides a few shows within a venue, and then leaves for

another market. Therefore, the mechanism of an event distribution is the same as the sequential

distribution.



117

Sequential distribution has been studied in marketing literature where researchers study

the market roll out of a new product (Bronnenberg and Mela 2004) and movie releases across

markets or channels (Lehmann and Weinberg 2000; Elberse and Eliashberg 2003; Chintagunta,

Gopinath, and Venkataraman 2009). These works show a dependent relationship between

preceding and following markets and indicate the effect of sequential distribution on sales or

profitability. In addition, they suggest the underlying reasons for the effect of sequential

distribution to be the lead market effect from geographically adjacent markets (Bronnenberg and

Mela 2004), word of mouth effect from previous markets (Elberse and Eliashberg 2003;

Chintagunta et al 2009), or effect of release timing between channels (Lehmann and Weinberg

2000). Hence, it is common to observe how well a new product sells in previous markets to

influence whether other markets adopt this product, when following markets launch this product,

and how well this product sells.

Similarly, when an event is distributed across markets, it is likely to see preceding

markets influencing following markets. This influence may come from geographic adjacency,

word of mouth, or release timing. Although essay two uses geographical adjacency between

markets and temporal sequence in a distribution to explain heterogeneous market responses, it

has not yet explored the possibility that markets may have a more direct dependent relationship.

Consequently, the objective of essay three is to examine whether an event distributed

sequentially across markets has an effect such that ticket sales in preceding markets can

influence sales in those following markets. We refer to such an effect as the carryover effect in

this essay.

To achieve this objective, we model ticket sales of each market as a function of its

performance schedule within a market and potential carryovers from an event distribution.



118

However, one modeling challenge is that scheduling decisions are correlated and endogenous

with the demand. For instance, the number of performances, the number of venues booked, and

the number of days scheduled may be highly correlated with one another. If we simply use these

scheduling decisions to explain market demand, these scheduling variables will be highly

correlated and suffer from the issue of collinearity.

To solve this issue, in addition to modeling supply and demand simultaneously to account

for the endogeneity, we have to use variables that are independent of one another yet still

represent the scheduling influences. Thus, in the demand model for event tickets, we use the size

of trading areas of booked venue(s) in a market as one instrumental variable for the scheduling

influence. We also use the distribution of performance dates in a schedule as the second

instrumental variable for the supply of an event on different dates.

On the other hand, we capture carryovers from an event distribution from the beginning

of its tour. Because an event travels to markets at different times and each market along the

distribution has different release timing, we employ the spatially weighted approach to account

for ticket sales of preceding markets as well as their release timing.

To specify the supply decisions simultaneously with the demand, we assume that event

scheduling within a market consists of three related decisions. First, event marketers consider

how many seats they have to provide in order to sell an expected number of tickets. We call this

decision an overall supply in a market. Next, they decide how many venues they need to reserve

given the number of seats needed in a market. This is the decision of venue usage. In the

meantime, they have to determine how many days they need to book given the number of seats

needed and the size of a venue capacity. We refer to this decision as the day usage decision. In





119

this way, we take into account the influence of expected demand on the supply decisions and use

variables to incorporate the scheduling influences on demand.

We contact a national ticket seller to obtain a dataset of live performance events and use

ticket sales for one event to test our model. This particular event sequentially performed 449

times in 50 cities in the U.S. domestic market between January and June 2004. Because we

aggregated these cities into 42 DMAs in essay two, we proceed to analyze ticket sales at a

market level in essay three.

The first finding of our demand model is that an event experiences more market sales

when more consumers are within the primary trading area of its venue(s). The intuition behind is

that when an event is more accessible to consumers and has more consumers within its primary

trading area, it provides more convenience to consumers due to a shorter travel distance. As a

result, an event with a larger trading area because of using more venues in a market can

accommodate more consumers and increase ticket sales.

Second, we show that an event sells more tickets when it has performances on various

dates in a market. In other words, when an event has more performances available to a market

and has a dispersed temporal schedule, it provides more flexibility to consumers especially for

those who have higher uncertainty about whether they could attend at a particular time.

Therefore, an event with a bigger variance in the distribution of performance dates sells more

tickets in a market.

Third, we show that an event distribution has a carryover effect on ticket sales. However,

the influence is across multiple venues within the same market but not across different markets.

In other words, when an event performs from one market to another, its ticket sales in preceding

markets do not affect sales in following markets. Yet, when this event performs in more than



120

one venue, its ticket sales in a preceding venue carry over to a later venue and influence its

overall market sales.

We think the nature of the family event analyzed in this essay is the underlying reason for

a carryover effect significant within a market but not across markets. Because this family event

targets young children and their parents, it is easier to observe children and parents discussing

event information within a market than across markets. Moreover, this family event travels

within the U.S. and often goes to a similar set of markets after a year or longer. Thus, these

markets do not have to depend on other participating markets but can rely on their own historical

experience to determine the quality of this event.

Finally, we show the endogeneity in the supply of an event. Event marketers use the

expected market demand to determine how many seats they need to provide, and this overall

supply further influences the number of venues and days they schedule the event.

The rest of essay three is organized as follows. We start with reviewing relevant

literature and constructing the conceptual framework. Next, we introduce our model

development and describe our data. After the model estimation and benchmark comparisons, we

discuss our results and conclude this essay.



4.2 Literature Review and Conceptual Framework

Essay three centers on literature in sequential distribution. Although we have reviewed

some relevant works in essay two, we discuss this literature in depth to show its mechanism and

possible effects in turn.

4.2.1 Sequential Distribution

Sequential distribution has been studied in movie and retailing contexts. The concept of

sequential distribution is that a new product starts in one channel or market and then gradually
121

distributes to another. Hence, as time passes by, the product availability increases and reaches

more consumers (Lehmann and Weinberg 2000). Based on where sequential distribution takes

place, we categorize extant works into two mechanisms: (1) sequential distribution across

channels and (2) sequential distribution across markets.

Sequential Distribution across Channels

Sequential distribution across channels refers to a new product released from one

channel to another, and it is a very common mechanism in the movie industry. One key

objective of research in this stream is to understand the impact of release timing of a new movie

title on its box-office revenues (Lehmann and Weinberg 2000; Hennig-Thurau et al 2006;

Hennig-Thurau, Houston, and Walsh 2007). In this way, researchers can suggest the optimal

release timing of a movie to another channel.

Specifically, Lehmann and Weinberg (2000) examined the optimal release timing from

movie theaters to video rental stores, and they found shortening the release timing (compared

with current practice) leads to increases in profits. On the other hand, Hennig-Thurau et al (2006)

studied revenue drivers in different movie channels (i.e., theater and video). They found that

release timing has a stronger influence on short-term box-office revenues than on long-term

revenues. Yet, release timing does not affect how well a movie sells on the video channel.

Another work by Hennig-Thurau et al (2007) examined the optimal release timing across

four distribution channels (i.e., theater, video purchase, video rental, and video on demand) and

further indicated that changing the order of distribution or shortening the release timing increases

profits for movie studios. To sum up, studies in this category emphasize the effect of time lags

between channels and show higher profitability due to a shortened time lag between channels.





122

Sequential Distribution across Markets

Sequential distribution across markets refers to a new product distributed from one

market to another, and it is observed in the movie and retailing industries. A primary objective

of this research stream is to investigate whether and how previous market success carries over to

later markets and influences market entry decisions or product sales in later markets (Elberse and

Eliashberg 2003; Bronnenberg and Mela 2004; Chintagunta et al 2009).

In terms of the movie industry, no matter whether movies are of limited or wide release

within a market, a common approach is to distribute movies sequentially across markets. For

instance, Elberse and Eliashberg (2003) investigated the relationship between the U.S. domestic

and a foreign market. Within a market, they concluded that box-office revenues of a movie title

and the number of screens in a theater in a preceding week affect the supply and demand in a

following week. They also found that total box-office revenues in the U.S market tend to carry

over to a foreign market and influence the supply and demand for the same movie in the opening

week. However, when they tested an interaction effect between the U.S. box-office revenues and

the time lag on a foreign market, they found this carryover effect only significant for the screen

management decision but insignificant for market demand.

Similarly, Chintagunta et al (2009) studied a sequentially released movie across the U.S.

local markets and examined the effect of online word of mouth (measured by the valance of

online reviews) from previous markets on the box-office revenues on the opening day in a new

market. They found that a time lag between an initial market and a current market negatively

affects sales, yet the average user rating of online reviews positively influences sales. However,

reviews are accumulated from the opening of a movie up to a current market. Researchers did





123

not incorporate the joint effect between the release timing and user rating generated in different

markets.

On the other hand, in the retailing context, Bronnenberg and Mela (2004) examined

manufacturers' market entry decisions and retailers' chain adoption decisions for newly

introduced frozen pizzas. They suggested that past market entry decisions influence whether a

manufacturer enters a new market, and past chain adoption decisions affect whether a chain in a

new market adopts this product. However, because the focus of this paper was on the supply

side, researchers did not investigate the effect of previous market entry or retail adoption on

demand in following markets.

Rationale for the Effect of Sequential Distribution

One primary reason for retailers or movie studios to practice sequential distribution is to

prevent financial losses of a failing launch (Lehmann and Weinberg 2000). Moreover, there are

several underlying reasons to explain why sequential distribution would be effective and

influence sales in later markets or channels.

For example, the success-breed-success effect (Elberse and Eliashberg 2003; Hennig-

Thuran et al 2006) shows a previous success in preceding markets or channels may be replicated

more easily in later entities. The word-of-mouth effect (Elberse and Eliashberg 2003; Hennig-

Thuran et al 2007; Chintagunta et al 2009) suggests that people exchange opinions and their

experiences influence how other people think. Moreover, the lead market effect (Bronnenberg

and Mela 2004) posits that similar behaviors tend to take place in spatially adjacent markets.

