Description
How, exactly, does offering student discounts raise a seller’s producer surplus?From our study of market power in Chapter 9, we know that when a firm can influence
its own price, it makes a higher profit than a perfectly competitive (i.e., pricetaking)
company. The market power pricing rule we came up with, however, requiredthe
firm to charge the same price to all customers. In this chapter, we see that ifa
firm can charge different prices to different groups of customers (e.g., studentsand
nonstudents), it can raise surplus and profit above those earned by a standardmonopolist
charging every customer the same price. There are many ways in whichfirms
with market power can charge different prices for the same good. This chapterexplores
the most common of these strategies and looks at how they affect producersand
consumers in the market.
Y
ou’ve no doubt noticed many places where you can receive price discounts
if you show your student ID. Commonly discounted goods include movie ad-
missions, clothing at the campus bookstore, gym memberships, train fare,
and even computer equipment.
It’s nice of these sellers to give you a price break while you’re getting your education.
School isn’t cheap, and every little bit helps. The sellers’ generosity must say something
about the value that they put on everyone receiving a good education. Right?
Not really. The main motivation behind such student discounts isn’t altruism. Instead, it
is almost surely the sellers’ attempt to extract more producer surplus from the market than
they would otherwise. That’s not to say you’re worse off because they’ve offered these
discounts; in fact, they make it more likely you will be able to consume goods that would
otherwise be too expensive for you. But there’s something in it for the sellers, too — these
discounts increase their producer surplus and improve their bottom lines.
Market Power and
Pricing Strategies
10
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 395 11/5/12 4:01 PM
396 Part 3 Markets and Prices
How, exactly, does offering student discounts raise a seller’s producer surplus?
From our study of market power in Chapter 9, we know that when a firm can influ-
ence its own price, it makes a higher profit than a perfectly competitive (i.e., price-
taking) company. The market power pricing rule we came up with, however, required
the firm to charge the same price to all customers. In this chapter, we see that if
a firm can charge different prices to different groups of customers (e.g., students
and nonstudents), it can raise surplus and profit above those earned by a standard
monopolist charging every customer the same price. There are many ways in which
firms with market power can charge different prices for the same good. This chapter
explores the most common of these strategies and looks at how they affect producers
and consumers in the market.
10.1 The Basics of Pricing Strategy
A pricing strategy is a firm’s plan for setting the price of its product given the mar-
ket conditions it faces and its desire to maximize profit. The pricing strategy for a
perfectly competitive firm is that it charges the equilibrium market price for its prod-
uct and earns no economic profit. The pricing strategy for firms with market power is
more complex. A firm with market power that charges one price to all its customers
sets the market price according to the quantity of output it chooses to produce to
maximize its profit. (Remember that firms operating in markets with barriers to entry
are able to earn economic profits even in the long run.) Some firms with market power,
however, can charge different prices to different customers for the same product using
a pricing strategy called price discrimination. If a firm with market power can price
discriminate, it can earn greater economic profit than a single-price monopoly.
It is important to understand that price discrimination is not the same phenom-
enon as the existence of different prices for different goods. Price differences can
occur across similar products even in a competitive market if the marginal costs of
producing the products are different. For example, if the marginal cost of washing
SUVs at the car wash is higher than that of washing Mini Coopers because SUVs are
bigger, car washes might charge more to wash SUVs. Price discrimination is some-
thing different. It implies the use of market power to charge higher prices for the same
product to those consumers who are willing to pay more for it. Price variations due
to price discrimination do not reflect differences in marginal costs; they exist simply
because the firm with market power has the ability to charge different prices for the
same product.
There are several pricing strategies a company can use depending on its circum-
stances. These range from direct price discrimination to indirect price discrimina-
tion to bundling to two-part tariffs and beyond. The motivation for these strategies is
straightforward: A company with market power charges a higher price for the units of
output that provide consumers with greater consumer surplus. By adjusting the price,
a firm extracts more producer surplus from each transaction.
When Can a Firm Pursue a Pricing Strategy?
All the pricing strategies we discuss in this chapter start from two key requirements:
Requirement 1: The firm must have market power. A company must have market
power to price discriminate. It’s that simple. If the firm you have in mind does not have
market power, you are in the wrong chapter of the book. You should be in Chapter 8 on
perfect competition. Without market power, a firm can’t choose its price at all, much
less choose to charge different prices to different consumers or use more advanced pricing
strategies.
10.1 The Basics of
Pricing Strategy
10.2 Direct Price
Discrimination I:
Perfect/First-
Degree Price
Discrimination
10.3 Direct Price
Discrimination II:
Segmenting/
Third-Degree Price
Discrimination
10.4 Indirect/Second-
Degree Price
Discrimination
10.5 Bundling
10.6 Advanced Pricing
Strategies
10.7 Conclusion
pricing strategy
A ?rm’s method of pricing
its product based on market
characteristics.
price discrimination
The practice of charging
different prices to different
customers for the same
product.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 396 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 397
Requirement 2: The firm must prevent resale and arbitrage. To take advantage of
advanced pricing strategies, a firm must be able to prevent its customers from reselling
its product among themselves. Otherwise, the customers able to buy units at a low price
could purchase a large number of units and resell them to other customers who would
otherwise have had to buy the product from the firm at a higher price. The practice of
taking advantage of price differences for a product by buying at a lower price and resell-
ing at a higher price is called arbitrage.
The ability to engage in arbitrage makes all customers better off. The low-price custom-
ers make a profit on resale, and the high-price consumers can buy the product at a lower
price than the firm would charge. The firm isn’t better off, though. It is effectively shut
out from directly selling to any consumers except those who want to buy at the lowest
price. Because it would then be selling at only one price, however, the firm would be back
in the traditional situation for a firm with market power described in Chapter 9: It should
produce the quantity at which marginal revenue equals marginal cost and charge the price
at which buyers would consume that quantity (and therefore not worry about resellers).
If a firm meets these two requirements, it can attempt to implement more profitable
pricing strategies. Figure 10.1 provides an overview of these strategies.
arbitrage
The practice of reselling a
product at a price higher
than its original selling
price.
Figure 10.1 An Overview of Pricing Strategies
Does the firm have
market power?
Can the firm
prevent resale
and arbitrage?
Do the firm’s
customers
have different
demand curves?
Can the firm directly
identify customers’
demands before they
buy the product?
Direct price
discrimination
Firm has complete
information about
every customer.
Perfect (first-degree)
price discrimination
(Section 10.2)
Perfect competition
produces quantity at which
MR = P = MC (Chapter 8)
Advanced pricing strategies
(Section 10.6)
Monopoly produces
quantity (Q*) at which
MR = MC, sets price P*
where Q* = D(P*) (Chapter 9)
Firm has information
on groups
of customers.
Segmenting (third-degree)
price discrimination
(Section 10.3)
• Block pricing
• Two-part tariff
Indirect (second-degree)
price discrimination
(Section 10.4)
Bundling (Section 10.5)
• Quantity discounts
• Versioning
• Coupons
No
No
No
No Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
A firm’s optimal pricing strategy is deter-
mined by characteristics of the firm, its
product, and its consumers. In particular,
a firm takes into account its degree of
market power, whether the product can be
resold, and its knowledge of its customers’
demand for the product.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 397 11/5/12 4:01 PM
398 Part 3 Markets and Prices
Strategies for Customers with Diferent Demands The first pricing strate-
gies we look at involve price discrimination. For price discrimination to be an option,
a firm needs to have different types of customers with different price sensitivities of
demand. The exact kind of price discrimination the firm should use depends on the kind
of information the firm has.
1. Can a firm identify its customers’ demands before they buy? If the firm has
complete, detailed information about each customer’s own demand curve before she buys
the product, it can practice perfect price discrimination and charge every customer a
different price. If information about its customers is less detailed, a firm may be able to
discriminate by customer group, as in third-degree price discrimination. The key to these
kinds of price discrimination is that a firm must be able to directly identify different
customers or groups of customers (as can a store that requires students to show IDs when
making purchases) and charge different prices to each customer or group of customers.
2. Can a firm identify its customers’ differing demands only after they make a
purchase? If a firm cannot identify different types of consumers before they make their
purchases, it can try more indirect price discrimination, which involves offering different
pricing packages and then identifying the customer’s type from the pricing package she
chooses. These pricing packages can take the form of quantity discounts, different ver-
sions of the product at different prices, or (under the right conditions) bundling together
different products.
Do a Firm’s Customers Have the Same Demand Curves? There is still an-
other set of pricing strategies that a firm can use even if its consumers have the same de-
mand curves. These strategies involve offering different unit prices to the same customer
for different quantities purchased or charging lump-sum fees on top of per-unit prices.
We explore all these strategies in the remainder of this chapter. To help clarify a
firm’s decision, each pricing strategy section has a When to Use It feature that explains
what a firm needs to know about its market and customers to use a given pricing strat-
egy most effectively. By using the best strategy, the firm can extract the most producer
surplus from the market.
10.2
Direct Price Discrimination I:
Perfect/First-Degree Price Discrimination
When to Use It Perfect/First-Degree Price Discrimination
1. The firm has market power and can prevent resale.
2. The firm’s customers have different demand curves.
3. The firm has complete information about every customer and can identify each
one’s demand before purchase.
Let’s start our study of pricing strategies by looking at a firm that has market power,
can prevent resale, and knows that its consumers differ in their willingness to pay and
therefore have different demand curves. To choose a price discrimination strategy that
will allow the firm to reap the greatest benefits of these three characteristics, the firm
must first ask itself whether it can directly identify what type of demand its customers
have before they purchase the product, or whether it can determine this only after they
buy the product. That is, do the buyers have some identifiable characteristic that allows
the firm to observe their sensitivity to price and willingness to pay for the firm’s prod-
uct? If they do, the company can directly identify its customers’ demands beforehand
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 398 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 399
and increase its producer surplus by using direct price discrimination, that is, by
charging different prices to different customers based on something that a firm can
observe directly about its customers’ identities. If it can know its consumers’ demands
only after they buy the product, then the firm has to use indirect price discrimina-
tion, which we discuss later in the chapter.
Let’s first consider the possibilities for a firm that has so much information about
its customers before they buy that it knows each individual buyer’s demand curve
and can charge each buyer a different price equal to the buyer’s willingness to pay.
This type of direct price discrimination is known as perfect price discrimination or
first-degree price discrimination.
Suppose a firm faces a market demand curve like the one labeled D in Figure 10.2.
Panel a shows the outcomes for a perfectly competitive firm and a monopolistic firm. We
know from Chapter 8 that in a perfectly competitive market, the equilibrium price (which
is the same as MR in that case) equals marginal cost MC and the firm produces quantity
Q
c
. Consumer surplus is the area under the demand curve and above the price, A + B + C.
Because we assume that marginal cost is constant, there is no producer surplus.
In Chapter 9, we saw that a firm with market power facing demand curve D and
with no ability to prevent resale produces the quantity where its marginal cost equals its
perfect price
discrimination
(?rst-degree price
discrimination)
A type of direct price dis-
crimination in which a ?rm
charges each customer ex-
actly his willingness to pay.
direct price
discrimination
A pricing strategy in which
?rms charge different
prices to different custom-
ers based on observable
characteristics of the
customers.
(a) A competitive market will set price equal to marginal
cost, producing Q
c
and selling at a price of P
c
. Consumers
will receive a consumer surplus equal to A + B + C and
the firm will earn zero producer surplus. A single-price
monopoly will sell quantity Q
m
at a price of P
m
and re-
ceive a producer surplus equal to B. Consumers will receive
consumer surplus equal to A and the deadweight loss from
market power will be area C.
(b) If a firm with market power can identify each cus-
tomer’s demand curve, then it will charge each customer
her willingness to pay and capture the entire surplus,
A + B + C. For example, the firm will charge a customer
willing to pay P
d
exactly the price P
d
and a customer
willing to pay P
f
the price P
f
. The firm will sell up to
the quantity Q
c
, the perfectly competitive quantity where
P
c
= MC. There is no deadweight loss when a firm prac-
tices perfect price discrimination.
Figure 10.2 Perfect (First-Degree) Price Discrimination
Quantity
Price
($/unit)
(a) Perfect competition and monopoly (b) Perfect price discrimination
D MR
MC
C
B
A
Q
c
Q
m
P
m
P
c
Quantity
Price
($/unit)
D MR
MC
B
C
A
Q
c
P
d
P
f
P
c
Consumer surplus (competition)
Producer surplus (competition)
Consumer surplus (market power)
Producer surplus (market power)
Deadweight loss from market power
= A + B + C
= 0
= A
= B
= C
Consumer surplus
Producer surplus
Deadweight loss from market power
= 0
= A + B + C
= 0
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 399 11/5/12 4:01 PM
400 Part 3 Markets and Prices
marginal revenue, Q
m
, and sets the price P
m
for that quantity from its demand curve. It
charges this single price to everyone in the market. This market power pricing has three
outcomes relative to the competitive pricing: (1) There is now a producer surplus equal
to the rectangle B (far better from the firm’s perspective than the competitive outcome,
no producer surplus); (2) there is now a deadweight loss equal to the triangle C, because
quantity is below its competitive level; and (3) consumer surplus is reduced to area A.