Thus, it is easier for adjacent markets to observe a focal market and imitate behaviors in this

focal market.





124

Summary

To sum up, studies in sequential distribution show a dependent relationship between

preceding and following markets and indicate the effect of sequential distribution on sales or

profitability. However, one limitation is that some, if not all, of these papers assume the decision

of sequential distribution is made one at a time rather than simultaneously (Lehmann and

Weinberg 2000; Elberse and Eliashberg 2003; Bronnenberg and Mela 2004; Hennig-Thuran et al

2006; Hennig-Thuran et al 2007). In other words, decisions of release timing, market entry,

chain adoption, and screen management are made sequentially after managers observe outcomes

(i.e., adoption decisions, box-office revenues, or profitability) from previous adoptions.

When managers have to plan a new product launch simultaneously for all participating

markets, it is not clear whether these markets still have a dependent relationship such that sales

in preceding markets carry over to following markets and influence their sales. Accordingly,

essay three contributes to this literature by studying an event distribution and its impact while a

touring sequence has to be planned at one time for an event to travel sequentially across markets.

4.2.2 Conceptual Framework

The objective of essay three is to examine whether markets along an event distribution

have a dependent relationship such that ticket sales of preceding markets have a carryover effect

to influence ticket sales in following markets. Hence, in our conceptual framework, we first

discuss how a performance schedule in a market influences its ticket sales. Then, we discuss

why preceding markets along an event distribution could influence following markets and what

the possible impact might be. Finally, we discuss the endogeneity between supply and demand

for an event.





125

Effects of Performance Schedule within a Market

When an event provides many performances in a market, its performance schedule is of a

relatively larger scale, compared with an event providing fewer performances. Among these

performances, if event marketers choose to book multiple venues and each venue is surrounded

by densely populated consumers, this event will be able to reach more consumers and have a

bigger primary trading area (Huff 1964) due to its enhanced spatial accessibility (Betancourt

2004). On the other hand, if these performances are at different times of day across various days

of week, this event will provide more flexibility to consumers and can deliver the performing

contents at consumers' desired times (Betancourt 2004). In this way, the supply of a

performance schedule within a market influences how well an event sells in this market.

Effects of Carryovers from an Event Distribution

Moreover, as an event travels across markets and incurs a varying number of ticket sales,

it is possible to see preceding markets influencing following markets due to the effect of event

distribution. In other words, how well an event sells in a market may influence its sales in

adjacent markets via the lead market effect (Bronnenberg and Mela 2004). Addition, it is

possible that when an event sells well in one market, event marketers try to replicate this success

in another market because of the success-breed-success effect (Elberse and Eliashberg 2003;

Hennig-Thuran et al 2006).

On the other hand, it is also likely that consumers who have attended an event talk about

this event online or offline thus influencing people who have not yet attended. In this way, the

word of mouth of this event may travel across markets and influence people in different areas

(Elberse and Eliashberg 2003; Chingatunga et al 2009). Hence, the more ticket sales an event





126

experiences from previous markets, the higher is its volume of word of mouth, and the more

likely an event will sell well.

One special case occurs when an event travels to multiple venues of the same market. It

is possible that people who have gone to an event in a preceding venue express their opinions

about this event and influence other people in the same market. If so, an event distribution will

not only influence ticket sales across markets but also affect ticket sales across venues within the

same market. Consequently, the carryover effect from an event distribution may be across

markets as well as within a market (but across multiple venues).

Finally, although the population size of a market may influence the baseline market

demand, once we control for this market characteristic, a sequentially distributed event may still

influence its market sales through its performance schedule within a market and carryovers from

an event distribution.

Endogenous Supply and Demand of an Event Distribution

Meanwhile, because supply is often endogenous with demand, it is likely that the supply

of an event in a market influences its market sales, and the expected demand in this market

affects the supply of the same market. Therefore, our conceptual framework for an event

distribution must consider supply and demand simultaneously and allow the expected demand

and other scheduling constraints to influence the supply decision. Figure 4-1 below indicates the

endogenous relationship and summarizes the effects of performance schedule and event

distribution on market sales.

Figure 4-1: Conceptual Framework of Essay Three

Specifically, we assume event marketers make several scheduling decisions for a

touring event. Similar to the screen management decision in the movie industry (Elberse and



127

Eliashberg 2003; Basuroy, Desai, and Talukdar 2006; Eliashberg et al 2007), the first scheduling

decision is to determine the total number of seats an event needs to provide in individual markets.

Because the total number of seats is the maximum possible seats that an event can sell within a

market, we call this an overall supply decision. To endogenize the overall supply with market

sales, we assume event marketers rely on a size of market population and expected market

demand to set a desirable amount of supply. Hence, they may increase the overall supply when

they expect higher demand in a bigger market. In addition, after setting an overall supply of an

event, other scheduling issues are deciding how many venues to use and how many days to book

for this event. We call these decisions as venue usage and day usage and assume these decisions

are as a result of the market characteristics (e.g., population size or population density) and

scheduling constraints (e.g., venue capacity, venue availability, or facility rental fees).




4.3 Model Development

4.3.1 Overview

To test our conceptual framework, we model the supply and demand for an event

simultaneously. At the supply side, we model the total number of seats, venues, and days needed.

At the demand side, we specify ticket sales of each market as a function of its performance

schedule within a market and potential carryovers from an event distribution. However, one

modeling challenge is that scheduling decisions are correlated and endogenous with market

demand. For instance, the number of performances, the number of venues booked, and the

number of days scheduled in a market may be highly correlated with one another. If we simply

use these scheduling decisions to explain market demand, these covariates will be highly

correlated and suffer from the issue of collinearity.


128

To solve this issue, in addition to modeling supply and demand simultaneously to account

for the endogeneity, we have to use variables that are independent of one another yet still

represent the scheduling influences. Thus, in the demand model for event tickets, we use the size

of trading areas of booked venue(s) in a market as one variable for the scheduling influence. We

also use the distribution of performance dates in a schedule as the second variable for the supply

of an event on different dates.

Although our modeling approach is similar to that of Elberse and Eliashberg (2003) who

specified the number of screens and box-office revenues simultaneously for a sequentially

distributed movie, our approach differs from theirs because we model several elements in the

scheduling decisions in additional to just the capacity decision.

As such, we model the linerized supply and demand to follow the multivariate normal

distribution.

ln ln
(19)
ln ~ ,
ln

where Sales
m
is the number of ticket sales in market m (i.e., market demand), Seats
m
is the total

number of seats supplied in market m (i.e., overall supply), Venues
m
is the number of venues

used in a market (i.e., venue usage), and Days
m
is the number of days available in a schedule (i.e.,

day usage). These dependent variables have expected values y
m
and a variance-covariance

matrixE. In this way, the correlations between supply decisions and the correlation between

supply and demand are controlled in the variance-covariance matrix.

4.3.2 Demand Equation: Market Sales

According to equation (19), we model expected market sales as a function of its

performance schedule within a market and potential carryovers from an event distribution:


129

(20)

where y
1m
is the expected ticket sales (in the log term) in market m, X
1
is a vector of variables to

represent the scheduling influences, X
2
represents potential carryovers from an event distribution,

Z
m
is a vector of market characteristics used as control covariates, ando is the vector of

associated parameter effects. We discuss the operationalization of these covariates in variable

specification.

4.3.3 Supply Equations: Overall Supply, Venue Usage, and Day Usage

Although some studies assume an exogenous supply decision (Swami et al 1999;

Eliashberg et al 2005; Eliashberg et al 2007; Chintagunta et al 2009), we propose an endogenous

and positive relationship between overall supply and market demand (Elberse and Eliashberg

2003; Basuroy et al 2006).

We assume that event scheduling within a market consists of several related decisions.

First, event marketers consider how many seats they have to provide in order to sell an expected

number of tickets. Hence, we specify the expected number of seats as a function of its expected

market demand and market characteristics:

(21) |

where y
2m
is the expected number of seats (in the log term) provided, y
1m
is the expected market

sales (in the log term), Z
m
is a vector of market characteristics used as control covariates, and|

is the vector of associated parameter effects.

Second, we assume the following decisions are to decide how many venues to reserve

and how many days to book. Specifically, given the amount of supply event marketers have to

provide, they can also refer to market characteristics such as market land area and population

density in a market to determine how many venues to book. They can also refer to the size of



130

venue capacity and the cost of venue rental to decide how many days are needed in order to be

cost effective. For example, if a market is densely populated and its land area is big, event

marketers may consider booking more venues to increase the spatial accessibility of this event.

On the other hand, if the average venue capacity is small and the daily cost of renting a venue is

high, event marketers may consider booking fewer days but scheduling more performances in a

day. We specify the expected venue and day usage as follows:

(22) ¸

u

where y
2m
is the expected number of seats (in the log term) provided, y
2m
is the expected number

of venues (in the log term) needed, y
3m
is the expected number of days (in the log term) needed,

Z
m
is a vector of market characteristics, and¸ andu are the vectors of associated parameter

effects.

Similar to Elberse and Eliashberg (2003), the advantage of specifying supply and demand

equations in the way above is that parameters in equations (20), (21), and (22) represent

elasticity of covariates. These parameter values suggest how changes in their covariates result in

changes in demand and supply. We can also compareo in equation (20) to rank the importance

of these covariates on market sales.

4.3.4 Variable Specifications

Because of the endogenous and correlated scheduling decisions, we aim to find

representative variables that are correlated with a performance schedule but do not have a severe

collinearity in the demand equation. Among several possible measures, we find the size of

trading area of venues and the flexibility in a temporal schedule may serve the modeling purpose.

The rationale is that when an event uses multiple venues in its performance schedule, it has a



131

bigger primary trading area and is more accessible for consumers within this area. In addition,

when this event has more performances at different times of day and on various days of week, it

provides consumers with higher flexibility to attend at their own convenience. Since these

benefits are relevant with a performance schedule but are not highly collinear, we propose three

variables and discuss how we operationalize these variables in turn.

Size of Trading Area

We follow the retail trading area in the retail location literature (Huff 1964; Applebaum

1966; Cliquet 1998) to compute the size of trading area of booked venue(s) in a market.

Specifically, we measure the size of trading area by referring to the population density around

each venue of a performance schedule. Because population density can determine the size of a

potential market (Huff 1964) yet it is not uniformly distributed (Donthu and Rust 1989), we

assume the zip code of each venue as its primary trading area and consumers living in the same

zip code to be the potential consumers. Therefore, the proxy of total consumers within the

primary trading areas is as follows:


(23)


where Size
m
is the size of trading area of selected venues, x
1m
is the total number of consumers

within the primary trading areas and Density
v
is the population density around the zip code of

venue v.

However, the level of people's willingness to travel can expand or shrink the trading area

of a venue (Huff 1964; Applebaum 1966). In other words, when people have higher tolerance to

travel, a venue is able to reach more people and has a bigger trading area. To consider the factor

of travel tolerance, we further include an adjustment term and rewrite equation (23) as follows:



132

(24) •


where ì
v
is an adjustment term to represent consumers' willingness to travel.

To approximate consumers' willingness to travel, we use the average commute time as a

proxy. Our assumption is that consumers who spend more time commuting on a daily basis are

more willing to travel and have higher travel tolerance. Hence, we compute ì
v
as an index

relative to the average (Mazzeo 2002):


(25) ; 1,2, . ,


where commute
v
is the average commute time (in minutes) for people living in zip code v and

mean(commute
v
) is the average. In this way, if ì
v
> 1, people are willing to travel farther, and

venue v has an expended trading area to reach more people. In contrast, if ì
v
< 1, the trading

area of venue v shrinks. Finally, if ì
v
= 1, the trading area of a venue is as it is.

Flexibility in a Temporal Schedule

Because the flexibility in a temporal schedule represents how easily consumers can attend

an event at different times of day and across various days of week, we use the distribution of

performance dates in a schedule as other variables. Specifically, we compute the average

number of performances per day for the flexibility during a day. In addition, among all

performances available to a market, we use its distribution and calculate its variance to represent

the flexibility during a week. Therefore, if an event has more performances per day and has a

bigger variance, consumers will have more flexibility to attend this event at their own

convenience.






133

Carryovers from an Event Distribution

As we mentioned in the conceptual framework, carryovers from an event distribution

may affect sales in later markets. Moreover, when an event performs in multiple venues within a

market, the carryover effect may also exist across venues but within this market. Therefore, we

measure across-market carryovers and within-market carryovers in this section.

To measure across-market carryovers since the beginning of an event distribution, we use

ticket sales from preceding markets as a proxy (Elberse and Eliashberg 2003; Bronnenberg and

Mela 2004). In this way, various amounts of ticket sales from preceding markets represent

different magnitudes of carryovers from these markets. However, because an event travels to

markets at a different time and each market along the distribution has different release timing, we

employ the spatially weighted approach to account for ticket sales of preceding markets as well

as their release timing (Yang and Allenby 2003; Bronnenberg and Mela 2004; Choi, Hui, and

Bell 2009).

M
(26)


where
1
exp ,

where AC
m
represents the amount of across-market carryovers up to market m, Sales
m
is a vector

of ticket sales that market m' has occurred up to the beginning of market m (m'=m), and W
1
is a

spatial weight matrix where each element (W
1mm'
) is an exponentially weighted distance measure

between a preceding market m' and a current market m (d
1
(m,m')).

Although it is arguable that our across-market measure only considers the temporal

sequence of participating markets but not considers the geographic adjacency between markets,

we think our measure is better because this essay focuses on understanding the effect of an entire

134

distribution rather than the effect of spatially adjacent markets only. However, it is possible to

include the geographic adjacency between markets as an extension and study the effect of spatial

adjacency.

Therefore, before measuring d
1
in equation (26), we observe markets are temporally

adjacent in several ways. Figure 4-2 below illustrates various possibilities of market

connectedness, where a darker color represents a preceding market m', a lighter color indicates a

current market m, and the width of a box is the length of a performing period. In our dataset, we

observe several ways of market connectedness. We classify them into three cases and discuss

each one in turn.

Figure 4-2: Illustration of Market Connectedness

Specifically, in the first case, Apart, performances in two markets are apart from each

other in a few days or are tightly connected. Case 1.a and Case 1.b in Figure 4-2 illustrates these

situations, respectively. In the second case, Overlap, performances in two markets have an

overlapped performing period. This overlapped period may be for a few days or for a longer

period. Case 2.a and Case 2.b in Figure 4-2 illustrates these situations, respectively. Note that

in the first two cases, an event only employs one venue to provide performances. If there are

multiple performing groups touring in the U.S. at the same time, it is possible to observe markets

without any time lag in between or markets have performances at the same time. Case 1.b, Case

2.a, and Case 2.b in Figure 4-2 represent these situations.

On the other hand, when an event performs in two markets and uses multiple venues in

one of the markets, it is likely that performances in a current market are in between two venues

of another market or overlaps with one of the venues. Case 3.a, In between a break, and Case

3.b, Overlap with one venue, in Figure 4-2 are examples of these situations. However, when an



135

event performs in two markets and both employ multiple venues, it is possible to see performing

periods overlapping in some venues yet apart in others (i.e., Figure 4-2, Case 3.c: between and

overlap). Therefore, Case 3.b and Case 3.c in Figure 4-2 exist if an event has more than one

performing group touring at the same time.

According to these different situations, we measure d
1
(in weeks) differently. In Case 1

(Apart), we measure d
1
by calculating the time lag (in days) between two markets and then

converting this value to week:

(27) , # ?7

where #apart indicates the time lag between two markets in days.

Case 2 represents a situation that markets have an overlapped performing period.

Because there are performances showing concurrently in two markets, we assume the carryovers

from these markets should have no decay but a stronger effect. In other words, markets of some

overlapped performing periods should have stronger influence on each other than markets that

are apart from each other. Therefore, overlapped markets should have higher spatial weights.

To do this, we allow d
1
(m,m') in equation (26) to be negative such that its associated spatial

weight (W
1mm'
) is larger:

(28) , 1 # ?7

where #overlap indicates the number of days that two markets have overlapped performances.

This specification ensures overlapped markets in Case 2 have higher weights than markets in

Case 1.

Finally, in Case 3, venues are either in between a break (Case 3.a), overlap with one

venue (Case 3.b), or between and overlap (Case 3.c). We consider each condition separately and

measure d
1
accordingly:



136

• Case 3.a In between a break

Case 3.a is when performances in market m are in between the first and second venue of

market m'. Because by the time of market m, sales in the second venue of market m' have not

yet occurred. Hence, d
1
(m,m') is the time lag between performances in the first venue of market

m' and those in the venue of market m. That is, Case 3.a is similar to Case 1.a. We measure d
1


using equation (27). However, the associated market sales (Sales
m'
) in equation (26) are up to

the end of first venue of market m' only.

• Case 3.b Overlap with one venue

Case 3.b is when performances in market m overlap with the first venue of market m'.

This is a similar case to Case 2. Therefore, we measure d
1
using equation (28) yet sales for

market m' are up to the end of first venue only.

• Case 3.c Between and overlap

Because Case 3.c is a combination of Case 1 and Case 2, we need to consider the number

of days markets are apart and overlapped at the same time. Hence, we allow #apart and #overlap

to cancel each other and measure d
1
accordingly:

(29) , # 1 # ?7

To measure within-market carryovers from preceding venues in a market, we take the

same spatially weighted approach and assign a different weight based on the time lag to a current

venue v:

(30)

,
where
1
exp ,



137

where WC
m
is the within-market carryovers for market m (if it is a market that uses multiple

venues), Sales
v'
is a vector of ticket sales that a preceding venue v' has occurred up to the

beginning of venue v, and W
2
is a spatial weight matrix to measure the temporal difference (d
2
)

between a current venue v and its preceding venue v' in market m.

In a market where an event employs multiple venues, performances tend to take place

sequentially with a number of days apart from one another. Hence, we measure d
2
in a similar

way to Case 1 in equation (27):

(31) , # ?7

4.3.5 Model Summary

To sum up, we model the supply and demand simultaneously. At the demand side, we

use three variables and two spatially weighted measures to represent the scheduling influences

from a performance schedule and carryovers from an event distribution. We also use the

population size as a market characteristic to control for the baseline effect on market demand. At

the supply side, we model the total number of seats, venues, and days an event needs to provide

for each market. We allow the expected market demand to influence the total number of seats

and assume event marketers book venues and days based on their overall supply. Meanwhile,

we take into account the potential effects of market characteristics and scheduling constraints in

the supply decision.

Finally, in case there are omitted yet correlated variables to affect supply and demand

jointly, we allow correlated error terms and estimate supply and demand simultaneously. We

rewrite our model specification as follow and present the relationships among these covariates in

Figure 4-3:





138



(32)












where








ln
ln
ln
ln







ln





ln


~







ln
ln
ln
ln





ln


,







ln


ln












ln





ln
M
Sales
m

Seats
m

Venues
m

Days
m
Size
m

Intenstiy
m
Variance
m

AC
m
WC
m
POP
m
Area
m

Density
m
Capacity
m

Rental
m
= market 1,2,.,M market
= Number of ticket sales (market demand)
= Number of seats supplied (overall supply) =
Number of venues booked (venue usage)
= Number of days scheduled (day usage)
= Size of trading area of venues
= Average number of performances per show day
= Variance in the distribution of performance dates
= Across-market carryovers up to market m
= Within-market carryovers in market m
= Size of market population
= Size of market land area (in square miles)
= Population density in market m
= Avg. capacity of selected venues in market m
= Avg. rental fees in market m


Figure 4-3: Overview of Model Development



4.4 Data

We contact a national ticket seller to obtain a dataset of live performance events and use

ticket sales for one event to test our model. This event sequentially performed 449 times in 50


139

cities in the U.S. domestic market between January and June 2004. We have aggregated the data

into 42 DMAs in essay two and analyze this aggregated dataset in essay three
5
.