If, however, the firm with market power can prevent resale and directly identify
each and every customer’s demand curve (panel b), the outcome is very different. In
this case, the firm can charge every customer her willingness to pay for every unit (or,
to guarantee she’d take the deal, just a bit below this level). This is perfect price dis-
crimination, and the benefit to the firm is tremendous. For any unit of output where a
customer’s willingness to pay is greater than the firm’s marginal cost of producing it,
the firm captures the whole amount of available surplus. So, for example, a customer
accounting for the portion of the demand curve at P
d
pays that relatively high price,
while another at P
f
pays that relatively low price. In these and all other cases, even
though the prices are different, customers pay the most they are willing to pay, and the
firm gets the entire surplus (the area below demand and above marginal cost).
After all such transactions, the firm will have sold a quantity of Q
c
to various
consumers at different prices depending on each buyer’s willingness to pay. (Because
the firm can prevent resale, customers aren’t able to buy the product from another
customer for a lower price than the firm offers.) The producer surplus the firm earns
as a result equals the entire surplus in the market (A + B + C). This is the maximum
amount of surplus that can be made from the market because no consumer will pay
more than his or her willingness to pay (that rules out the area above the demand curve)
and the firm must pay its costs (that eliminates the area below the marginal cost curve).
It’s good to be a firm that can perfectly price discriminate.
Another interesting feature of perfect price discrimination is that, unlike the single-
price market power outcome, there is no deadweight loss! It is efficient: No potential
surplus is lost from a reduction in the equilibrium quantity. The quantity sold ( Q
c
) is the
same quantity that would be sold if the market were perfectly competitive. Who keeps
the market surplus is very different in the two cases, however: Under perfect competition,
the entire surplus goes to the consumers, while under perfect price discrimination, the
entire surplus goes to the producer. Efficiency is not the same thing as fairness. (We will
further discuss issues of market efficiency and distribution in Chapter 14.)
10.1 ?gure it out
A firm with market power faces an inverse demand
curve for its product of P = 100 – 10Q. Assume
that the firm faces a marginal cost curve of
MC = 10 + 10Q.
a. If the firm cannot price discriminate, what is
the profit-maximizing level of output and price?
b. If the firm cannot price discriminate, what
are the levels of consumer and producer surplus in
the market, assuming the firm maximizes its profit?
Calculate the deadweight loss from market power.
c. If the firm has the ability to practice perfect
price discrimination, what is the firm’s output?
d. If the firm practices perfect price discrimination,
what are the levels of consumer and producer
surplus? What is the deadweight loss from market
power?
Solution:
a. If the firm cannot price discriminate, it maxi-
mizes profit by producing where MR = MC. If the
inverse demand function is P = 100 – 10Q, then the
marginal revenue must be MR = 100 – 20Q. (Re-
member that, for any linear inverse demand function
P = a – bQ, marginal revenue is MR = a – 2bQ.)
? The online appendix
demonstrates ef?ciency for
?rms that practice perfect
price discrimination.
(http://glsmicro.com/appendices)
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 400 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 401
Setting MR = MC, we obtain
100 – 20Q = 10 + 10Q
90 = 30Q
Q = 3
To find the optimal price, we plug Q = 3 into the
inverse demand equation:
P = 100 – 10Q
= 100 – 10(3)
= 100 – 30
= 70
The firm sells 3 units at a price of $70 each.
b. To find consumer and producer surplus, we
need to start with a diagram showing the demand,
marginal revenue, and marginal cost curves:
Quantity
Price
($/unit)
MC
0
MR
D
D B
C
A
$100
10
40
70
4.5 3
Consumer surplus is the area above price and below
demand (area A). Producer surplus is the area above
marginal cost but below the price (area B + C). (Note
that we could just label these two areas as a large
trapezoid, but it is easier to remember the formulas
for the area of a rectangle and a triangle!) We can
calculate the areas:
Area A =
1
_
2
base × height
=
1
_
2
× 3 × ($100 – $70)
= 0.5(3)($30)
= $45
Consumer surplus is $45.
Area B = base × height
To get the height of areas B and C, we need the MC
of producing a quantity of 3:
MC = 10 + 10Q = 10 + 10(3) = $40. So,
Area B = 3 × ($70 – $40)
= 3($30)
= $90
Area C =
1
_
2
× base × height
=
1
_
2
× 3 × ($40 – $10)
= 0.5(3)($30)
= $45
So, Producer surplus = Area B + Area C =
$90 + $45 = $135.
The deadweight loss from market power is the
loss in surplus that occurs because the market is not
producing the competitive quantity. To calculate the
competitive quantity, we set P = MC:
100 – 10Q = 10 + 10Q
90 = 20Q
Q = 4.5
The deadweight loss can be seen on the diagram as
area D:
Area D =
1
_
2
× base × height
=
1
_
2
× (4.5 – 3) × ($70 – $40)
= 0.5(1.5)($30)
= $22.50
The deadweight loss from market power is $22.50.
c. If the firm practices perfect price
discrimination, it will produce where P = MC. As
we saw in part (b) above, this means that the firm
will produce 4.5 units.
d. If the firm practices perfect price
discrimination, consumer surplus will be zero because
every consumer will be charged a price equal to his
willingness to pay. Producer surplus will be the full
area between the demand curve and the marginal
cost curve (area A + B + C + D):
Producer surplus = area A + area B + area C + area D
= $45 + $90 + $45 + $22.50
= $202.50
There is no deadweight loss when the firm perfectly
price discriminates. The competitive output level is
achieved (Q = 4.5). Producers end up with the entire
surplus available in the market.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 401 11/5/12 4:01 PM
402 Part 3 Markets and Prices
Examples of Perfect Price Discrimination
Actual cases of died-in-the-wool perfect price discrimination are rare. What firm really
knows every single customer’s willingness to pay for its product? There are instances,
though, where sellers charge many, many different prices for the same product. Two
classic examples are cars and college education.
When people walk into a car dealership, the salesperson sizes them up and eventu-
ally begins negotiating over price. While the dealer doesn’t have complete information
about each customer’s willingness to pay, haggling differently with every customer is a
lot like perfect price discrimination — the auto dealer is trying to simultaneously learn
about the customer’s valuation of the car and arrive at a price as close as possible to
that level. That’s why you should think twice when you go to buy a car and the sales-
man asks you, “How much are you looking to spend on a car?” That’s an invitation for
you to give up your consumer surplus.
Likewise, families applying for college financial aid are required to submit complete
information about their assets and income along with the student’s assets and income.
From this information, the school has an almost perfect understanding of each student’s
willingness to pay. This allows schools to produce an individually tailored financial aid
plan. But that is another way of saying that they charge a different tuition price to each
student, depending on how much they think the student can afford.
application
How Priceline Learned That You Can’t Price Discriminate
without Market Power
Priceline is the online travel service known in part for originating the “name your own
price” model of online sales. The initial idea was that people would go to Priceline’s
site and enter what they were willing to pay for an airplane ticket— for example, $300
for a round-trip from Los Angeles to Boston on April 10th. Priceline would then see
if there were any airlines willing to supply the ticket to Priceline for less than that. If
so, Priceline would charge the customer’s credit card $300 and issue the ticket, earning
the difference as profit.
The idea was that by asking each person what she was willing to pay, Priceline
could engage in something like perfect price discrimination and therefore make a lot of
money. We can think of its original business model in terms of Figure 10.3. Priceline
figured that, with a marginal cost of tickets of MC and travelers’ willingness to pay
(demand curve) at D, it stood to earn producer surplus approximately equal to the
area A + B. The stock market liked this model, too: Within three years of starting up
its Web site, the company was valued at $13 billion, more than several of the major
airlines combined.
There was a serious problem in Priceline’s approach, however. Priceline wanted to
price discriminate, but it didn’t really have market power in the travel agency industry.
There are thousands of offline travel agencies; several other major online travel firms
like Orbitz, Travelocity, and Expedia; and airlines sell a lot of tickets directly from their
own Web sites. We know from what we’ve just learned that a company can’t price-
discriminate if it doesn’t have market power. Priceline learned this lesson the hard way.
Priceline’s problem was that, because travelers could also get fares at low prices
directly from other travel sites, they wouldn’t offer their true willingness to pay from
their demand curves. Instead, customers would only offer to buy tickets at a lower price
than they could buy them elsewhere.
Priceline’s market demand curve was therefore not the consumer’s demand curve D,
but rather a curve strictly below the market price of tickets at other sites. In the figure,
the outside price occurs at P
out
. So, the actual demand curve facing Priceline was not
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 402 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 403
D but D
act
instead. This kind of price discrimination doesn’t make large profits. It left
Priceline with a surplus of only B, the small area below the actual demand curve and
above marginal cost. Indeed, this demand curve left Priceline with less producer surplus
than that earned by other travel sites (which were charging prices at or above P
out
).
Realizing this, Priceline eventually deemphasized the “name your own price” busi-
ness model and expanded into the conventionally priced online travel business. It has
so far succeeded — its stock market valuation was back up to over $20 billion in 2011
after falling all the way to $225 million in 2000. It had a tough road back. The moral
of the story is, as always: Remember your economics. ?
10.3
Direct Price Discrimination II: Segmenting/
Third-Degree Price Discrimination
When to Use It Segmenting/Third-Degree Price Discrimination
1. The firm has market power and can prevent resale.
2. The firm’s customers have different demand curves.
3. The firm can directly identify specific groups of customers with different price
sensitivities (but not the demand of every individual customer) before purchase.
Because it’s rare for a firm to have the kind of comprehensive information about
customers that it needs to practice perfect price discrimination, a firm can’t gener-
ally capture all of the market surplus using price discrimination. But it can still earn
more profit than a regular monopoly by using a pricing strategy called segmenting
(or third-degree price discrimination), charging different prices to different groups
(segments) of customers based on the identifiable attributes of those groups.
1
With market power, Priceline could use perfect
price discrimination to capture the entire sur-
plus above MC but below D, the area A + B.
However, because it does not have market power,
Priceline’s demand curve D
act
is below demand
curve D. Using perfect price discrimination,
Priceline can only capture B, the area above MC
but below D
act
.
Figure 10.3 Perfect Price Discrimination without Market Power: What Went Wrong
with Naming Your Own Price
Quantity of
airline flights
Price
($/flight)
D
D
act
MC
B
A
P
out
Expected producer surplus
Actual producer surplus
= A + B
= B
1
While third-degree discrimination sounds like a variant of first-degree discrimination, the truth is that
these names were somewhat arbitrarily coined by economist E. H. Chamberlin back in the 1930s.
segmenting
(third-degree price
discrimination)
A type of direct price
discrimination in which
a ?rm charges different
prices to different groups
of customers.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 403 11/5/12 4:01 PM
404 Part 3 Markets and Prices
For this kind of pricing strategy to work, the company must be able to directly
identify groups of customers — students, for example — who have systematically dif-
ferent demands than other buyers. This group-level demand identification is typically
much easier to determine than figuring out every individual customer’s willingness
to pay.
Think about a company that sells a clothing line emblazoned with the logo of a local
university. If the company knows that students typically don’t have a lot of money and
tend to be bargain hunters while their parents or the faculty are less price-sensitive,
the firm will want to charge students a lower price for clothing and parents or faculty a
higher price. To do this, the company needs to be able to identify the groups directly. It
must be able to tell before the sale which customers are students and which are parents
or faculty, as well as prevent parents and faculty from pretending to be students to
get the discount. One way the company can do this is to make showing a student ID a
condition of the lower price.
As with all forms of price discrimination, however, the company must be able
to prevent resale. They can’t sell school sweatshirts at a student discount just to
have the students then turn around and sell them to visiting parents or faculty for
less than the higher price these groups would be charged. As a practical matter,
if such resales became a problem, the company could institute a quota that would
limit the number of sweatshirts a student could buy. Limiting resale is critical to
price discrimination.
The Bene?ts of Segmenting:
A Graphical Approach
If a firm is able to engage in segmenting, how different
should the prices be across the groups, and how much does
the company stand to gain by price discriminating com-
pared to the standard one-price monopoly strategy?
To answer these questions, let’s consider an example
with two consumer groups, the market for entry into the
prestigious Ironman 70.3 Cozumel Triathlon. This triath-
lon is a race that comprises a 1.2-mile swim, a 56-mile
bike ride, and a 13.1-mile run. It may seem like a mas-
ochistic pursuit, but people pay serious money to enter
this race.
There are two kinds of people who want to enter the
Ironman Cozumel: people who live in and around Cozu-
mel, and people who fly in from somewhere else. The two groups’ demand curves for
entering the race are shown in Figure 10.4. Panel a shows the demand ( D
T
) for the
participants traveling to Cozumel for the competition. The travelers mostly come
from the United States; have high incomes and expensive triathlon equipment; and
will have to pay for a plane ticket, a hotel room, food, and a rental car. They don’t
care if the price of their registration for the race is a bit higher, because it’s a small
share of the total cost to them. In other words, the demand curve for the traveling
participants is fairly inelastic.
Panel b of the figure shows the local group’s demand curve, D
L
. The local residents’
demand is more price-sensitive because they have many other activities they can pursue
if the price of entering the race is too high. Thus, their demand curve is flatter and
more elastic.
Preventing resale won’t be a problem for the firm organizing the race as long as it
can tell which athletes are from out of town and which are not. This is easy because
out-of-town athletes have to pay their entrance fees with some form of identification
H
u
g
o
O
r
t
u
ñ
o
S
u
á
r
e
z
/
D
e
m
o
t
i
x
/
C
o
r
b
i
s
How many of these triathletes had to travel to Cozumel
to compete?
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 404 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 405
that gives their address, and they have to prove who they are when claiming their bib
numbers on race day.
The fundamental economic idea of segmenting is simple. If a firm can directly
identify groups that have different demands and charge different prices to each, it
can essentially treat each group as a separate market. The firm then sets its profit-
maximizing quantity for each one of these “markets” where MR = MC and sets
the corresponding single-price profit-maximizing price according to each market’s
demand curve.
Let’s see how the organizers of the Ironman Cozumel competition follow the seg-
menting strategy. The organizers have identified these two different demand curves
and treat each as a separate market. From the demand curve of out-of-town entrants
(travelers) D
T
, the organizers compute marginal revenue, labeled MR
T
in panel a of
Figure 10.4. Then from the point at which MR
T
equals marginal cost MC, the organiz-
ers determine the optimal quantity of entries to sell to out-of-towners ( Q
T
= 600). At
that quantity, the entry fee is P
T
= $220.
The organizers go through the same process for the local entrants. These entrants’
demand curve D
L
in panel b implies a marginal revenue curve MR
L
. The optimal
number of entries for the organizer to offer to locals is Q
L
= 700, the quantity at
which marginal revenue from locals equals marginal cost. (The marginal cost is the
same for either type of racer. It amounts, basically, to the cost of a bib, some extra
Gatorade, some water, a finisher’s medal, and a race T-shirt.) The price, determined
from the locals’ demand curve, is P
L
= $170, significantly lower than the $220 price
for traveling entrants.
(a) The Ironman 70.3 Cozumel Triathlon segments its par-
ticipants into two groups, traveling and local participants.
Traveling participants are relatively insensitive to price
and have an inelastic demand curve D
T
. The number of
traveling participants will be Q
T
= 600, and each will pay
a registration fee of P
T
= $220/entry. Producer surplus,
P S
T
, will be relatively large.
(b) Local participants have a relatively elastic demand
curve D
L
. A greater number of locals will register for the
triathlon ( Q
L
= 700) at a lower price ( P
L
= $170/entry).
Producer surplus for locals, P S
L
, is relatively small.
Figure 10.4 Segmenting Entry Fees at the Ironman 70.3 Cozumel Triathlon
Quantity
of entries
Price
($/entry)
MC
MR
T
PS
T
D
T
0
Q
T
= 600
P
T
= 220
$340
100
(a) Traveling participants (b) Local participants
Quantity
of entries
Price
($/entry)
MC
MR
L
PS
L
D
L
0
Q
L
= 700
P
L
= 170
$240
100
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 405 11/5/12 4:01 PM
406 Part 3 Markets and Prices
That’s all there is to the strategy. As long as a seller can keep people from sneaking
into the lower-price group or keep those in the lower-price group from reselling to the
higher-price group, it can use segmenting to treat each group like a separate market
and set the monopoly price for each market.
A firm following this pricing strategy will not earn as much producer surplus as one
using perfect price discrimination (which would allow it to take the entire surplus from
the market). However, it will earn more surplus than if it acted like a regular monopoly
and charged the same price to everyone, because the strategy gives the firm some ability
to charge a higher price to consumers with relatively inelastic demand and lower prices
to consumers with relatively elastic demand.
Figure 10.5 shows the total Ironman Cozumel demand and marginal revenue that
would face a monopolist forced to set only a single price. As in Chapter 5, we calculate
the market demand as the horizontal sum of the participants’ demand curves — in this
case, the sum of the traveling and local participants’ demands. This results in a kink
in the market demand curve at $240, the demand choke price for local participants. At
prices above $240, no locals purchase tickets, so the market demand curve is just the
traveling racers’ demand curve.
A single-price monopolist race organizer sets the quantity of entries where its mar-
ginal cost equals marginal revenue, and charges the price corresponding to the total
market demand curve. This quantity, 1,300 racers, is shown in Figure 10.5, and the cor-
responding price is $186.67 per entry. Notice how this price falls between the two prices
($170 and $225) that the organizers charge the segments when price-discriminating. Al-
though it might not be obvious from looking at the figure, the producer surplus for the
single-price monopolist is considerably smaller than the surplus the monopolist would
earn by segmenting the market. (We see that this is indeed the case when we calculate
the benefits from segmenting in the next section.)
The Bene?ts of Segmenting:
A Mathematical Approach
To do the same analysis of segmenting using mathematics, we start with the two distinct
demand curves for the Ironman Cozumel. The demand curve of the traveling partici-
pants is given by Q
T
= 1,700 – 5 P
T
, and the locals’ demand curve is Q
L
= 2,400 – 10 P
L
.
A single-price monopolist faces the kinked demand
curve D, equal to the horizontal sum of the de-
mand curves for travelers and local participants.
The race organizer will sell 1,300 entries at a price
of $186.67, between the two prices ($170 and $225)
charged when the market is segmented. The result-
ing producer surplus, rectangle A, is smaller than
the producer surplus under market segmentation.
Figure 10.5 Single-Price Monopolist at the Ironman 70.3 Cozumel Triathlon
Quantity
of entries
Price
($/entry)
MC
MR
D
A
0
1,300 500
240
$340
100
186.67
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 406 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 407
Note that, in accordance with our story, the locals’ quantity demanded is more sensitive
to price than the travelers’ quantity demanded: A $1 increase in the entry fee reduces
the number of local entrants by 10, while it only decreases the number of traveling en-
trants by 5. We assume the marginal cost to the organizer of adding another triathlete
to the race is a constant $100, no matter how many entrants there are.
The mathematical analysis of segmenting is done using the same steps as in the
graphical analysis above. If the race organizers can identify the separate groups
and prevent resale, they can compute the marginal revenue curves for each segment and
solve for the monopoly prices separately for each group.
We can follow the methods discussed in Chapter 9 to find the marginal revenue
curves from linear demand curves. First, we determine the inverse demand curves by
rearranging the demand function to express price in terms of quantity demanded. Doing
so gives us the following equations:
For travelers:
Q
T
= 1,700 – 5 P
T
5 P
T
= 1,700 – Q
T
P
T
= 340 – 0.2 Q
T
For locals:
Q
L
= 2,400 – 10 P
L
10 P
L
= 2,400 – Q
L
P
L
= 240 – 0.1 Q
L
Next, we know that the marginal revenue curve will look like the inverse demand
curve, but the coefficient on quantity will be twice as large. The marginal revenue
curves for the two segments are
For travelers: For locals:
MR
T
= 340 – 0.4 Q
T
and MR
L
= 240 – 0.2 Q
L
The organizers want to sell the quantities at which marginal cost ($100, the same for
both groups of triathletes) equals its marginal revenue. Setting each marginal revenue equa-
tion above equal to marginal cost tells us the optimal number of entrants from each group:
For travelers:
MR
T
= MC
340 – 0.4 Q
T
= 100
240 = 0.4 Q
T
Q
T
= 600
For locals:
MR
L
= MC
240 – 0.2 Q
L
= 100
140 = 0.2 Q
L
Q
L
= 700
The last step is to find the entry fees that correspond to these quantities by plugging
the quantities back into the inverse demand curve:
For travelers:
P
T
= 340 – 0.2 Q
T
= 340 – 0.2(600)
= 340 – 120
= $220
For locals:
P
L
= 240 – 0.1 Q
L
= 240 – 0.1(700)
= 240 – 70
= $170
Therefore, in a segmentation strategy, the race organizers sell 600 entries to out-of-
towners for $220 each and 700 entries to locals at $170 each.
The total producer surplus the organizers earn is the difference between the price and
the marginal cost for each segment times the number of entries sold to that segment. In
Figure 10.4, those surpluses are rectangles PS
T
for the segment of nonlocal triathletes
and PS
L
for the local triathletes. Using the results we computed above, we have
For travelers:
PS
T
= (220 – 100) × 600
= 120(600)
= $72,000
For locals:
PS
L
= (170 – 100) × 700
= 70(700)
= $49,000
for a combined producer surplus of $121,000 to the race organizer.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 407 11/5/12 4:01 PM
408 Part 3 Markets and Prices
In our graphical analysis, we contended that the price-discriminating monopolist
earns more producer surplus than the single-price monopolist. This makes intuitive
sense, because a firm that segments the market can charge higher prices to more price-
inelastic customers and capture more of their consumer surplus. But how can we show
this algebraically?
First, we can see that the marginal cost curve intersects demand at the part of the
demand curve below the kink — the portion of the demand curve that is the sum of
the local and nonlocal demand:
Q = 1,700 – 5P + 2,400 – 10P = 4,100 – 15P
The inverse demand curve at this intersection is then P =
4,100
____
15
–
Q
__
15
, and the mar-
ginal revenue curve has twice the slope, or MR =
4,100
____
15
–
2Q
___
15
. We set MR equal to the
marginal cost to solve for the optimal number of participants under the single-pricing
strategy:
4,100
_
15
–
2Q
_
15
= 100
4,100 – 2Q = 1,500
Q = 1,300
Note that 1,300 is exactly the sum of the local and traveling participants under the
previous pricing system. Single-price monopolists and those who segment differ in
the prices they set, but not always in the quantity they provide. That doesn’t mean the
firm would be selling to the same group of individuals, however. The new price will
be lower than the segmented price for travelers (inducing more to buy than in the
segmented case) and higher than the segmented price for locals (excluding some locals
from buying). Just what is the price in this instance? Plug the quantity into the inverse
demand curve:
P =
4,100
_
15
–
1,300
_
15
= $186.67
Thus, although locals face a slightly higher price, the travelers get a bargain relative to
the segmented outcome.
To calculate the producer surplus, we find the area of the rectangle A in Figure 10.5:
PS = (186.67 – 100) × 1,300
= 86.67(1,300) = $112,671
If the monopolist organizers segment the market for triathlon entries, they earn
$121,000 in producer surplus; if they must charge a single price, they earn $112,671.
Just by segmenting the market, the monopolist organizers can increase their producer
surplus by $8,329, or about 7%.
How Much Should Each Segment Be Charged?
Because the standard market power pricing rule applies in each segment, it also means
that the Lerner index, the basic markup formula we derived in Chapter 9, applies in
each market. Recall that this formula relates the price elasticity of demand to the
markup of price over marginal cost:
(P– MC)
_
P
= –
1
_
E
D
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 408 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 409
If the firm sells the same good to both segments of the market, the marginal cost
of producing for each segment is the same. In this case, the only reason to charge
different prices to customers in different segments is because they have different
demand elasticities. To see what the Lerner index implies for the ratio of the prices
in the two segments (label them 1 and 2), first solve the Lerner index for price in
each segment:
( P
1
– MC)
_
P
1
= –
1
_
E
1
D
P
1
– MC = –
1
_
E
1
D
× P
1
P
1
+
(
1
_
E
1
D
× P
1
)
= MC
P
1
(
1 +
1
_
E
1
D
)
= MC
P
1
(
E
1
D
_
E
1
D
+
1
_
E
1
D
)
= MC
P
1
=
(
E
1
D
_
1 + E
1
D
)
× MC
Likewise,
P
2
=
(
E
2
D
_
1 + E
2
D
)
× MC
Now, we can compute the ratio of these prices:
P
1
_
P
2
=
[ E
1
D
/(1 + E
1
D
)] × MC
__
[ E
2
D
/(1 + E
2
D
)] × MC
=
[ E
1
D
/(1 + E
1
D
)]
__
[ E
2
D
/(1 + E
2
D
)]
As the demand in Segment 1 becomes less elastic relative to Segment 2 (i.e., E
1
D
becomes smaller than E
2
D
in absolute value), the ratio P
1
/ P
2
will rise. That is, the
greater the difference in price sensitivities between the segments, the greater should be
the ratio in their prices.
Returning to our Ironman Cozumel example, suppose we know that the elasticity
of demand for travelers is –1.83 and the elasticity for locals is –2.43.
2
We can imme-
diately determine what the ratio of prices should be by plugging these elasticities into
the formula:
P
1
_
P
2
=
–1.83
_
–1.83 + 1
_
–2.43
_
–2.43 + 1
=
–1.83
_
–0.83
_
–2.43
_
–1.43
=
2.2
_
1.7
= 1.29
In other words, the race organizer should set the price travelers face to be almost
1.3 times (i.e., 30% higher than) the price for locals. This is in fact the ratio between
the $220 and $170 optimal entry fees we computed earlier.
2
If you remember the calculation of elasticity from Chapter 2, you can verify these values.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 409 11/5/12 4:01 PM
410 Part 3 Markets and Prices
make the grade
We mentioned this before, but it bears repeating: Al-
ways be careful about the distinction between price
discrimination, when firms charge different prices
for the same product, and price differences. It’s often
surprisingly hard to tell them apart. Prices can dif-
fer across different customer groups if a firm with
market power price discriminates, but prices can
also differ across the groups if the marginal cost
of supplying the groups differs, even in a perfectly
competitive market.