4.4.1 Touring Sequence

We have discussed how the event travels across markets in essay two. Table 3-1 lists the

first and last dates of performances and the venue usage for each DMA and Figure 3-3 shows the

touring sequence graphically. Among these 42 DMAs, the event performed in multiple venues

in six DMAs where we observe two ways of within-market touring.

One approach is that the event first performed in one venue in a focal DMA, left for other

DMAs, and then returned to the focal DMA again but performed in a different venue.

Specifically, the event took this approach in the Greenville-Asheville DMA (market ID= 9), the

Raleigh-Fayetteville DMA (market ID= 10), and the Champaign-Springfield DMA (market

ID=20). In the Greenville-Asheville DMA, the event first performed in Greenville between

January 28 and February 1, left for other DMAs, and then returned to Asheville on June 9, 2004.

In the Raleigh-Fayetteville DMA, it performed in Raleigh between February 5 and February 9,

left for other DMAs, and then returned to Fayetteville on May 20, 2004. Finally, in the

Champaign-Springfield DMA, it performed in Springfield between April 9 and April 11 and then

in Champaign on April 23.

The other approach is that the event performed in venues within a market consecutively

and then left for other DMAs. For example, when it performed in the Norfolk-Hampton DMA

(market ID= 13), it first stayed in Norfolk between February 18 and February 22 and then went

to Hampton on February 25. In the Philadelphia DMA (market ID= 22), it first performed in

Philadelphia between April 14 and April 25 and then went to Atlantic City on April 28.



5
Essay one provides detailed discussion about the event and essay two describes how we aggregate sales data into
42 DMAs.
140

However, the tour for the New York DMA (market ID= 16) is a combination of these two

approaches. The event first performed in East Rutherford, Uniondale, and New York

consecutively between March 3 and April 11. Then, it left for other DMAs and finally returned

to Trenton on June 3.

4.4.2 Covariates in the Demand Model

Venue Usage and Size of Trading Area

In terms of the venue usage within a market, we find that a selected venue may not be in

the center of a DMA but it is often located in a densely populated area. For example, Figure 4-4

illustrates the venue locations of the six DMAs discussed above and shows the population

density around each venue. Therefore, it is reasonable to assume that the zip code of a venue is

the primary trading area for this venue and consumers living in this zip code are the potential

consumers in the trading area. As such, it is meaningful to use the population density to measure

the size of potential market.

Figure 4-4: Venue Locations and Surrounding Population Density

Specifically, to calculate the size of trading area for selected venues in a market, we refer

to the data collected from the U.S. Census Bureau for population, land area (in square miles), and

consumers' travel time to work (in minutes) at a zip code level for all venues observed in the

dataset. We further divide the population by the size of land area for the population density of

each venue (Venue
v
). On average, there are 3,289 consumers in the same zip code of a venue

with the standard deviation being 4,239.

In addition, the average travel time to work across all observed venues is 20.70 minutes

with the standard deviation being 5.71. We divide travel time to work for each venue

(Commute
v
) by the sample average to get the index of travel tolerance (ì
v
). Hence, the mean



141

travel tolerance across venues is 1 with its standard deviation being 0.28. Using the new

information above, we compute the size of trading area at a venue level. Then, for DMAs that

have multiple venues, we aggregate across venues to conclude that an average size of trading

area in a market is about 4,291 consumers with the standard deviation being 9,968. Table 4-1

indicates the descriptive statistics of the size of trading area across markets (in the log term).

Table 4-1: Descriptive Statistics of Covariates (in the log term)

Day Usage and Flexibility Measures

We summarize the touring dates across markets in Figure 4-5. On average, it took an

event 5.79 days performing in a market with the number of show days ranging from two to 32.

In terms of days of week for performances, we find that most markets (32 out of 42 DMAs) tend

to offer the last performance on Sunday. However, depending on the number of performances

offered in a market, some markets started the first performance on Wednesday (22 out of 42

DMAs), some on Thursday (10 out of 42 DMAs), and the rest on Tuesday or Friday. In other

words, the flexibility that an event provides with consumers to attend on various days of week is

heterogeneous across markets. Descriptively, nine DMAs have performances for two to three

days in a week, nine DMAs have performances across four days, 14 DMAs have performances

across five days, and 10 DMAs have performances more than six days.

Figure 4-5: Touring Dates across Markets

After examining the distribution of performance dates for each market, we find an

average market has its variance in the distribution of performance dates to be 199.71 days with

the standard deviation being 831.68. This skewed distribution is due to four DMAs that have

performances in multiple venues and have a long lag between venues. Therefore, if we exclude





142

these four DMAs, the average value of variance is 2.325 days with its standard deviation being

3.37.

In addition, on average, there are 1.79 performances available during a show day with the

standard deviation being 0.21. Although we do not know the specific times for day of our

performances, we still find the flexibility that an event provides with consumers to attend at

different times of day to be heterogeneous across markets. Table 4-1 indicates the descriptive

statistics of the flexibility in days of week and for times of day (in the log term).

Across-Market and Within-Market Carryovers

Figure 4-5 also illustrates how markets are temporally connected with one another.

According to venue usage and the first and last dates of performances, we classify 42 DMAs into

markets that are completely apart from one another (Case 1 in Figure 4-2), overlapped (Case 2),

or are in between multiple venues (Case 3). We further apply equations (27), (28), or (29) to

compute the time lag between markets to ensure all preceding markets have different spatial

weights in equation (26) and calculate across-market carryovers accordingly. Hence, the average

across-market carryovers are 73,963.88 with the standard deviation being 65,688.67.

Figure 4-5: Touring Dates across Markets

Similarly, we use equation (31) to calculate the time lag between venues within a market

for those six DMAs that have multiple venues. As a result, we have an average within-market

carryovers being 51,564.62 and its standard deviation being 73,673.07. Table 4-1 indicates the

descriptive statistics of the across-market and within-market carryovers (in the log term).

Population Size

The last covariate in the demand equation is the population size in each market. Because

we have computed the target market population in essay two, we include the descriptive statistics



143

in Table 4-1. The average population size in a market is 439,662 and the standard deviation is

647091.

4.4.3 Covariates in the Supply Model

Venue Capacity and Market Capacity

Before we study the overall supply in each market (Seat
m
) as the first supply decision, we

need to know the number of performances and the seating capacity for each venue. However, we

do not have information regarding venue capacity in our dataset, so we refer to venue websites

and the Wikipedia to collect seating capacity data.

According to venue websites, venues have various configurations for different events

(e.g., basketball games, hockey games, concerts, etc.). Hence, we choose the format that is the

closest to the setting of a family event and record the associated capacity as the venue capacity

(Capacity
v
). Using all venue capacity in the same market, we further compute the average venue

capacity in a market (Capacity
m
) for equation (32) and observe heterogeneity in venue capacity.

On average, a venue has 13,612 seats with standard deviation being 4,682. Fifty percent of

venues have capacity between 10,423 seats (quartile 1) and 17,315 seats (quartile 3).

Next, we multiply the venue capacity by the number of performances in this venue to

know the total number of seats supplied by this venue and then sum across all venues in the same

market to get the market capacity (Seats
m
). On average, an event offers 156,747 seats in a

market with its standard deviation being 184,537. Some markets only supplied a few seats (e.g.,

Mankato DMA offered 14,496 seats in a total) but some markets provided as many as 1,159,059

seats (i.e., New York DMA).

According to the market sales and market capacity, we find that at most 50% of market

capacity was filled. On average, only 24% of total capacity was filled in a market. Figure 4-6



144

presents the rate of filled capacity across markets. Table 4-1 also indicates the descriptive

statistics of the overall market supply (in the log term).

Figure 4-6: Capacity-Filled Rate across Markets

Market Land Area and Population Density

To study the number of venues a market needs to book in equation (32), we still need

information about the market land area and population density at a market level. Hence, we use

the U.S. Census Bureau statistics to obtain the market land area (in square miles) and the size of

population at a county level.

After we divide the county population by its land area, we understand the population

density at a county level. Then, we sum across all counties within the same DMA to get the

population density (Density
m
) at a market level. We also compute the land area in a market

(Area
m
) by summing the land area across counties in the same DMA. Therefore, an average

market has 3,846 square miles of land and its population density is 422 people per square mile.

Table 4-1 indicates the descriptive statistics of the market land area and population density (in

the log term).

Facility Rental Fees

We also use the facility rental fees (Fees
m
) to study the number of days event marketers

need to book in a market. However, because this information is not publicly available, we

assume rental fees of a venue are positively correlated with housing values in the same zip code.

In other words, when a median value of a single-family house is high, it is very likely that rental

fees of a venue in this zip code are also high. Hence, we collect housing market data from the

U.S. Census Bureau based on this assumption. The distribution of the housing value across

markets is skewed. The average value (in thousands) is 2055 and the standard deviation is 4855.



145

The median of the housing value is 94.2. Table 4-1 also summarizes the descriptive statistics of

this covariate (in the log term).