For example, a bottle of Coca-Cola, which is basi-
cally just carbonated water plus syrup, is often less
expensive than a bottle of carbonated water alone.
Perhaps this price difference reflects price discrimi-
nation because the kinds of people who buy bot-
tled water are less price-sensitive than the people
who buy soda. But maybe the cost of bottling fancy
carbonated water is greater than the cost of bottling
soft drinks (a lot more people buy soda than carbon-
ated water and there might be some economies of
scale, for example). You can’t tell just from the prices.
The only way to tell the difference between price
discrimination and price differences due to costs in
competitive markets (without actually being able to
observe the firm’s marginal cost) is to find something
that changes the price elasticity of demand without
changing the cost. Price discrimination implies that
a firm with market power sets its price based on the
elasticity of demand and the marginal cost of produc-
ing. Price in a competitive market depends only on
marginal cost. (This is related to the distinction we
discussed in Chapter 9 about how firms with market
power react differently than competitive firms to rota-
tions in demand.)
Is it really price discrimination?
10.2 ?gure it out
You manage a hair salon that has two locations: one
in a large city in Ohio with several competing salons,
and another in a small city in Pennsylvania with less
competition. In Ohio, your customer’s price elasticity
of demand is –3, while for your Pennsylvania custom-
ers it is –2. Assume that the marginal cost of produc-
ing a haircut is $30 regardless of location.
a. What are your salon’s optimal markups and
prices in each location?
b. Why do they differ?
Solution:
a. The Lerner index provides us with a formula
for seeing the relationship between pricing and the
price elasticity of demand:
(P – MC)
_
P
= –
1
_
E
D
Substituting for marginal cost (= $30) and the price
elasticity of demand for Ohio customers (= –3), we get
(P – $30)
_
P
=
1
_
–(–3)
P = 3(P – $30)
2P = $90
P = $45
Repeating the same steps for Pennsylvania gives
(P – $30)
_
P
=
1
_
–(–2)
P = 2(P – $30)
P = $60
Customers in Ohio will be charged a price of $45 per
haircut, while those in Pennsylvania will be charged a
price of $60 per haircut.
b. Because demand is relatively more elastic in
Ohio than in Pennsylvania (the absolute value of the
price elasticity of demand is greater), customers in
Ohio are more price-sensitive. Therefore, they will be
charged a lower price.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 410 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 411
Ways to Directly Segment Customers
There are many ways firms directly identify customer segments for the purposes of
price discrimination. Here are some of the most common ones.
By Customer Characteristics Firms sometimes price according to customer
characteristics such as age (e.g., senior citizen discounts at the movies or child discounts
at a hotel), gender, or whether the customer is a student or local resident. The basic
idea remains to identify the more price-sensitive customers and charge them less. Firms
need to be careful when pricing based on consumer characteristics in certain countries
because in some cases this may be prohibited by laws against discrimination based on
age, gender, race, physical disabilities, and so on.
Segmenting can even be based on the user’s species. Doctors and veterinarians some-
times use the same medicines. Drug makers recognize that Grandma’s willingness to
pay for the arthritis medication Lodine probably well exceeds someone’s willingness
to purchase Lodine for her arthritic dog Rover (and not only because Grandma’s sav-
ings are larger than Rover’s collection of buried rawhides). This difference in willing-
ness to pay probably explains why a congressional investigation found that the price of
Lodine for humans was almost three times higher than for dogs. Indeed, it determined
that manufacturers priced almost every comparable medication significantly higher for
people than for animals.
3
freakonomics
Victoria’s Not-So-Secret Price Discrimination
Sometimes price discrimination can end up being costly not just to consum-
ers, but also to producers. In 1996 Denise Katzman of New York City sued
Victoria’s Secret for gender discrimination and asked for millions of dollars
in damages. In alleging gender discrimination, Katzman didn’t object to the
catalog’s pages of scantily clad women. Rather, she pointed to the promo-
tional coupon on the catalog’s back page.
The problem? While Ms. Katzman’s catalog offered her $10 off an order of $75, an al-
most identical catalog for a male friend offered $25 off the same amount. Was her catalog
out of date? Nope. The folks at Victoria’s Secret were just engaging in a little “naked” price
discrimination.
Although the company kept its reasons for the different promotions a secret, we can
speculate on why it might employ such price discrimination using our economics reason-
ing. We know that price discrimination occurs when a company uses its market power to
charge higher prices to people who are willing to pay more. In this case, Victoria’s Secret
recognized that its practice of sending out catalogs gave it the opportunity to segment its
customers and advertise different prices to different types of customers. Women might be
willing to purchase $75 of fancy underwear for a price of $65, but men are probably not
as willing to shell out that kind of money for underwear for their wives or girlfriends. They
might only pay $50 for the same order. Because most people don’t end up reading through
their friends’ catalogs, this form of price discrimination could easily go undetected.
Ms. Katzman never did collect her millions in damages, however. Neither did fellow
New Yorker Roy Den Hollander who in 2007 brought suit against bars that sponsor Ladies’
Nights, which Hollander termed “invidious.” He lost his suit, and bars everywhere continue
to advertise gender-based price discrimination with weekly Ladies’ Nights.
3
http://lobby.la.psu.edu/010_Insuring_the_Uninsured/Congressional_Statements/House/
H_Thurman_031600.htm
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 411 11/5/12 4:01 PM
412 Part 3 Markets and Prices
Customer characteristics can also apply to firms or other corporate organiza-
tions in business-to-business transactions. Academic journals, for example, know that
individuals are much more price sensitive to subscription prices than libraries, so the
publishers charge significantly more for institutional subscriptions than for individual
ones. Elsevier, for example, one of the largest publishers of academic journals, charges
individuals $112 for a year’s subscription to the International Journal of Industrial
Organization (don’t all rush to order it at once), but the publisher charges libraries
$1,720 for the same subscription.
By Past Purchase Behavior Consumers reveal a lot about their willingness to pay
when they buy other products, and many sellers use that information to segment cus-
tomers. In industries like auto insurance or direct-broadcast satellite TV, where people
don’t like switching companies once they decide on a provider, existing customers tend
to be less price-sensitive than potential new customers. As a result, it is common for
firms in these industries to give special discounts to new customers, such as reduced
premiums during the first policy period or the first three months of a subscription free.
These are ways to price discriminate based on whether the customer has bought the
product before.
For some other products, the price sensitivity of new customers is lower than that of
past purchasers. For example, it is notoriously difficult to convince people to upgrade
their software to a new version. When Microsoft releases a new version of Windows, the
price of upgrading an older version is typically much lower than buying the new ver-
sion outright. With this low price, Microsoft is trying to entice the more price-sensitive
customers to purchase the new version.
By Location Customers living in one area may have a hard time getting to another
to take advantage of a lower price, or they might not even have knowledge of the prices
in other locations. This often allows sellers to charge different prices in different loca-
tions, depending on the price sensitivity of local demand.
Over Time One way to price discriminate in certain markets is to take advantage of
the different kinds of people who buy a product at different times. When a new genera-
tion of computer CPUs first hits the market, for example, the new CPUs usually sell at
a substantial premium, sometimes hundreds of dollars more than the last generation’s
chips. Yet only a few months later, they are available for a fraction of their original price.
Maybe marginal cost fell that much, you say? Perhaps. But how about movies in first-
run theaters that cost $10 but then cost only $4 when the same movie runs at a discount
movie house several weeks later? Or hardcover books that cost $26.95 while their paper-
back versions cost only $10.95, when the actual difference in production cost is only about
a dollar? These are all cases in which the kinds of people who want the latest, greatest,
most current version of a product—PC gamers, big movie fans, and active readers—tend
to be less sensitive to price than the folks who enter the market later.
In other cases, demand can become less price-sensitive (more inelastic) over time, and
price discrimination will lead to price increases over time. Many goods and services that
have initially uncertain quality have this feature. For example, tickets to a new play
or musical that hasn’t been reviewed are often relatively inexpensive. But once local
reviewers have given the play a “thumbs up,” demand can become much more inelastic
and the producers raise the price accordingly.
In either situation, a firm that prices the same good differently in two different time
periods applies the basic segmentation rules and uses the standard monopoly pricing
rule as it applies to the state of demand in each period.
However, there is one complication in pricing across time that is worth keeping in
mind. Technically, pricing across time is only segmenting if the seller directly assigns
customers to a given time period. That is, in segmentation strategies, the seller is effec-
tively saying, “You buyers over here, this is your price. You buyers over there, you have
a different price.” Buyers are stuck paying the price designated for their group (assum-
ing again as we have throughout this chapter that the seller can prevent resale). With
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 412 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 413
time-based segmentation, however, if customers are forward-looking, meaning that they
consider what the seller might do in the future even as they decide whether to buy
today, then the seller is not actually directly segmenting its customers. The seller can-
not prevent its customers from changing groups; the buyers choose when to buy. So, for
example, if buyers believe that the seller is charging a high price today but will reduce
the price in the future, they might consider waiting to purchase, even if they had the
type of relatively inelastic demand that the seller was trying to take advantage of with
the high current price. In cases like this, the seller needs to consider how the different
prices it plans to charge over time will affect the consumer’s decision of when to buy.
For instance, Intel might want to initially price its fast new CPU at an extremely
high level to take advantage of a segment of high-horsepower PC gamers with really
inelastic demand, while making deep discounts thereafter. But if gamers realize Intel is
likely to do this, they might be willing to trade off waiting to purchase the new CPU
in exchange for enjoying the deep discount. This potential response will limit Intel’s
ability to segment the market in the first place. It could lead to Intel having to charge
a lower initial price than it would have otherwise, and perhaps also reduce the discount
applied to that price later.
The more forward-looking consumers are, the more segmenting across time actually
becomes something known as indirect price discrimination, the pricing strategy we
discuss next.
Segmenting by Location in the European Market for Cars
Car manufacturers like Volkswagen and BMW who do a lot of
business in Europe sell the same car in many different coun-
tries. The customers in these countries have very different
incomes and tastes in cars. Because the automakers in this
market likely have some market power, this is an excellent op-
portunity for segmenting if the automakers can prevent their
customers in one country from selling to those in another.
Manufacturers could then segment their customers by country,
selling the same car at different prices in each country using
the price discrimination methods we’ve been discussing. This
practice would allow these manufacturers to earn higher pro?ts
and more producer surplus than they could by selling their cars
at the same price everywhere.
It turns out the auto companies have many options for pre-
venting resale across countries. First, they can print all manuals
and documents only in the country’s language. Swedish drivers
don’t want manuals in Greek, and vice versa. Second, they can
forbid servicing a car in a country other than the one in which
it was purchased. No one wants to get towed to Romania when
their car experiences problems in Spain. Third, they can punish dealers who sell cars to
people from a different country.
Economists Pinelopi Goldberg and Frank Verboven gathered evidence on car prices in
Europe to investigate this issue.
*
They found that the price of the same car could vary sub-
stantially across countries. For example, in 2003, the price of a VW Golf in Germany was
10% higher than in Portugal and almost 25% more expensive than in Greece.
Goldberg and Verboven concluded that some of the price differences across coun-
tries in Europe arose from differences in the taxation of autos, but that much of the price
theory and data
A
P
P
h
o
t
o
/
F
o
c
k
e
S
t
r
a
n
g
m
a
n
n
/
d
a
p
d
A VW Golf bought in Hannover, Germany costs more than
the same car bought in Portugal or Greece.
*
Pinelopi K. Goldberg and Frank Verboven, “Cross-Country Price Dispersion in the Euro Era: A Case Study of the Euro-
pean Car Market,” Economic Policy 19, no. 40 (October 2004): 483 – 521.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 413 11/5/12 4:01 PM
414 Part 3 Markets and Prices
10.4
Indirect/Second-Degree
Price Discrimination
When to Use It Indirect/Second-Degree Price Discrimination
1. The firm has market power and can prevent resale.
2. The firm’s customers have different demand curves.
3. The firm cannot directly identify which customers have which type of demand
before purchase.
We’ve seen how firms with market power can use direct price discrimination to increase
their producer surplus above the amount they could earn by charging only a single price.
The key is to charge higher prices to customers with relatively inelastic demand and
lower prices to those with more elastic demand. However, being able to directly observe
a customer’s demand type before purchase (as required with direct price discrimination)
is often difficult. A firm might know that its customers have different price sensitivities,
but it may not be able to tell to which group any particular customer belongs.
Even without this knowledge, a firm can still earn extra producer surplus through
price discrimination by using a pricing strategy called indirect price discrimination,
also known as second-degree price discrimination. In this pricing strategy, a firm
gives its customers various pricing choices and allows the customers to choose among
them.
There are many different kinds of indirect price discrimination techniques a company
can use. The principle that underlies all of them, however, is the need to set up the
pricing options to convince customers to pick the “right” choice; that is, to purchase
the option meant for their group rather than another option for a different group. For
example, airlines choose ticket rules and prices so that business travelers with inelastic
demand pay more, on average, for their tickets than leisure travelers with relatively
more elastic demand. At the same time, however, the airline wants to keep business
travelers from deciding that tickets meant for them are too expensive and instead buy-
ing up cheaper tickets intended for leisure travelers.