Correlation

Finally, before we estimate the proposed model, we also check the correlation among our

covariates and the correlation among all dependent variables. Table 4-2 reports the correlation

between covariates in the demand model and Table 4-3 indicates that dependent variables are

moderate or highly correlated. Hence, our proposed model that correlates all error terms among

dependent variables has accounted for this issue.

Table 4-2: Correlation Coefficient of Demand Covariates


Table 4-3: Correlation Coefficient of Dependent Variables


4.5 Estimation and Results

4.5.1 Model Estimation

We estimate demand and supply equations simultaneously using the Bayesian approach

where parameters are specified to follow diffuse prior distribution as follows:

Priors for model of market sales:

~ 10,10 and ~ 0,100 where i=1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6

Priors for model of overall supply:

~ 11,10 and ~ 0,100 where i=1, 2

Priors for model of venue usage:

~ 0.11,10 and ~ 0,100 where i=1, 2, 3

Priors for model of day usage:

~ 1.5,10 and ~ 0,100 where i=1, 2, 3

Priors for the variance-covariance of Supply and Demand:

~ ,4

146

We run 30,000 iterations in WinBUGs. After checking the convergence criteria, we

check the autocorrelation plots for all covariates, discard the first 20,000 iterations for burn-in,

and use the remaining iterations as the posterior distribution.

4.5.2 Results of Demand Equation

Scheduling Influence in a Performance Schedule

First, we show that the size of trading area of selected venues in a market has a positive

effect on market sales. When an event performs in multiple venues in a market or when its

venues are located in densely populated areas, this event sells more tickets in this market

(o
1
=0.160). Our explanation is that scheduling performances in multiple venues or selecting

venues in densely populated area can improve the spatial accessibility of this event (Huff 1964;

Donthu and Rust 1989; Betancourt 2004). In this way, consumers living within the trading area

do not have to travel a longer distance to attend an event. When there are more consumers

within the trading area of a market, it is more likely for this market to sell more tickets (Huff

1964; Applebaum 1966; Cliquet 1988).

Second, we find the flexibility of performance dates in a schedule has a positive effect on

ticket sales. When the variance in the distribution of performance dates increases, an event

provides consumers with higher flexibility to attend on various days of week (Betancourt 2004)

and sell more tickets in a market (o
3
=0.235). However, when there are more performances in a

show day, the flexibility for times of day does not contribute to ticket sales.

Carryovers in an Event Distribution

Moreover, we show that a sequentially distributed event has an effect on ticket sales.

However, the influence is across multiple venues within the same market but not across different

markets. In other words, when an event performs from one market to another, its ticket sales in



147

preceding markets do not affect sales in following markets. Yet, when this event performs in

more than one venue within a market, its ticket sales in a preceding venue can carry over to a

later venue and influence its overall market sales (o
5
=0.083).

We think the nature of the family event analyzed in this essay is the underlying reason for

a carryover effect significant within a market but not across markets. Because this family event

targets young children and their parents, it is easier to observe children and parents discussing

event information within a market than across markets. Moreover, this family event travels

within the U.S. and often goes to a similar set of markets after a year or longer. Thus, these

markets do not have to depend on other participating markets but can rely on their own historical

experience to determine the quality of this event.

Our results are consistent with the results in Elberse and Eliashberg (2003). Specifically,

they used sales in a preceding week as the volume of word of mouth and found a significant

effect on box-office revenues in a following week within the same market. This is similar to our

carryover effect within a market except that our carryover effect is across venues but not over

time. On the other hand, when Elberse and Eliashberg (2003) measured the interaction effect

between market sales in a domestic market and the time lag between a domestic and foreign

market, they found this interaction, or weighted word of mouth, effect insignificant across

markets. Although our spatially weighted measure for the carryovers across markets is similar

to their measure except that we take into account all of the participating markets instead of just

the initial market, our results are consistent with their work and support their results.

Elasticity

Another advantage of our model specification is that parameter estimates in our demand

model suggest the elasticity for all covariates. After comparing elasticity across significant



148

covariates, we conclude that the variance in the distribution of performance dates is more

important than the size of trading area of selected venues and the carryovers of an event

distribution within a market, respectively in this order. Although market population has a higher

elasticity (o
6
= 0.264), this is a market characteristic that event marketers cannot manipulate in

their scheduling decisions. Furthermore, these elasticity values suggest event marketers which

factors to strengthen. If trade-offs among these factors have to be made, they can make rational

decisions based on the elasticity. We summarize the parameter estimates in our demand model

in Table 4-4.

Table 4-4: Results of the Demand Model

4.5.3 Results of Supply Equations

From the results of the supply model, we confirm the endogeneity between the supply

and demand for an event. Event marketers use the expected market demand to determine how

many seats they need to provide (|
1
=0.771) but not the size of market population. Moreover, in

terms of the venue usage, when event marketers need to increase their overall supply, they tend

to schedule performances in more venues (¸
1
=0.473) but do not consider the size of market land

area or population density in this market.

On the other hand, when event marketers evaluate how many days to book for an event,

they consider how many seats they need to supply (u
1
= 0.929) and the average venue capacity in

a market (u
2
= -0.703). In other words, when they need to provide more seats to a market, they

book more days for this event and have a longer performing duration. However, the number of

days needed decreases with the venue capacity. Although we do not find average housing value

influences the decision of day usage, it is possible that this variable is not an appropriate proxy





149

for the rental facility fees in a market. Table 4-5 below summarizes the parameter values in the

supply equations.

Table 4-5: Results of the Supply Model

4.5.4 Correlated Demand and Supply

Finally, we find correlated error terms in the supply and demand models. In other words,

there are unspecified covariates affecting both supply and demand at the same time. The

correlation between the market sales and overall supply is 0.549 and the correlation between the

market sales and day usage is 0.499. On the other hand, the decisions of overall supply and day

usage are also correlated (corr(c
Seats
, c
Days
)=0.823)). Hence, it is necessary to assume correlated

error terms in our model to avoid biased parameter estimates. Table 4-6 below indicates the

correlation coefficients among our supply and demand models.

Table 4-6: Correlation between Supply and Demand Models



4.6 Conclusions

4.6.1 Summary

When an event travels across markets and has its distribution sequence planned at one

time, it is not clear whether and how the sequential distribution of this event influences ticket

sales in each participating market. The objective of essay three is to examine whether markets

along an event distribution have a dependent relationship and whether ticket sales of preceding

markets have a carryover effect to influence ticket sales in following markets.

To achieve this objective, we model ticket sales of each market as a function of its

performance schedule within a market and potential carryovers from an event distribution.

Specifically, we employ three variables to represent the scheduling influences from various

venues and performance dates, and take the spatially weighted approach to capture carryovers of

150

participating markets that have different ticket sales and release timing. We also specify the

supply and demand for this event simultaneously to account for a likely endogeneity. At the

supply side, we model separate but correlated decisions of overall supply, venue usage, and day

usage. In this way, our proposed model provides better understanding of scheduling effects on

demand and control for the endogenous supply and demand.

We contact a national ticket seller to obtain a dataset of a live performance event and

analyze ticket sales at a market level. The first result indicates that an event experiences more

market sales when it plays in several venues and has a bigger trading area to accommodate more

potential consumers. Second, an event sells more tickets when its performances are dispersed

across days of week but not during many times a day. In other words, the flexibility in a

temporal schedule is along the days of week to attract more consumer attendance.

Third, we find a significant effect of carryovers from an event distribution. When an

event performs in multiple venues within a market, ticket sales in a preceding market carry over

to later venues and influence its market sales although this carryover effect does not exist across

participating markets. Finally, we find supply and demand for an event to be endogenous. Event

marketers use the expected market demand to determine how many seats they need to provide,

and this overall supply further influences how many venues they reserve and how many days

they book in a schedule.

4.6.2 Conclusion

This essay contributes to the sequential distribution literature by studying an event

distribution where its touring sequence is set at one time rather than sequentially. We show that

the impact of sequential distribution exists locally but not across markets. In other words,

although markets along a tour do not have a dependent relationship, venues of the same market



151

have a dependent relationship and preceding venues can influence ticket sales in later venues and

ticket sales in this market.

The methodological contribution of this essay is to employ variables for an endogenous

and correlated performance schedule. By modeling the supply and demand simultaneously and

having the variables in the demand equation, we ensure unbiased scheduling effects and provide

actionable implications for event marketers.

To sum up, the first implication of essay three lies in the decision of venue usage. After

event marketers decide how many venues to book, they can refer to the size of trading area of

each alternative venue and select among these venues accordingly. Moreover, they can add or

drop venues based on the size of trading area if the desirable number of venues is not feasible in

a market. The second implication lies in the decision of day usage. Event marketers should

consider not to allocate multiple performances in a day but to disperse performances across

various days of week. However, event marketers should still evaluate the overall costs for such

scheduling changes in any venue or day usage.

Finally, when a touring sequence has to be planned simultaneously, it is not necessary for

event markets to consider any dependent relationship across markets. However, if this event

performs in multiple venues in a specific market, it is preferred that event marketers schedule

this event in a more important venue prior to other venues. In other words, the scheduling

objective for a touring event should be to minimize the travel distance across markets but

maximize the within-market carryovers for venues in the same market.