Indirect Price Discrimination through
Quantity Discounts
The most basic type of indirect price discrimination is the quantity discount, a pricing
strategy in which customers who buy larger quantities of a good pay a lower per-unit
price. For quantity discounting to work, customers who purchase larger quantities of a
product need to have relatively more elastic demands than consumers who buy smaller
quantities. If the consumers in the market do not have these elasticity characteristics,
difference was due to basic direct price discrimination by segmenting. The auto firms were
varying their markups depending on the conditions of local demand. The VW Golf pricing
patterns are consistent with the theory that demand in Germany is less elastic than in Por-
tugal or Greece, so VW charged its German customers more.
Goldberg and Verboven had some good news for European consumers (especially those
in high-demand countries), though. They uncovered clear evidence that, as Europe has
become more economically integrated, it has been much more difficult for car sellers to
prevent resale or arbitrage across boundaries and the price differences have narrowed.
indirect price
discrimination
(second-degree price
discrimination)
A pricing strategy in which
customers pick among a
variety of pricing options
offered by the ?rm.
quantity discount
The practice of charging
a lower per-unit price to
customers who buy larger
quantities.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 414 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 415
the firm would be trying to find a way to raise prices on the people who buy greater
quantities, the opposite of a quantity discount.
To illustrate the idea, let’s say there are two types of customers of the online broker-
age house E*TRADE. One type of customer is not very interested in trading stocks.
Because of this, these customers don’t have a big incentive to shop across different
online trading houses in search of lower commission rates (the fees they pay a broker-
age firm to facilitate a trade). Thus, their demands are relatively inelastic with respect
to the commission charged. The demand curve for uninterested traders is D
u
in panel a
of Figure 10.6. The other type of customer is obsessed with trading stocks. Because
these individuals trade many times each day, they are very sensitive to the commis-
sion rate. Thus, their demands are relatively elastic with respect to the commission.
The demand curve for these obsessed traders is shown as D
o
in panel b. The marginal
revenue curves for each group are MR
u
and MR
o
, respectively. The marginal cost is
the same for both groups.
E*TRADE would like to charge higher commissions to the uninterested traders with
an inelastic demand than it charges the obsessed traders with the more elastic demand.
This third-degree price discrimination (segmenting) would bring E*TRADE more pro-
ducer surplus, but the company cannot pursue this strategy because it cannot tell which
type of trader each person is when she signs up for an account. What E*TRADE does
know, however, is what the demand curves of the two groups look like, even if it can’t
identify to which group any given trader belongs. Based on the demand curve D
u
, for
example, E*TRADE would want to set its standard profit-maximizing quantity and price
(commission per trade) for uninterested traders where MR
u
equals MC: For Q
u
trades
per month, E*TRADE would charge uninterested traders $30 per trade. For obsessed
traders, E*TRADE would like to follow the same procedure and charge them a price of
$9 per trade; at that commission, the obsessed traders would make Q
o
trades per month.
(a) The online brokerage company E*TRADE has two
types of customers: uninterested traders and obsessed
traders. Uninterested traders have a relatively inelastic
demand curve D
u
. E*TRADE would like to charge un-
interested traders the profit-maximizing commission rate
P
u
= $30 per trade and sell quantity Q
u
trades per month.
(b) Obsessed traders have a relatively elastic demand curve
D
o
. E*TRADE would like to charge them the lower com-
mission rate P
o
= $9 per trade. Although E*TRADE cannot
directly identify which group any particular trader belongs
to, it can set different prices for the two groups using a
quantity discount by requiring traders to make at least Q
o
trades per month to get a reduced commission rate.
Figure 10.6 Quantity Discounts at E*TRADE
Quantity of trades
(per month)
Price
($/trade)
0
Q
u
P
u
= $30
(a) Uninterested traders (b) Obsessed traders
MC
MR
u
D
u
Quantity of trades
(per month)
Price
($/trade)
0
Q
o
P
o
= $9
MC
MR
o
D
o
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 415 11/5/12 4:01 PM
416 Part 3 Markets and Prices
If E*TRADE could segment the market, it would charge each group P
u
and P
o
per trade, and at those prices, each group would make Q
u
and Q
o
trades per month.
However, E*TRADE can’t directly assign different commission rates to different trad-
ers. And it can’t just offer new customers a choice of whether to pay $30 or $9 com-
missions no matter how much or little they trade because every customer would choose
the cheaper option. What can E*TRADE do to take as much of each trader’s surplus
for itself? Rather than offer all customers a $9 per trade commission, E*TRADE can
tie that commission rate to a requirement that the customer make at least Q
o
trades
per month. For customers who do not want to make at least Q
o
trades per month,
E*TRADE can offer a $30 per trade commission plan that allows them to trade as little
or much as they’d like in one month.
The idea behind this strategy is that an obsessed trader, who demands a high quan-
tity of trades and has a more elastic demand, will choose the $9 plan that requires a
purchase of at least Q
o
trades each month. An uninterested trader, on the other hand,
will choose the $30 per trade plan. In other words, traders from both groups will sort
themselves into the price and quantity combinations designed for them, even though
E*TRADE cannot directly identify either type. This is the essence of any kind of suc-
cessful indirect price discrimination strategy: The firm must set its prices so that a
customer doesn’t try to fake her demand type and buy the package meant for another
customer type. We discuss this requirement for the successful implementation of all
indirect price discrimination (including quantity discounts) next.
Incentive Compatibility The plan to charge uninterested traders a higher com-
mission than obsessed traders is logical, but for such a plan to work well and allow
E*TRADE to reap the maximum producer surplus available to it, E*TRADE needs to
make sure that the uninterested trader won’t want to switch from her $30/ Q
u
package
to the $9/ Q
o
package designed for the obsessed traders. That is, the $9 commission deal
can’t be so good that the uninterested trader will make extra trades just to obtain the
lower price. E*TRADE has to be sure that the uninterested trader’s consumer surplus is
bigger with the $30 per trade package than with the $9 package that requires a purchase
of at least Q
o
trades. The offers need to be internally consistent so that each type of
buyer actually chooses the offer designed for it.
Economists have a term for this type of internal consistency: incentive
compatibility. In this example, the two packages are incentive compatible if:
1. An uninterested trader prefers the $30 package over the $9 package (and she will make
this choice if the $30 package gives her greater consumer surplus than the $9 package).
2. An obsessed trader prefers the $9 package because it offers her more consumer surplus
than the $30 package.
Let’s see whether this set of offers is incentive compatible. First, we need to show that
the uninterested trader’s consumer surplus from trades at $30 each is greater than her
surplus from making Q
o
trades at $9 each. Finding the consumer surplus from the first
offer is familiar territory. As shown in Figure 10.7, at a price of $30 per trade, an unin-
terested trader makes quantity Q
u
trades, and the consumer surplus is the area under the
uninterested trader’s demand curve and above the $30 price. This is triangle A in panel a.
Finding the uninterested trader’s consumer surplus for the $9 package offer is a
bit trickier. The first thing we need to do is put the $9 package’s price and quantity
combination in the diagram showing the demand for trades of an uninterested trader.
Call this point X, as shown in panel a. Notice that point X lies above the uninterested
trader’s demand curve. That means if an uninterested trader were to make trade num-
ber Q
o
(at a commission of $9), she would actually lose consumer surplus by doing so.
At a price of $9, an uninterested trader really only wishes to purchase Q
max
trades, the
quantity demanded at that price.
The fact that Q
max
is less than Q
o
implies that the uninterested trader’s willingness
to pay for the trades between Q
max
and Q
o
is lower than the $9 she would have to pay
incentive
compatibility
The requirement under an
indirect price discrimina-
tion strategy that the price
offered to each consumer
group is chosen by that
group.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 416 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 417
for them. In fact, all trades for which her demand curve (which indicates her willingness
to pay) lies below $9 will result in a loss of consumer surplus. In panel a, these surplus-
destroying trades are those between Q
max
and Q
o
, and the total consumer surplus lost
is the area labeled L. (The demand curve just runs along the horizontal axis once it
hits the axis, because willingness to pay for higher quantities is zero.) That area is the
downside for an uninterested trader accepting the lower-commission offer. There is an
upside, however. The first Q
max
trades she conducts create consumer surplus, area A
+ B in the figure. This consumer surplus is quite a bit larger than her surplus under
the $30 per trade offer (area A) because the price is so much lower. The net consumer
surplus an uninterested trader gets from taking the $9 package offer is therefore area
A + area B – area L.
Comparing the uninterested trader’s consumer surpluses from the two offers, we can
now see that she will choose the $30 per trade offer over the $9 package offer if
area A > area A + area B – area L
0 > area B – area L
area B < area L
That is, an uninterested trader will take the offer designed for her ($30 per trade) if the
extra consumer surplus she would obtain from the lower commission rate (area B) is
smaller than the loss she suffers from having to buy a larger quantity than she would
have otherwise at the lower offered price (area L).
For uninterested traders, we have outlined under what conditions the offers are
incentive compatible. Will an obsessed trader choose the $9 package meant for her?
(a) Before charging a quantity discount to obsessed trad-
ers, E*TRADE needs to ensure that its pricing strategy
is incentive compatible. At P
u
= $30 per trade, uninter-
ested traders make Q
u
trades and receive surplus A. At
the quantity and price offered to obsessed traders ( Q
o
, P
o
),
their surplus is reduced by area L but increases by
area B. Uninterested traders will choose to pay $30 per
trade if area B is greater than area L.
(b) Under the pricing policy for uninterested traders,
obsessed traders would have to pay both a higher price
( P
u
= $30 > P
u
= $9) and make fewer trades per month
( Q
o
> Q
u
). Therefore, the quantity discount is incentive-
compatible for these traders.
Figure 10.7 Incentive Compatibility
Quantity
of trades
(per month)
Price
($/trade)
0
Q
u
Q
max
Q
o
P
u
= $30
P
o
= 9
(a) Uninterested traders (b) Obsessed traders
MC
A
B
L
X
D
u Quantity
of trades
(per month)
Price
($/trade)
0
Q
o
P
o
= $9
MC
D
o
Consumer surplus at P
u
= A
Consumer surplus at P
o
= A + B – L
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 417 11/5/12 4:01 PM
418 Part 3 Markets and Prices
We know that at a commission rate of $9 per trade, an obsessed trader earns con-
sumer surplus on every trade up to Q
o
; she is happy to trade that much at that price.
Taking the $30 offer would require her to make a smaller quantity of trades than Q
o
at a
higher price per unit. Having to consume a smaller quantity even holding the price fixed
at $9 per trade would make an obsessed trader worse off, because it would eliminate
surplus-creating trades she would have made otherwise at that price. Even worse, how-
ever, would be that the trader would have to pay $30 instead of $9 for each of the trades
she did make. Both the quantity restriction and the increase in price reduce the obsessed
trader’s consumer surplus. Thus, the $9 package offer is better for obsessed traders.
We saw that an uninterested trader also faces a higher price and lower quantity if she
takes the $30 per trade offer instead of the $9 package. So, why isn’t an uninterested trader
automatically worse off by taking the $30 offer as is an obsessed trader? The reason is that
if an uninterested trader faced a price of $9 per trade but got to choose how many trades
she made, she would never choose to make Q
o
trades. She would only choose to make Q
max,
the quantity of trades demanded at a price of $9 per trade. Any trades between Q
max
and
Q
o
destroy consumer surplus for an uninterested trader because the price is higher than
her willingness to pay. It is the potential consumer surplus-destroying trades tied to the $9
package that make it likely that an uninterested trader would prefer the $30 offer.
10.3 ?gure it out
Suppose you are a pricing analyst for MegaDat
Corporation, a firm that recently developed a new
software program for data analysis. You have two
types of clients who use your product. Type A’s
inverse demand for your software is P = 120 – 10Q,
where Q represents users and P is in dollars per user.
Type B’s inverse demand is P = 60 – 2Q. Assume
that your firm faces a constant marginal cost of
$20 per user to install and set up this software.
a. If you can tell which type of buyer is buying
the product before a purchase is made, what prices
will you charge each type?
b. Suppose instead that you cannot tell which type
of buyer the client is until after the purchase. Suggest
a possible way to use quantity discounts to have buyers
self-select into the pricing scheme set up for them.
c. Determine whether the pricing scheme you
determined in part (b) is incentive-compatible.
Solution:
a. To maximize profit, set MR = MC for each
type. Therefore, we first need to solve for the mar-
ginal revenue curves for each type. Because we have
linear inverse demand curves, we know that the MR
curves will have the same vertical intercept but twice
the slope. This means that MR = 120 – 20Q for
Type A buyers and MR = 60 – 4Q for Type B
buyers. Now set MR = MC to find the
profit-maximizing quantity for each type:
For Type A:
120 – 20 Q
A
= 20
20 Q
A
= 100
Q
A
= 5
For Type B:
60 – 4 Q
B
= 20
4 Q
B
= 40
Q
B
= 10
At these quantities, the prices will be
For Type A:
P
A
= 120 – 10 Q
A
= 120 – 10(5)
= $70
For Type B:
P
B
= 60 – 2 Q
B
= 60 – 2(10)
= $40
b. The firm could charge $70 per user for a
package where the buyer can purchase any quantity
she wishes and a price of $40 for any buyer willing to
purchase 10 or more units.
c. This plan is incentive-compatible for Type B
users. They are willing to continue to purchase Q = 10
at a price of $40 each.
For a Type A consumer, we need to consider the
amount of consumer surplus she receives under each
scheme. We can do this with the help of a diagram
showing the Type A demand curve and the two
prices, $70 and $40.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 418 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 419
Indirect Price Discrimination through Versioning
Airline tickets are a classic example of what we call versioning—offering a range of
products that are all varieties of the same core product. Airlines have a group of business
travel customers who are not very sensitive to prices and a group of leisure travelers who
are highly sensitive to price. Airlines want to charge different prices to the two passenger
groups, but they can’t tell who is flying on business when a customer buys a ticket. So, the
airlines instead offer different versions of the product (tickets on a given flight) available at
different prices. The cheaper version, with many restrictions, is intended for leisure travel-
ers who buy generally well in advance of the travel date, stay over a Saturday night, and
book a round-trip flight. The more expensive version has fewer restrictions and is intended
D
B
C
A
Quantity of software (users)
Price
($/user)
0
$120
40
20
70
8 5 10
L
At a price of $70, a Type A buyer would choose to
purchase 5 units. Consumer surplus would equal area
A, the area below the demand curve but above price.
If a Type A buyer were to opt to purchase the
other package (10 units at a price of $40 each), her
consumer surplus would be the area above the price
and below demand (areas A + B + C), but she
would also lose consumer surplus because she would
be buying units that she values less than the price of
$40. This would be area L in the diagram.
Thus, opting for the quantity discount would
change the Type A buyer’s consumer surplus by
area B + area C – area L. The $40 10-unit package
would be incentive-compatible only if area L >
area B + area C. Let’s calculate those values:
Area B = base × height
= (5)($70 – $40)
= (5)($30)
= $150
To calculate area C, we need to determine the base
of the triangle. This means that we need to know the
quantity at which the Type A buyer’s willingness to
pay is exactly $40:
P = 120 – 10Q
40 = 120 – 10Q
10Q = 80
Q = 8
Area C =
1
_
2
× base × height
= (0.5)(8 – 5)($70 – $40)
= (0.5)(3)($30)
= $45
Therefore, area B + area C = $150 + $45 = $195.
To calculate area L, we need to be able to deter-
mine the height of the triangle. To do so, we need
the price at which a Type A buyer would be willing
to purchase Q = 10 units:
P = 120 – 10Q
= 120 – 10(10)
= 120 – 100
= $20
Area L =
1
_
2
× base × height
= (0.5)(10 – 8)($40 – $20)
= (0.5)(2)($20)
= $20
So, we know that area B + area C = $150 + $45 =
$195 and area L = $20.
Because area A + area B > area L, the $40
10-unit pricing scheme is not incentive-compatible
for Type A buyers. These buyers will want to receive
the quantity discount and will purchase 10 units at
a price of $40 each. Thus, this pricing scheme would
not be successful at making the buyers self-select into
the pricing scheme established for their types.
versioning
A pricing strategy in which
the ?rm offers different
product options designed
to attract different types of
consumers.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 419 11/5/12 4:01 PM
420 Part 3 Markets and Prices
for business travelers who generally don’t like spending a weekend away from home, often
need to buy their tickets at the last minute, and may choose to purchase a one-way flight
for each segment to provide them with added flexibility. By offering two versions of tickets
for a given flight, the airline attempts to make the two types of customers sort themselves
(and by doing so, the airline captures more producer surplus).
For this scheme to work, the airlines need to make sure the prices of each version are
incentive compatible. If the airline sets the prices for each group based on the markup
formula it would use with direct price discrimination, the restricted-travel version might
be too cheap relative to the ticket with fewer restrictions. In this case, business travelers
might actually bite the bullet and start planning trips earlier or stay at their destination
over the weekend. In some cases, business travelers might try to skirt the rules altogether.
For example, it’s possible to avoid the Saturday stay requirement by buying what is
known as “back-to-back” tickets. For example, a business traveler wishing to fly from
Philadelphia to Orlando and back for a Wednesday meeting might buy one Philadelphia-
Orlando round-trip with a departure on Wednesday morning and a return on Sunday, and
an Orlando-Philadelphia round-trip with a Wednesday evening departure and a Sunday
return. The traveler would only use the first leg of each trip. As you might expect, this
kind of behavior is intensely hated by the airlines, which try to forbid it in every way they
can, but, basically, it’s just the market’s normal response to indirect price discrimination.
Versioning and Price-Cost Margins With versioning, the different versions’
marginal costs do not need to be the same. All that is necessary for versioning to work
is for the markup of price over marginal cost to be bigger for the versions bought by
customers with less elastic demand.
Consider the example of an automaker like Toyota, which sells a lot of midsize sedans.
Some of Toyota’s buyers in this segment will not be very price-sensitive. Maybe they are
status-conscious, or just have a particular taste for cars with many fancy features. Oth-
ers will be more price-sensitive. If Toyota could tell which type of customer was which
when they walked through the door, Toyota could just use direct price discrimination and
charge different prices according to the strategy we discussed in Section 10.3. In reality,
however, it’s not always easy to tell what type of customer comes through the door at
any particular time. So, Toyota uses indirect price discrimination and designs two differ-
ent versions of the car that it can sell at different markups, hoping to induce buyers to
segment themselves based on their sensitivity to price and tastes for features.
For example, Toyota makes the Camry, one of the highest-selling cars in the world. It
sells, nicely equipped, for about $25,000 in the United States. But Toyota also makes the
Lexus ES 350, which is built on the same platform and in the same plant as the Camry. It
is similar in many ways to the Camry but is more luxurious. Think of the ES 350 as being
a Camry but with a sun roof, dual-zone climate control, a GPS navigation system, xenon
headlights, and a premium stereo system. The ES 350 sells for around $38,000.
While a sunroof, xenon headlights, and all those extra options raise Toyota’s marginal
cost of producing an ES 350, it’s unlikely that this increase in marginal cost would amount
to $13,000 per car. Toyota charges more than the cost difference because the different ver-
sions split its customers into groups based
on their price sensitivities. The Lexus group
has less elastic demand, so Toyota’s markup
over marginal cost can be higher, just like
the Saturday-night stay splits an airline’s
customers into leisure and business travelers.
To be incentive compatible, Toyota can’t
make the deal for the cheap version so good
that it convinces the luxury customers to pur-
chase Camrys instead. Quantitatively, think
of it the following way. Suppose there are just
two types of customers whose willingness to
pay for each car is listed in Table 10.1.
Toyota Camry Lexus ES 350
Budget consumer $27,000 $30,000
Luxury consumer $28,000 $42,000
Table 10.1 Consumer Valuations for Camrys
and ES 350s
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 420 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 421
Notice that both consumers believe the Lexus is worth more than the Camry. It’s
not that Toyota has made a version that one group likes and the other doesn’t. The
budget consumers value a Lexus more than a Toyota, but not very much more: $30,000
versus $27,000. The luxury consumers, however, value the ES 350 a lot more than the
Camry: $42,000 versus $28,000.
If Toyota prices the Camry at $25,000 and the Lexus ES 350 at $38,000, the budget
consumers get $2,000 of consumer surplus from buying the Camry and –$8,000 from buy-
ing the Lexus (it costs more than they value it), so they will buy the Camry. The luxury
consumers get $3,000 of surplus from buying the Camry and $4,000 from the Lexus, so
they go with the Lexus. Each group chooses the version designed to take advantage of
the nature of their demand curves. That means these prices are incentive compatible.
What would happen if Toyota priced the Lexus at $40,000 rather than $38,000?
The budget consumers would still buy the Camry. Now, however, the status consumers
would get more consumer surplus from buying the Camry ($3,000) than from buying
the Lexus ($2,000), so they would also decide to buy the Camry. That $2,000 price
increase for the Lexus would cause Toyota to lose $13,000 (losing a sale of a $38,000
Lexus at the old price for a $25,000 Camry instead) for each luxury consumer. (Or
worse: The luxury consumers might go buy another automaker’s luxury car.) By charg-
ing the group with the less elastic demand too high a price, Toyota would not be setting
incentive-compatible prices and its attempt at indirect price discrimination would fail.
One detail that is important to note is that it is not the mere existence of custom-
ers with inelastic demand that allows Toyota (or any other firm) to indirectly price-
discriminate with versioning. What is required is that differences exist in demand
elasticities across customer groups. If different consumer groups had the same price
elasticities of demand, even if relatively inelastic, then designing versions specifically
for each group will not help a firm price discriminate. Automakers offer cars with dif-
ferent paint colors, for example, but there is rarely price discrimination based on paint
color because the price sensitivities of people who like blue cars and silver cars are
no different.
There is virtually no limit to the kinds of versioning a company can implement to
get its customers to self-select into groups based on their price sensitivities. Now that
you understand this kind of price discrimination, you will start to see it everywhere
you look. Some firms offer “enhanced” features, such as the way Intuit does with its
TurboTax software. It has a bare-bones version that is actually free online, versions
with special Q&A features, and a small business application package that includes the
ability to handle more complex structures like partnerships. The marginal cost differ-
ence between editions is trivial, but by offering “bells and whistles” versions, Intuit is
able to get the less price-sensitive business customers to pay more.
Indirect Price Discrimination through Coupons
Coupons are also a form of indirect price discrimination. Retailers would like to charge
shoppers who have less elastic demands more for products while setting a lower price
for consumers who are more sensitive to price. Again, however, they have no way of
directly identifying and separating these different groups when they buy, so they have
to get the groups to do it themselves. Coupons are the device they use to do so.
The key to the way coupons work is that the trouble of using coupons — searching
for the right site or deal online, combing through junk mail, or searching through news-
paper inserts — is more likely to be borne by consumers who have more elastic demand.
Because both the willingness to do the work clipping the coupons and the willingness
to shop around for cheaper groceries are determined by the consumers’ perceived value
of time, coupon clipping and the price elasticity of demand are likely to be correlated.
That way, the people who actually end up getting a price discount from a coupon are
those consumers with more elastic demand — exactly the group to whom the retailers
would like to offer lower prices. The shoppers who are less sensitive to price end up
paying the higher, undiscounted price.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 421 11/5/12 4:01 PM
422 Part 3 Markets and Prices
That’s why coupons usually aren’t right next to (or especially already attached to)
the items to which they apply. If they were, it would be easy for even the shoppers with
less elastic demand to use them, and everyone would receive the discount. The fact that
firms require consumers to expend a little effort to use a coupon is not coincidence; it
is exactly the point. Mail-in rebates work on the same principle: Only those consumers
willing to go through the trouble of filling out the form and sending it in — presumably
the most price-sensitive ones — will receive the discount.
4
10.5 Bundling
When to Use It Bundling
1. A firm has market power and can prevent resale.
2. A firm sells a second product and consumers’ demand for that product is negatively
correlated with their demand for the first product.
Another indirect price discrimination strategy that firms with market power can use
to increase their producer surplus over the standard monopoly pricing surplus is called
bundling. This strategy involves putting together two or more products that a firm
produces and selling them as a single package with its own price.
When you subscribe to cable or satellite television, for example, you are buying a
bundled good. You pay a single monthly fee for service, and the cable or satellite com-
pany delivers a number of networks together. You don’t pick and choose every channel
individually. For your $45 per month, you get, say, 90 channels rather than paying $6
per month for ESPN, $4 a month for MTV, and so on.
Sometimes, things can be bundled just because people really prefer buying things
together. Think about a pair of basketball shoes. Although shoemakers could sell shoes
individually, there really isn’t much demand for single shoes or for mixing a Nike basket-
ball shoe for the left foot with an Under Armour shoe for the right. People want to buy
both shoes together. This sort of bundling, which occurs because the goods are strong
complements to one another (i.e., one good raises the marginal utility of the other), is
not a price discrimination strategy. Nike and Under Armour would bundle their left and
right shoes together even if they operated in a perfectly competitive market.
In this chapter, we’re interested in ways that companies can use bundling as a
way to price discriminate. To explain how bundling can be a strategic pricing deci-
sion, it is vital that we first clear up an extremely common misconception. Bundling
will generally not allow a company with market power in one product to leverage
its market power into a second product. To illustrate what we mean, let’s look at a
specific example.
Take a cable company providing TV channels to your home. To make it easy, let’s
say there are only two cable networks: ESPN and the soap opera network SOAPnet
(ESPN is among the most watched cable networks, and SOAPnet is not). Why would
the cable company force you to buy both as a bundle for some price rather than just
sell them separately?
At first glance, people tend to think it’s a way for the cable company to leverage
market power/high demand for ESPN to force people to pay more for the lesser product
(SOAPnet). But this “forcing it down their throat” argument usually does not make
sense. To see why, suppose there are two customers (Jack and Dakota) in the market.
4
That said, there is occasionally a coupon right next to (or even attached to) an item. In this case, the
point of the coupon is not to price discriminate as much as it is to advertise. It’s essentially a little
sign that says, “Buy me . . . I’m cheaper than usual.”
bundling
A pricing strategy in which
the ?rm sells two or more
products together at a
single price.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 422 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 423
Both like ESPN a lot and SOAPnet less, as reflected in
Table 10.2. Jack values ESPN at $9 per month and Dakota
values it at $10 per month. Jack values SOAPnet at $1 per
month, while Dakota values it at $1.50. For simplicity, let’s
assume the marginal cost of supplying the networks is zero.