152

Tables and Figures
Table 4-1: Descriptive Statistics of Covariates (in the log term)
Variable Label N Mean Std Dev Min Max
Covariates in the demand equation
Sales Number of ticket sales 42 10.18 1.15 7.87 13.27
Size Size of trading area 42 7.54 1.26 4.78 11.08
Intensity Avg. number of performances in a 42 0.58 0.12 0.34 0.79
show day
Variance Variance in the distribution of 42 1.02 2.20 -1.10 8.44
performance dates
AC Across-market carryovers 42 10.93 0.74 9.52 12.75
WC Within-market carryovers 6 5.16 8.33 -7.45 12.13
POP Population size 42 12.46 0.92 9.75 15.23


Covariates in the supply equations
Seats Number of seats supplied 42 11.59 0.85 9.58 13.96
Venues Number of venues booked 42 0.12 0.30 0 1.39 Days
Number of days supplied 42 1.57 0.56 0.69 3.47
Area Size of market land area (in square 42 7.90 0.80 6.55 9.81
miles)
Density Population density of a market 42 5.72 0.85 3.79 7.62
Capacity Avg. capacity of selected venues in a 42 9.45 0.42 8.06 10.09
market
Rental Avg. housing value of a market (in 42 5.24 1.85 3.60 9.71
thousands)























153

Table 4-2: Correlation Coefficient of Demand Covariates
ln(Size) ln(Intensity) ln(Variance) ln(AC) ln(WC) ln(POP)
ln(Size) --
ln(Intensity) 0.41 --
ln(Variance) 0.52 0.22 --
ln(AC) -0.02 0.08 -0.00 --
ln(WC) 0.44 0.22 0.20 0.11 --
ln(POP) 0.63 0.28 0.45 -0.23 0.16 --












































154

Table 4-3: Correlation Coefficient of Dependent Variables
ln(Sales) ln(Seats) ln(Venues) ln(Days)
ln(Sales) --
ln(Seats) 0.87 --
ln(Venues) 0.51 0.57 --
ln(Days) 0.80 0.86 0.73 --















































155

Table 4-4: Results of the Demand Model
Parameter Effect Median (Std Dev)
ln(Sales): Expected ticket sales in a market
o
0

o
1
o
2
o
3
o
4
o
5
o
6
Intercept
Effect of geographic coverage
Effect of intensity
Effect of variance
Effect of across-market carryover
Effect of within-market carryover
Effect of population size
5.329 (1.164)
0.161 (0.073)
0.128 (0.168)
0.235 (0.038)
0.002 (0.063)
0.083 (0.021)
0.264 (0.086)
**
*


**


**
**
** significant at the 95% highest posterior density







































156

Table 4-5: Results of the Supply Model
Parameters Median (Std Dev)
ln(Seats): Expected number of seats supplied in a market
|
0
|
1
|
2
Intercept
Effect of expected market sales
Effect of population
4.766
0.771
-
0.073
(0.832)
(0.086)
(0.050)
**
**


ln(Venues): Expected number of venues needed
¸
0
¸
1
¸
2
¸
3
Intercept
Effect of planned overall supply
Effect of market land area
Effect of market population density
-4.621 (0.709)
0.473 (0.067) -
0.042 (0.046) -
0.087 (0.050)
**
**


ln(Days): Expected number of days needed
u
0
u
1
u
2
u
3
Intercept
Effect of planned overall supply
Effect avg. venue capacity
Effect of housing value
-2.169 (1.097)
0.929 (0.070) -
0.703 (0.098) -
0.024 (0.028)
**
**
**
** significant at the 95% highest posterior density


























157

Table 4-6: Correlation between Supply and Demand Models
E
c
Sales

c
Seats

c
Venues

c
Days

c
Sales

--
0.549 **
-0.169
0.499 **

c
Seats



--
-0.280
0.823 **

c
Venues




--
-0.273
** significant at the 95% highest posterior density












































158

Figure 4-1: Conceptual Framework

Sales in Previous
Markets and Venues




Scheduling costs Market Carryovers across
& constraints Characteristics and within a market




Supply of an Event
(Scheduling Decisions)
1. Overall supply
2. Venue usage
3. Day usage













Endogeneity





Demand for an Event
Ticket sales
at a market level





























159

Figure 4-2: Illustration of Market Connectedness
Case (1): Apart
(1.a) A few days apart (1.b) Tightly connect




Case (2): Overlap
(2.a) Little overlapped (2.b) Much overlapped





Case (3): In between a market of multiple venues
(3.a) In between a break (3.b) Overlap with one venue




(3.c) Between and overlap
previous market m'
current market m





























160

Figure 4-3: Overview of Model Development




Market land
area

¸
2




Population
density

¸
3








Market
population




Across?market
carryover

o
4


o
6




Within?market
carryover

o
5
|
2



Seats


|
1


¸
1



u
1






u
2


Venues

Days






u
3

Size of
Trading Area

Intensity

Variance


o
1


o
2

o
3



Sales
Venue Rental
capacity facility fees

































161

Figure 4-4: Venue Locations
(a) Greenville-Asheville (b) Raleigh-Fayetteville














(c) Norfolk-Hampton




















































































(d) New York






































































(e) Champaign-Springfield (f) Philadelphia























162

Figure 4-5: Touring Dates across Markets


6/27/2004

6/7/2004

5/18/2004

4/28/2004

4/8/2004

3/19/2004

2/28/2004

2/8/2004

1/19/2004

12/30/2003
1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35 37 39 41
Market ID
































163

P
e
r
f
o
r
m
a
n
c
e

D
a
t
e
s


Figure 4-6: Capacity-Filled Rate across Markets
60%

50%

40%

30%

20%

10%

0
%
1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35 37 39 41
Market ID





































164

%

C
a
p
a
c
i
t
y

F
i
l
l
e
d


5 Conclusion




5.1 Summary

Scheduling is an important decision facing event marketers in the live entertainment

industry. When they schedule a tour for an event, they have to design a performance schedule

within each participating market and determine an overall travel sequence across markets.

Therefore, their scheduling decisions are within and across markets, which may have different

effects on ticket sales.

Although marketing research in the live entertainment industry has focused on

identifying drivers for ticket sales, researchers have not evaluated whether the scheduling

decisions influence how markets respond. In other words, researchers treat the supply and

demand for an event as two separate problems and they have not yet investigated the relationship

between supply and demand.

As such, this dissertation analyzes performance schedules of a live performance event

and examines the effects on ticket sales within and across markets. Specifically, essay one

investigates whether and how performances of similar scheduling characteristics sell differently

in terms of how many tickets each performance sells and when ticket sales arrive. We use the

venue locations and performance dates as the scheduling characteristics for each performance

and measure the similarity in these scheduling characteristics by the geographic distance between

venues and the temporal distance between performance dates.

Methodologically, we use the competing destination model to examine the number of

ticket sales and the Weibull hazard model for the timing of ticket sales. In addition, we also

control for a possible endogeneity between a performance schedule and it demand effect. Using



165

70 performances in the New York market, we show that performances sell differently depending

on how similar their venue locations and performance dates are.

In other words, when performances are in the same or nearby venues, they have higher

similarity in a geographic schedule. From consumers' perspective, they may perceive nearby

venues to be more attractive due to this similarity in venue locations. As a result, more

consumers purchase tickets for those performances and they are more willing to purchase these

tickets early. On the other hand, when performances are on the same or closer dates, they have

higher similarity in a temporal schedule. Because consumers often have uncertainty about their

consumption state and prefer various attendance timing for choices, shorter temporal distance

between performances result in higher competition and sales cannibalization.

Since results in essay one are limited in the New York metropolitan market, essay two

analyzes performance schedules across 42 markets and examines whether the results in essay one

are heterogeneous across markets and if there are any explanatory factors to explain differences

across markets. We first conduct a preliminary analysis using the same model developed in

essay one and compare the effects of scheduling characteristics across markets. After confirming

the heterogeneous market responses to performance schedules, we employ the hierarchical

Bayesian approach to identify explanatory factors for differences across markets.

Our results show that market population, geographic adjacency between markets, and

temporal sequence in an event distribution can explain different market responses. First, when a

market has a bigger population, the effects of days of week and baseline attractiveness are

attenuated. Second, with respect to a current market, after an event travels to more of its

geographically adjacent markets, the current market is less responsive to its baseline

attractiveness and temporal schedule. Third, after an event follows its temporal sequence to



166

perform in several markets, a current market in a late distribution sequence tends to respond

more favorably to a Sunday performance.

As such, essay one examines the impact of a performance schedule in a single market,

and essay two analyzes all performance schedules observed in the dataset and uses market and

additional scheduling characteristics to explain different market responses. However, the event

in our dataset is sequentially distributed across its participating markets. It is important to

understand whether the carryover effect exists due to an event distribution and how this

carryover effect influences ticket sales of participating markets.

Therefore, essay three analyzes the distribution of this live performance event and

examines whether ticket sales of preceding markets carry over to following markets and

influence ticket sales in those following markets. Besides controlling for the effect of a

performance schedule within a market, we model ticket sales of each market as a function of its

potential carryovers from an event distribution. We also model the supply and demand for an

event simultaneously to account for a possible endogeneity. Specifically, we use the size of

trading area(s) of scheduled venue(s) in a market and flexibility in the distribution of

performance dates in a schedule to represent the scheduling influences and employ the spatially

weighted approach to incorporated carryovers of preceding markets and their different release

timing.

Our results show that when an event has a larger trading area in a market and/or offers

more performances along a dispersed time span, it tends to sell more tickets in this market.

Moreover, we show that an event distribution has an effect on ticket sales. However, the effect

of carryovers is significant across venues of the same market but not across markets. When an





167

event performs in more than one venue, its ticket sales in a preceding venue carry over to a later

venue and influence its overall market sales.

5.2 General Discussions

In general, this dissertation indicates several scheduling effects. We classify these effects

into effect of within-market scheduling and effect of across-market scheduling. Moreover, we

study the effect of within-market scheduling into two aspects. Essays one and two focus on the

effect of within-market scheduling at a performance level, yet essay three addresses the same

effect at a market level. We sum up these scheduling effects and discuss the differences in turn.