Does the cable company raise its producer surplus by
bundling the prized ESPN with SOAPnet? If it sells the
channels separately, it would have to price each channel at
the lower of the two customers’ valuations for each channel
($9.00 for ESPN and $1.00 for SOAPnet). Otherwise, the
company would sell to only the one customer and would
lose the revenue from the other.
5
Thus, it sells ESPN for
$9 per month and SOAPnet for $1 per month, earning a
total surplus of $20 per month (2 × $9) + (2 × $1) from selling the channels separately.
Now suppose the cable company sells the channels as a bundle. The combined value
the customers put on the bundle ($10.00 per month for Jack and $11.50 for Dakota)
means the company will again set the price at the lower valuation so it won’t lose half
of the market. It therefore prices the bundle at $10 and sells it to both customers. This
yields a surplus of (2 × $10), or $20 per month, the same amount it earned selling the
networks separately. Bundling has not raised the firm’s surplus.
Furthermore, if the company combines ESPN with something customers don’t actu-
ally want at all (say, e.g., that the valuation on SOAPnet was zero or even negative),
then the amount that customers would be willing to pay for that network plus ESPN
would be that much lower. As a general matter, then, a company can’t make extra
money by attaching a highly desired product to an undesired one.
How should a firm bundle products to make more producer surplus? Suppose that,
instead of the valuations being what they are in Table 10.2, the two valuations for
SOAPnet are switched. Both customers value ESPN far more, but now Jack has a higher
valuation for SOAPnet ($1.50 per month) than does Dakota ($1.00). The key thing that
has changed, as will become clear in a minute, is that the willingness to pay for the two
goods is now negatively correlated across the consumers. This means that one of the
customers has a higher willingness to pay for one channel than the other customer, but a
lower willingness to pay for the other channel. In our example, Jack has lower willingness
to pay for ESPN than Dakota but greater demand for SOAPnet, as shown in Table 10.3.
With this change, the firm receives more producer surplus using the bundling strategy.
If the cable company sells the channels separately, the calculation is the same as before:
ESPN for $9 per month, SOAPnet for $1, and earns a total of $20 of surplus per month.
If the firm bundles the channels, however, it can sell the package to both customers for
$10.50 per month. This earns the company (2 × $10.50) or
$21 of producer surplus per month, more than the $20 per
month from selling the channels separately.
The reason why bundling works in the second scenario
is the negative correlation between the two customers’ will-
ingness to pay, which occurs because Dakota values one
part of the bundle (ESPN) more than Jack, while Jack
values SOAPnet more than Dakota. If the cable company
wants to sell to the entire market, it can only set a price
equal to the smaller of the two customers’ willingness to
pay, whether pricing separately or as a bundle. In the first
example with positively correlated demand (when Dakota
had a higher willingness to pay for both channels), the
ESPN SOAPnet Bundle
Jack $9.00 $1.50 $10.50
Dakota $10.00 $1.00 $11.00
Table 10.3 Negatively Correlated
Valuations per
Subscriber-Month
5
In reality, most network owners like Disney, which owns ESPN and SOAPnet, do not own the cable
company, so they actually bundle the channels they sell to the cable company that then passes along
that bundle to you. The point is the same, however.
ESPN SOAPnet Bundle
Jack $9.00 $1.00 $10.00
Dakota $10.00 $1.50 $11.50
Table 10.2 Positively Correlated
Valuations per
Subscriber-Month
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 423 11/5/12 4:01 PM
424 Part 3 Markets and Prices
lower of the customers’ valuations for the bundle ($10 per subscriber for Jack) is smaller
by $1.50 than the larger valuation ($11.50 per month for Dakota) because it reflects
Jack’s lower valuations for both channels. Therefore, if the cable company wants to sell
the channels as a bundle, it must offer Dakota a discount that embodies the fact that Jack
has a lower willingness to pay for both channels. As a result, the cable company does no
better than having sold the channels separately.
With a negative correlation of demands across customers, there is less variation (only
$0.50) in each customer’s willingness to pay for the bundle: $10.50 per month for Jack
and $11.00 per month for Dakota. This reduced variation means the cable company
doesn’t need to give as large a discount to Dakota to sell to both customers. Bundling
has reduced the difference in total willingness to pay across the customers. What’s im-
portant is that the smaller of the two combined valuations is larger when the channel
demands are negatively correlated. Jack will pay $10.50 instead of only $10, which al-
lows the company to raise its price. In this way, bundling allows sellers to “smooth out”
variations in customers’ demands, raises the prices sellers can charge for their bundled
products, and increases the amount of surplus they can extract.
Mixed Bundling
The previous example shows why a firm might choose to sell two products as a bundle
instead of separately. Sometimes, however, firms simultaneously offer the products
separately and as a bundle and then let the consumer choose which to buy. This indi-
rect pricing strategy is called mixed bundling. The Extra Value Meals at McDonald’s
include a sandwich, fries, and a drink at one price. McDonald’s also offers these three
things individually. This is where mixed bundling acts as a form of indirect price dis-
crimination because the firm offers different choices and lets customers sort themselves
in ways that increase producer surplus.
Mixed bundling is a lot like the bundling strategy we’ve just discussed (offering only
the bundle is often called pure bundling). It is useful in the same type of situations, but
is better than pure bundling when the marginal cost of producing some of the components
is high enough that it makes sense to let some customers opt out of buying the entire
bundle.
Returning to our cable network example, let’s suppose there are four customers and
that they value the networks according to Table 10.4. The willingness to pay is negatively
correlated across the networks, so we know bundling can work as a pricing strategy.
Now suppose instead of marginal costs being zero, the marginal cost of supplying ESPN
is $6.00 per month and SOAPnet is $1.00 per month. Therefore, the marginal cost of pro-
ducing the bundled package is $7.00. If the cable company sells the bundle for $12.15 (the
minimum valuation of the bundle across
the customers), it will sell the bundle to all
four customers. Subtracting costs, this will
net a per-customer producer surplus of $5.15
per month for a total of (4 × $5.15), or $20.60.
But look more closely at Penny and Shel-
don. Their relative values for the two channels
are extreme. Penny really values ESPN and
barely values SOAPnet, while the opposite
is true for Sheldon. And crucially, the value
they put on one of these channels is below
the marginal cost of supplying it: SOAPnet
for Penny and ESPN for Sheldon. As we will
see, in these cases it makes sense for the cable
company to try to split these customers off
from the bundle, because it does not want to
supply channels to customers who value them
at less than the cost of providing them.
ESPN
(MC = $6)
SOAPnet
(MC = $1)
Bundle
(MC = $7)
Penny $12.00 $0.50 $12.50
Leonard $11.00 $1.15 $12.15
Raj $9.00 $3.15 $12.15
Sheldon $5.00 $7.75 $12.75
Table 10.4 Negatively Correlated Valuations
When the Marginal Cost Exceeds
the Valuation for Some Customers
mixed bundling
A type of bundling in which
the ?rm simultaneously of-
fers consumers the choice
of buying two or more
products separately or as
a bundle.
pure bundling
A type of bundling in which
the ?rm offers the products
only as a bundle.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 424 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 425
Figuring out the right mixed bundling strategy is slightly complicated because of
incentive compatibility, so we’ll take it one step at a time. Given the issues we just dis-
cussed, the cable company would like to end up selling the bundle to Leonard and Raj,
only ESPN to Penny, and only SOAPnet to Sheldon. Because both Leonard and
Raj value the bundle at $12.15 per month, that’s a reasonable starting point for think-
ing about the price of the bundle. If this is the price of the bundle, however, the com-
pany can’t charge Sheldon his full $7.75 valuation for SOAPnet. If it tried to, Sheldon
would choose the bundle instead because it would give him 60 cents more consumer
surplus ($12.75 – $12.15) than if he bought only SOAPnet (consumer surplus of zero if
priced at $7.75). A price of $7.75 for SOAPnet is therefore not incentive compatible. To
set an incentive-compatible price for SOAPnet, the cable company has to leave Sheldon
with at least 60 cents of consumer surplus per month. Thus, the incentive-compatible
price for the purchase of SOAPnet alone would be $7.75 – $0.60, or $7.15 per month.
And because Leonard and Raj value SOAPnet at less than $7.15, both will buy the
bundle rather than take the SOAPnet-only option, so incentive compatibility holds in
the other direction, too.
We can do the same type of calculations with ESPN and Penny. The cable company
can’t charge $12.00 for ESPN alone, because Penny would opt for the bundle to get 35 cents
($12.50 – $12.15) of consumer surplus rather than zero from buying ESPN at $12.00. So, the
company has to leave Penny with at least 35 cents of surplus from buying just ESPN. The
highest price that will achieve this is $12.00 – $0.35, or $11.65. Again, offering this option won’t
move Leonard and Raj away from the bundle, because both value ESPN at less than $11.65.
So with those three prices — ESPN alone for $11.65, SOAPnet alone for $7.15, and
the bundle for $12.15 — the cable company will sell two bundles (to Leonard and Raj)
to earn a producer surplus (subtracting out the marginal costs) of $5.15 per month
for each bundle. Additionally, it will sell ESPN alone to Penny to earn a surplus of
$11.65 – $6.00 = $5.65 and SOAPnet alone to Sheldon for a surplus of $7.15 – $1.00 =
$6.15. The total monthly producer surplus from using mixed bundling is therefore
(2 × $5.15) + $5.65 + $6.15 = $22.10. That is more than the $20.60 per month the
cable company would make by using pure bundling.
Producer surplus has increased because the cable company has saved itself the trou-
ble of delivering a product to a customer who values it at less than it costs to produce.
10.4 ?gure it out
Fit Club, Inc. is a health club that offers two types of equipment: weight machines and a
swimming pool. There are currently three customers (Abe, Betty, and Chris), whose will-
ingness to pay for using each type of equipment per month is listed in the table below:
Willingness to Pay (per month)
WEIGHT MACHINES INDOOR POOL
Abe $60 $50
Betty $50 $125
Chris $25 $140
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 425 11/5/12 4:01 PM
426 Part 3 Markets and Prices
The weight room and the swimming pool each have a constant marginal cost of $20 per
month. In the case of the pool, the marginal cost is the price of the water and chemicals
used, while the marginal cost of the weight machines is the cost of cleaning and maintain-
ing them. Each customer is considering monthly access to each type of equipment, and the
firm has to decide what type of membership package to offer the customers.
a What price will the firm charge for each product if it wishes to sell a health club
membership to all three customers? What is the firm’s producer surplus if it sells separate
access to the weight room and the pool room at these prices?
b. What price will the firm charge for a bundle of access to both the weight room
and the swimming pool if it wishes to sell the bundle to all three customers? How much
producer surplus will Fit Club, Inc. earn in this case?
c. Suppose the firm is considering offering its customers a choice to either purchase
access to the weight room and the swimming pool separately at a price of $60 for the weight
machine and $140 for the pool, or to purchase a bundle at a price of $175. Which option will
each customer choose? How much producer surplus will Fit Club, Inc. earn in this situation?
Solution:
a. To sell access to the weight machines to all three customers, the health club must
charge a price no greater than $25, the lowest willingness to pay of the customers (Chris).
For the same reason, the price for the pool will be $50.
At these prices, the firm’s producer surplus for its sales of access to the weight ma-
chines will be
Producer surplus for weight machine = (Price – marginal cost) × quantity
= ($25 – $20) × 3
= ($5)(3) = $15
For access to the pool, producer surplus will be
Producer surplus for the pool = ($50 – $20) × 3
= ($30)(3) = $90
Total producer surplus will be $15 + $90 = $105.
b. To determine the price of the bundle, we need to calculate each buyer’s willingness
to pay for the bundle. This is done simply by summing the customers’ willingness to pay
for each product as shown in the table below:
Willingness to Pay (per month)
WEIGHT MACHINES INDOOR POOL BUNDLE
Abe $60 $50 = $60 + $50 = $110
Betty $50 $125 = $50 + $125 = $175
Chris $25 $140 = $25 + $140 = $165
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 426 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 427
10.6 Advanced Pricing Strategies
When to Use It Block Pricing and Two-Part Tariffs
1. The firm has market power and can prevent resale.
2. The firm’s customers may have either identical or different demand curves.
In the previous sections, we analyzed pricing strategies based on price discrimination,
the ability of a firm to charge more for units of output sold to those willing to pay more
and, as a result, extract producer surplus by departing from the single-price monopoly
pricing discussed in Chapter 9. In this section, we look at how firms with market power
can achieve that goal not by charging a given price per unit, but by varying unit prices
offered to the same customer or charging lump-sum fees on top of per-unit prices. We
start with a return to our discussion of quantity discounts.
So, the maximum price the health club can charge for its bundle (and still sell to all
three buyers) is $110. It will sell 3 bundles at this price. Therefore, its producer surplus
will be
Producer surplus for bundle = (price – marginal cost) × quantity
= ($110 – $40) × 3
= ($70)(3) = $210
c. We need to compare each buyer’s willingness to pay to the prices set for purchasing
access to each room separately and the price of the bundle.