First, for the effect of within-market scheduling at a performance level in essays one and

two, we find that the effect of a geographic schedule differs from the effect of a temporal

schedule. The similarity in venue locations benefit ticket sales at a performance level but the

similarity in performance dates cannibalizes ticket sales. Moreover, market responses to

performance schedules are heterogeneous and can be explained via the market and additional

scheduling characteristics. Second, for the effect of within-market scheduling at a market level

in essay three, we find that an event sells more tickets when it employs more venues in its

geographic schedule and serve a bigger trading area. It also sells more when the distribution of

its performance dates in a temporal schedule has a big variance to offer consumers greater

flexibility in attendance timing. Third, for the effect of across-market scheduling in essay three,

we find that markets are not dependent on one another, but venues within the same market have a

dependent relationship to influence ticket sales in this market.

Although the effect of a geographic schedule at a performance level seems contradictory

to the effect at a market level, these results are in fact complimentary. Although the first two

essays suggest event marketers to decrease the geographic distance between performances and



168

increase the similarity in venue locations, this suggestion is for markets that employing multiple

venues only. When an event performs in just one single venue, event marketers can follow the

learning in essay three to select a venue that has the biggest trading area. In other words, if event

marketers decide to schedule an event in multiple venues, they can apply their learning in essay

three to select venues and then allocate performances to these venues based on the first two

essays.

Consequently, the order of these essays allows us to understand the scheduling effects

from a performance level to a market level. Essay one starts with examining the effect of a

performance schedule at a performance level in a single market and concludes that performances

scheduled closely in distance but distantly in time can experience more ticket sales. In addition,

essay one also suggests performances experiencing earlier timing of ticket sales when these

performances are scheduled in nearby venues. To test the generalizability of these results and

explain the heterogeneity across markets, essay two expands the scope of analysis and confirms

the scheduling impact in all participating markets of a touring event.

Finally, essay three examines whether an event has a carryover effect when it

sequentially distributes across markets. This essay concludes that markets do not influence one

another on their ticket sales yet their venues within the same market have such an effect.

Although one may argue that the third essay does not have to be conducted after the first two

essays, we choose this sequence to investigate the carryover effect after we can understand and

control for the effect of a performance schedule within a market.

Finally, although it is arguable that essay three could have used the density measures

developed in essay one, we choose to use three variables for the following reasons. First, the

scheduling characteristics represent the similarity between performances in a schedule. They do



169

not represent how well an event is able to serve its trading area at a market level or express the

flexibility in attendance timing in a temporal schedule. Second, the measure of geographic

density in essay one is applicable only when an event performs in multiple venues in a market.

For markets where an event performs in one venue only, there is no variation in its geographic

distance yet the trading area of this single venue could still influence ticket sales. Therefore, it is

necessary to use different measures to differentiate the effect of scheduling characteristics at a

performance level from the effect of a performance schedule at a market level.

5.3 Contributions

This dissertation has both empirical and academic contributions to the marketing field.

Empirically, we show that performance schedules do affect ticket sales. Managers can use

performance schedules to estimate ticket sales at a performance or market level. Event

marketers can use these estimates as benchmarks to monitor a pattern of ticket sales and even

allocate marketing resources accordingly.

Academically, the findings in this dissertation enrich literature in event tickets and

sequential distribution. We introduce new drivers of ticket sales to the event tickets literature

such that researchers can use new differential measures to explain variations in the number and

timing of ticket sales. Moreover, we examine a sequential distribution problem in a new context

where simultaneous planning is needed and find the effect of sequential distribution only within

a local market but not across markets.

5.4 Limitation and Future Research

The primary limitation in this dissertation is that we do not have access to consumer

identification data. Although individual transactions are observed, we cannot model a

consumer's decision process to understand the effect of a performance schedule at a finer level.



170

To resolve this issue, we could apply an agent based modeling approach. Using our model

results as aggregated parameter values, we can further simulate individual consumers in a market

using the U.S. Census data and allow variations in agents' preferences. This future direction will

better assist event marketers in performance scheduling and allow researchers to study marketing

problems using a complexity system.

Another future research lies in the pricing structure of event tickets. As our data suggest,

the total price that a consumer pays includes the face value, facility fees, and convenience

charges, where face value represents the highest share in the total price paid, followed by

convenience charges and facility fees. When summarizing consumers' channel usage, we find

that consumers tend to purchase in box offices to avoid paying for convenience fees. However,

convenience fees are the major revenue source for ticket sellers. If ticket sellers and event

promoters could collaborate and re-structure the pricing breakdowns (e.g., the merger between

Ticketmaster, a primary ticket seller, and Live Nation, an event promoter), it is likely that

consumers' ticket purchases will migrate to the Internet or other channels. This new topic

involves pricing and channel strategies and we leave it for a future direction.






















171

Reference

Applebaum, William (1966), "Methods for Determining Store Trade Areas, Market Penetration,
and Potential Sales," Journal of Marketing Research, 3 (2), pp.127-141.

Basuroy, Suman, Kalpesh Kaushik Desai, and Debabrata Talukdar (2006), "An Empirical
Investigation of Signaling in the Motion Picture Industry," Journal of Marketing Research, 43
(2), pp.287-295.

Betancourt, Roger R. (2004), Economics of Retailing and Distribution, Edward Elgar Publishing
Ltd.

Bradlow, Eric T., Bart Bronnenberg, Gary J. Russell, Neeraj Arora, Sri Devi Duvvuri, Frankel
Ter Hofstede, Catarina Sismeiro, Raphael Thomadsen, and Sha Yang (2005), "Spatial Models in
Marketing," Marketing Letters, 16 (3-4) pp.267-278.

Bronnenberg, Bart J. and Carl F. Mela (2004), "Market Roll-Out and Retailer Adoption for New
Brands," Marketing Science, 23 (4), pp.500-518.

Cachon, Gérard P. (2004), "The Allocation of Inventory Risk in a Supply Chain: Push, Pull, and
Advance-Purchase Discount Contracts," Management Science, 50 (2), p.222-238.

Carlyle, Kellie E., Michael D. Slater, and Jennifer L. Chakroff (2008), "Newspaper Coverage of
Intimate Partner Violence: Skewing Representations of Risk," Journal of Communication, 58 (1),
pp168-186.

Chintagunta, Pradeep K., Shyam Gopinath, and Sriram Venkataraman (2009), "Online Word-of-
mouth Effecs on the Offline Sales of Sequentially released new products: An Application to the
Movie Market," working paper.

Choi, Jeonghye, Sam K. Hui, David R. Bell (2009), "Spatio-Temporal Analysis of Imitation
Behavior in Adoption of an Online Grocery Retailer," Journal of Marketing Research,
forthcoming.

Chu, Wujin and Woosik Chu (1994), "Signaling Quality by Selling through a Reputable Retailer:
an Example of Renting the Reputation of Another Agent," Marketing Science, 13 (2), pp.177-
189.

Cliquet, Gerard (1998), "Integration and territory coverage of the hypermarket industry in France:
A relative entropy measure," International Review of Retail, Distribution and Consumer
Research, 8 (2), pp.205-224.

Corning, Jonathan and Armando Levy (2002), "Demand for Live Theater with Market
Segmentation and Seasonality," Journal of Cultural Economics, 26 (3), pp.217-235.




172

Currim, Imran S., Charles B. Weinberg, Dick R. Wittink (1981), "Design of Subscription
Programs for a Performing Arts Series," Journal of Consumer Research, 8 (2), pp.67-75

Desiraju, Ramarao and Steven M. Shugan (1999), "Strategic Service Pricing and Yield
Management," Journal of Marketing, 63 (1), pp.44-56.

Dobson, Gregory and Phillip J. Lederer Lederer (1993), "Airline Scheduling and Routing in a
Hub-and-Spoke System," Transportation Science, 27 (3), pp.281-297.

Donthu, Naveen and Roland T. Rust (1989), "Estimating Geographic Customer Densities Using
Kernel Density Estimation," Marketing Science, 8 (2), pp.191-203.

Dorndorf, Ulrich, Florian Jaehn, Chen Lin, Hui Ma, and Erwin Pesch (2007), "Disruption
Management in Flight Gate Scheduling," Statistica Neerlandica, 61 (1), pp.92-114.

Elberse, Anita and Jehoshua Eliashberg (2003), "Demand and Supply Dynamics for Sequentially
Released Products in International Markets: The Case of Motion Pictures," Marketing Science, 22
(3), pp.329-354.

Eliashberg, Jehoshua, Sanjeev Swami, Charles B. Weinberg, and Berend Wierenga (2009),
"Evolutionary Approach o the Development of Decision Support Systems in the Movie Industry,"
Decision Support Systems, 47 (1), p.1-12.

____, Anita Elberse, and Mark A.A.M. Leenders (2006), "The Motion Picture Industry: Critical
Issues in Practice, Current Research, and New Research Directions," Marketing Science, 25 (6),
pp.638-661.

____, Quintus Hegie, Jason Ho, Dennis Huisman, Steven J. Miller, Sanjeev Swami, Charles B.
Weinberg, and Berend Wierenga (2007), "Demand-Driven Scheduling of Movies in a Multiplex,"
working paper.

Etschmaier, Maximilian M. and Dennis F. X. Mathaisel (1985), "Airline Scheduling: An
Overview," Transportation Science, 19 (2), pp.127-138.

Fotheringham, A. Stewart (1983), "Some theoretical aspects of destination choice and their
relevance to production-constrained gravity models," Environment and Planning A, 15 (8),
pp.1121-1132.

____ (1988), "Consumer Store Choice and Choice Set Definition," Marketing Science, 7 (3),
pp.299-310.

Gallego, Guillerimo and Garrett van Ryzin (1994), "Optimal Dynamic Pricing of Inventories
with Stochastic Demand over Finite Horizons," Management Science, 40 (8), pp.999-1020.

González-Benito, Óscar (2005), "Spatial Competitive Interaction of Retail Store Formats:
Modeling Proposal and Empirical Results," Journal of Business Research, 58 (4), pp.457-466.


173

Havlena, William J. and Susan L. Holak (1988), "The Influence of Variety on the Demand for
Bundles of Musical Performances," Advances in Consumer Research, 15, pp.22-26.

Hennig-Thurau, Thorsten, Mark B. Houston, Gianfranco Walsh (2006), "The Differing Roles of
Success Drivers Across Sequential Channels: An Application to the Motion Picture Industry,"
Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 34 (4), pp.559-575.

____, Victor Henning, Henrik Sattler, Felix Eggers, and Mark B. Houston (2007), "The Last
Picture Show? Timing and Order of Movie Distribution Channels," Journal of Marketing, 71 (4),
pp.63-83.

Huber, Joel, John W. Payne, and Christopher Puto (1982), "Adding Asymmetrically Dominated
Alternatives: Violations of Regularity and the Similarity Hypothesis," Journal of Consumer
Research, 9 (1), pp.90-98.

____ and Christopher Puto (1983), "Market Boundaries and Product Choice: Illustrating
Attraction and Substitution Effects," Journal of Consumer Research, 10 (1), pp.31-44.

Huff, David L. (1964), "Defining and Estimating a Trading Area," Journal of Marketing, 28 (3),
pp.34-38.

Jank, Wolfgang and P.K. Kannan (2005), "Understanding Geographic Markets of Online Firms
Using Spatial Models of Consumer Choice," Marketing Science, 24 (4), pp.623-634.

Jarrah, Ahmad I., Jon Goodstein, and Ram Narasimhan (2000), "An Efficient Airline Re-
Fleeting Model for the Incremental Modification of Planned Fleet Assignments," Transportation
Science, 34 (4), pp.349-362.

Kamakura, Wagner A. and Gary J. Russell (1989), "A Probabilistic Choice Model for Market
Segmentation and Elasticity Structure," Journal of Marketing Research, 26 (4), pp. 379-390.

Lehmann, Donald R. and Charles B. Weinberg (2000), "Sales Through Sequential Distribution
Channels: An Application to Movies and Videos," Journal of Marketing, 64 (3), pp.18-33.

Leslie, Phillip (2004), "Price Discrimination in Broadway Theater," RAND Journal of
Economics, 35 (3), pp.520-541.

Lohatepanont, Manoj and Cynthia Barnhart (2004), "Airline Schedule Planning: Integrated
Models and Algorithms for Schedule Design and Fleet Assignment," Transportation Science, 38
(1), pp.19-32.

Luce, R. Duncan (1959), Individual Choice Behavior, New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

Lutz, Nancy A. and V. Padmanabhan (1995), "Why do We Observe Minimal Warranties?"
Marketing Science, 14 (4), pp.417-441.



174

Manchanda, Puneet, Peter E. Rossi, and Pradeep K. Chintagunta (2004), "Response Modeling
with Nonrandom Marketing-Mix Variables," Journal of Marketing Research, 41 (4), pp.467-478.

Mazzeo, Michael J. (2002), "Product Choice and Oligopoly Market Structure," RAND Journal of
Economics, 33 (2), pp.221-242.

McCardle, Kevin, Kumar Rajaram, Christopher S. Tang (2004), "Advance Booking Discount
Programs Under Retail Competition," Management Science, 50 (5), pp.701-708.

McFadden, Daniel L. (1974), "Conditional Logit Analysis of Qualitative Choice Behavior," in
P.Zarembka, ed., Frontiers in Econometrics, Academic Press, New York, pp.105-142.

McGill, Jeffrey I. and Garrett J. van Ryzin (1999), "Revenue Management: Research Overview
and Prospects," Transportation Science, 33 (2), pp.233-256.

Moe, Wendy W. and Peter S. Fader (2002), "Using Advance Purchase Orders to Forecast New
Product Sales," Marketing Science, 21 (3), pp.347-364.

____ and ____ (2009), "The Role of Price Tiers in Advance Purchasing of Event Tickets,"
Journal of Service Research, forthcoming.

Moore, Thomas Gale (1966), "The Demand for Broadway Theatre Tickets," The Review of
Economics and Statistics, 48 (1), pp.79-87.

Moorthy, Sridhar and Kannan Srinivasan (1995), "Signaling Quality with a Money-Back
Guarantee: The Role of Transaction Costs," Marketing Science, 14 (4), pp.442-466.

Ntzoufras, Ioannis (2009), Bayesian Modeling Using WinBUGS, John Wiley & Sons, Inc.,
Hoboken, New Jersey.

Okada, Erica Mina (2005), "Justification Effects on Consumer Choice of Hedonic and Utilitarian
Goods," Journal of Marketing Research, 42 (1), pp.43-53.

Orhun, A. Yesim (2005), "Spatial Differentiation in the Supermarket Industry," working paper.

Padmanabhan, V. and Ram C. Rao (1993), "Warranty Policy and Extended Service Contracts:
Theory and an Application to Automobiles," Marketing Science, 12 (3), pp.230-247.

Prelec, Drazen and George Loewenstein (1998), "The Red and the Black: Mental Accounting of
Savings and Debt," Marketing Science, 17 (1), pp.4-28.

Purohit, Devavrat and Joydeep Srivastava (2001), "Effect of Manufacturer Reputation, Retailer
Reputation, and Product Warranty on Consumer Judgments of Product Quality: A Cue
Diagnosticity Framework," Journal of Consumer Psychology, 10 (3), pp.123-134.




175

Putler, Daniel S. and Shilpa Lele (2003), "An Easily Implemented Framework for Forecasting
Ticket Sales to Performing Arts Events," Marketing Letters, 14 (4), pp.307-320.

Reddy, Srinivas K., Vanitha Swaminathan, and Carol M. Motley (1998), "Exploring the
Determinants of Broadway Show Success," Journal of Marketing Research, 35 (3), pp.370-383.

Rossi, Peter E. and Greg M. Allenby (2003), "Bayesian Statistics and Marketing," Marketing
Science, 22 (3), pp.304-328.

Seim, Katja (2006), "An Empirical Model for Firm Entry with Endogenous Product-Type
Choices," RAND Journal of Economics, 37 (3), pp.619-640.

Shugan, Steven M. and Jinhong Xie (2000), "Advance Pricing of Services and Other
Implications of Separating Purchase and Consumption," Journal of Service Research, 2 (3),
pp.227-239.

Simonson (1989), "Choice Based on Reasons: The Case of Attraction and Compromise Effects,"
Journal of Consumer Research, 16 (3), pp.158-174.

Soberman, David A. (2003), "Simultaneous Signaling and Screening with Warranties," Journal of
Marketing Research, 40 (2), pp.176-192.

Spiegelhalter, David J., Nicola G. Best, Bradley P. Carlin, and Angelika van der Linde (2002),
"Bayesian Measures of Model Complexity and Fit," Journal of the Royal Statistical Society:
Series B (Statistical Methodology) , 64 (4), pp.583-639.

Swami, Sanjeev, Jehoshua Eliashberg, and Charles B. Weinberg (1999), "SliverScreener: a
Modeling Approach to Movie Screens Management," Marketing Science, 18 (3), pp.352-372.

Talluri, Kalyan and Garrett van Ryzin (2004), "Revenue Management Under a General Discrete
Choice Model of Consumer Behavior," Management Science, 50 (1), pp.15-33.

Tang, Christopher S., Kumar Rajaram, Aydin Alptekinoglu, and Jihong Ou (2004), "The
Benefits of Advance Booking Discount Program: Model and Analysis," Management Science, 50
(4), pp.465-478.

Thomadsen, Raphael (2007), "Product Positioning and Competition: The Role of Location in the
Fast Food Industry," Marketing Science, 26 (6), pp.792-804.

Venkatesh R. and Vijay Mahajan (1993), "A Probabilistic Approach to Pricing a Bundle of
Products or Services," Journal of Marketing Research, 30 (4), pp.494-508.

Vitorino, Maria Ana (2007), "Empirical Entry Games with complementarities: an Application to
the Shopping Center Industry," working paper.

Watson, Randal (2005), "Entry and Location Choice in Eyewear Retailing," working paper.


176

Weinberg, Charles B. and Kenneth M. Shachmut (1978), "ARTS PLAN: a Model Based System
for Use in Planning a Performing Arts Series," Management Science, 24 (6), pp.654-664.

___ (1986), "ARTS PLAN: Implementation, Evolution, and Usage," Marketing Science, 5 (2),
pp.143-158.

Weatherford, Lawrence R., Samuel E. Bodily, and Phillip E. Pfeifer (1993), "Modeling the
Customer Arrival Process and Comparing Decision Rules in Perishable Asset Revenue
Management Situations," Transportation Science, 27 (3), pp.239-251.

Weiner , Richard (2000), "Of Bulldog Editions and Matters," Public Relations Tactics, 7 (9),
pp.7.

Xie, Jinhong and Steven M. Shugan (2001), "Electronic Tickets, Smart Cards, and Online
Prepayments: When and How to Advance Sell," Marketing Science, 20 (3), pp.219-243.

Yang, Sha and Greg M. Allenby (2003), "Modeling Interdependent Consumer Preferences,"
Journal of Marketing Research, 40 (3), pp.282-294.

Zhu, Ting and Vishal Singh (2009), "Spatial Competition with Endogenous Location Choices: an
Application to Discount Retailing," Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 7 (1), pp.1-35.

___, ___, and Mark Manuszak (2009), "Market Structure and Competition in the Retail Discount
Industry," Journal of Marketing Research, forthcoming.

__, __, and Anthony Dukes (2007), "Local Competition, Entry, and Agglomeration," working
paper.
























177


doc_113992125.docx
 

Attachments

Back
Top