Abe will only purchase a weight machine membership. His willingness to pay for the
pool is below the price of $140. The same is true for the bundle, which he values only at
$110. Therefore, the health club will only sell Abe access to the weight machines.
Betty will not be willing to buy either membership separately, because her willingness
to pay for each is below the set price. However, Betty’s willingness to pay for the bundle
($175) is exactly equal to the price, so she will purchase the bundle.
Chris will only purchase access to the indoor pool. His willingness to pay for weight
machines is only $25, far below the price of $60. Likewise, Chris is willing to pay at most
$165 for the bundle. Thus, the health club will only be able to sell pool access to Chris.
Total producer surplus will therefore be:
Producer surplus for weight machines = (price – marginal cost) × quantity
= ($60 – $20) × 1
= $40
Producer surplus for the pool = ($140 – $20) × 1
= $120
Producer surplus for bundle = ($175 – $40) × 1
= $135
Total producer surplus when the health club offers customers a choice of bundling or sepa-
rate prices is $40 + $120 + $135 = $295.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 427 11/5/12 4:01 PM
428 Part 3 Markets and Prices
Block Pricing
We call the strategy in which a firm reduces the price of a good if the customer buys
more of it block pricing. You see this sort of thing all the time. Buying a single 12-oz
can of Pepsi might cost $1, but a six-pack of 12-oz cans costs only $2.99. However, un-
like indirect price discrimination (such as quantity discounts), block pricing does not
require that buyers have different demand curves and price sensitivities. All buyers of
Pepsi may, in fact, have the same demand curve, but Pepsi could still gain producer
surplus from providing buyers with an option to buy a larger quantity of soda at a
lower price.
Consider Figure 10.8, which shows a demand curve for Walmart’s photo holiday
cards. Here, we assume this is the demand curve of just one customer (or we could
suppose all customers have this same demand curve), so the firm is not trying to price-
discriminate across customers with different types of demand, as would be the case if
Walmart offers quantity discounts. If Walmart follows the pricing rule for firms with
market power in Chapter 9, it will pick the quantity at which marginal revenue equals
marginal cost and charge a price equal to the height of the demand curve at that quan-
tity. In the figure, the monopoly quantity is 100 cards and the price is 25 cents per card.
Walmart’s producer surplus from pricing at that point equals the area of rectangle A.
If Walmart can prevent resale, however, it doesn’t have to charge a single price.
Suppose it offers the first 100 holiday cards for sale at 25 cents each, but then allows a
consumer to buy as many as 25 more cards (numbers 101–125) at a lower per-unit price
of 20 cents each. The customer will take advantage of this offer because the incremental
purchase at the lower price yields an additional consumer surplus equal to the area of
triangle B. Walmart is better off, too, because it adds an additional amount of producer
surplus equal to the area of rectangle C.
Walmart could keep offering discounted prices on larger quantities. For example, it
could offer the next 50 cards, up to the 175th photo card, for 10 cents each. Again, the
consumer will take the deal because the consumer surplus from that block of cards (area D
in the figure) is positive. Walmart also comes out ahead because it earns producer sur-
plus E. Note that the price strategy we just described could also be expressed in the
following way: 100 units are $25, 125 units are $30, and 175 units are $35. Even if all
customers have this same demand, all will opt to purchase 175 cards at a price of $35
and Walmart still increases its producer surplus. (This is why block pricing is different
D is the demand curve of an individual consumer
of Walmart’s photo cards. Under monopoly pricing,
Walmart sells at the point on the demand curve
corresponding to the quantity where MR = MC
(Q = 100 photo cards, P = $0.25 per card). When
Walmart can prevent resale, it can use a block pric-
ing strategy instead. It could still sell the first 100
at a price of $0.25 per card, while charging a lower
price of $0.20 each for the next 25 photos purchased
(for a total quantity of 125 cards) and $0.10 each
for the next 50 cards (for a total of 175 cards).
Producer surplus increases from area A to A + C
to A + C + E, respectively, and consumer surplus
increases by area B and areas B + D, respectively.
Figure 10.8 Block Pricing
Quantity of
photo cards
Price
($/photo card)
MC
D
A
B
C
D
E
0
175 125 100
0.20
$0.25
0.05
0.10
MR
block pricing
The practice of reducing
the price of a good when
the customer buys more
of it.
? The online appendix ?nds
pro?t-maximizing block prices.
(http://glsmicro.com/appendices)
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 428 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 429
from the quantity discounts we saw when discussing indirect price discrimination. Here,
no customer sorting needs to occur for Walmart to gain producer surplus.)
A block-pricing strategy like this raises more producer surplus for a firm than does
the conventional single-price monopoly strategy because it allows a firm to better match
the prices of different quantities of its output to consumers’ valuations of those quanti-
ties. For the first set of units that customers buy — the units for which customers have
a high willingness to pay — the firm charges a relatively high price. With block pricing,
the firm doesn’t have to completely give up selling a large number of units by charging
that initial high price. Block pricing lets it sell additional units of its product, those for
which consumers have lower willingness to pay, at lower prices.
This example shows how block pricing can work for even a single customer type,
though if there were lots of identical customers, the firm would need to be able to pre-
vent resale to avoid being undercut by its own customers.
Two-Part Tarifs
Another pricing strategy available to firms with market power and identical consumers is
the two-part tariff, a pricing strategy in which a firm breaks the payments for a product
into two parts. One component is a standard per-unit price. The second is a fixed fee that
must be paid to buy any amount of the product at all, no matter how large or how small.
For example, a lot of mobile phone “unlimited service” calling plans have this struc-
ture. You might pay, say, $50 a month for service and then be able to make as many
calls as you would like at no additional cost. Here, the fixed fee portion of the two-part
tariff is $50 and the per-unit price is zero (though for other markets and products, the
per-unit price is often positive). A video game system such as Microsoft’s XBox is like
a two-part tariff, too. Here, the cost of the console itself is the fixed fee and the cost of
the individual games represents the per-unit price.
To see why using a two-part tariff can be advantageous for a firm with market
power, consider the market in Figure 10.9. It shows the demand for mobile phone ser-
vice offered by the firm, the marginal revenue curve corresponding to demand, and the
firm’s constant marginal cost.
The firm’s conventional single-price monopoly profit-maximizing quantity is found
where marginal revenue equals marginal cost. The quantity at which this condition
holds is 300 minutes per month, and the price at which consumers are willing to
As a single-price monopoly, a mobile phone service
will sell 300 minutes of mobile service per month at
a price of $0.10 per minute. Using a two-part tariff,
however, the firm can increase its producer surplus
from rectangle B to the triangle A + B + C. To
do this, it will charge the per-unit price of $0.05 per
minute, where D = MC, and set a fixed fee equal
to the consumer’s surplus at this quantity, the area
A + B + C. Under this pricing scheme, the firm
will sell 600 minutes of mobile service per month.
Figure 10.9 Two-Part Tarif
Quantity of mobile service
(minutes per month)
Price
($/minute)
MC
D
A
B
C
0
600 300
$0.10
0.05
MR
two-part tariff
A pricing strategy in which
the payment has two com-
ponents, a per-unit price
and a ?xed fee.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 429 11/5/12 4:01 PM
430 Part 3 Markets and Prices
purchase that quantity is 10 cents per minute. At the price of 10 cents per minute, the
consumer surplus is area A and the firm’s producer surplus is rectangle B.
Now suppose instead that the firm uses the following two-part tariff pricing structure.
First, it reduces the per-unit price all the way to marginal cost, 5 cents. This change
increases the number of units it sells from 300 minutes to 600, but drives per-unit profit
to zero. However, the firm knows that each customer will buy a quantity of 600 minutes
per month of air time at this price and have a consumer surplus equal to area A + B +
C as a result. Knowing that this consumer surplus represents the willingness of the con-
sumers to pay above the market price, the firm will set a fixed fee to try to capture that
consumer surplus. Therefore, the firm decides to set the fixed-fee portion of the two-part
tariff equal to A + B + C. This fee is not per minute; it’s a one time per month fee for
any consumer who wants to buy any number of units at 5 cents per minute.
What happens under this two-part tariff pricing structure? At a unit price of
5 cents per minute, the consumer buys 600 minutes of air time. This part of the price
structure doesn’t make the phone company any money, because its marginal cost of
delivering service is also 5 cents per minute. However, the company is also charging the
fixed fee A + B + C. And importantly, the consumer is willing to pay that, because
if she uses 600 minutes of air time, she will enjoy consumer surplus equal to the same
area. The company has set the size of the fixed fee so that the consumer is no worse off
(and actually it could make her strictly better off if it charged just a touch less than
A + B + C) than if she bought nothing. By using a two-part tariff, the firm captures
the entire surplus in the market for itself, as opposed to only area B under standard
market power pricing.
Again, if you spread this insight to a market with many identical customers, the abil-
ity to prevent resale would be crucial for making the pricing strategy work. If the phone
company couldn’t prevent resale, one customer could pay the fixed fee, buy up a huge
amount of minutes at marginal cost, sell off these extra minutes at a small markup to
other consumers who did not pay the fixed fee, and make lots of money. For example,
if the consumer could rig her phone so other people would pay her 6 cents per minute
to make calls on it when she wasn’t using the phone, this would defeat the company’s
strategy.
10.5 ?gure it out
You have been hired as an intern at the Golden
Eagle Country Club Golf Course. You have been as-
signed the task of creating the pricing scheme for the
golf course, which typically charges an annual mem-
bership fee and a per-use cost to its customers. Each
of your customers is estimated to have the following
demand curve for rounds of golf per year:
Q = 300 – 5P
If Golden Eagle can provide rounds of golf at a con-
stant marginal cost of $50 and charges that amount per
round of golf, what is the most that members would be
willing to pay for the annual membership fee?
Solution:
This pricing scheme, with an annual membership
fee and a per-unit price, is a two-part tariff. If the
price per round of golf is set at P = $50, then each
member will want to play
Q = 300 – 5P
= 300 – 5(50)
= 300 – 250
= 50 rounds per year
With this knowledge, we can determine the maxi-
mum annual membership fee each customer is willing
to pay. This will be equal to the amount of consumer
surplus the customer will get from playing 50 rounds
of golf each year at a price of $50 per round.
To calculate consumer surplus, it is easiest to
draw a diagram, plot the demand curve, and find
the area of consumer surplus. To simplify matters,
let’s rearrange the demand function into an inverse
demand function:
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 430 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 431
Being able to capture the entire surplus in the market is great if you’re running a
firm, but it’s important to realize that a firm can attain this extreme result only if
its customers have the same demand curve. The problem is much more complicated
when there are customers with different demand curves.
For this more advanced two-part tariff pricing case, think about a firm that faces
two kinds of customers whose demand curves for the firm’s product are shown in
Figure 10.10. Panel a shows the demand curve of the firm’s relatively low-demand
(a) For low-demand customers, the firm would want
to sell a quantity of Q
cL
, charge a per-unit price of P
cL
and a fixed fee equal to the consumer surplus A + B + C.
Since this is much lower than the consumer surplus for
high-demand customers (D + E + F in panel b), such
a pricing strategy will leave a lot of surplus to the high-
demand customers in the market.
(b) For high-demand customers, the firm would want to
sell a quantity of Q
cH
, and charge a per-unit price of P
cH
and a fixed fee equal to D + E + F. Since this fixed fee
is higher than the consumer surplus for low-demand
customers, low-demand customers won’t buy anything.
Figure 10.10 Two-Part Tarif with Diferent Customer Demands
Quantity
Price
($/unit)
MC
A
B
C
D
E
F
MR
L
D
L
Q
mL
Q
cL
P
mL
P
cL
(a) Low-demand customer (b) High-demand customer
Quantity
Price
($/unit)
MC
MR
H
D
H
Q
mH
Q
cH
P
mH
P
cH
Q = 300 – 5P
5P = 300 – Q
P = 60 – 0.2Q
Rounds of golf
(per year)
Price
($/round)
MC
0
D
A
$60
P = 50
50
The vertical intercept is 60 and the consumer sur-
plus is the area below the demand curve and above
the price of $50, area A. We can calculate the area
of triangle A:
Area of A =
1
_
2
× base × height
=
1
_
2
× 50 × ($60 – $50) = 0.5(50)($10)
= $250
If the golf course set the price of a round of golf at
$50, the consumer would purchase 50 rounds per
year. This gives the golfer a consumer surplus equal
to $250. Therefore, customers would be willing to
pay up to $250 for an annual membership.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 431 11/5/12 4:01 PM
432 Part 3 Markets and Prices
customers, while panel b shows the demand of the firm’s relatively high-demand cus-
tomers. If the firm tries to use a two-part tariff where it sets the unit price at marginal
cost MC and the fixed fee at A + B + C, it will capture all of the surplus from the
relatively low-demand customers in panel a but leave a lot of surplus to the relatively
high-demand customers in panel b, because area A + B + C is much smaller than area
D + E + F. If the firm instead sets the fee at D + E + F to capture the surplus of
the high-demand customers, low-demand customers won’t buy at all. This is not neces-
sarily better than the first strategy. If the firm has a lot of low-demand customers, this
could be a big loss for the firm, even if the reduction in profit from losing any given
low-demand customer might be small. So, neither approach is perfect. Computing the
profit-maximizing two-part tariff when consumers have different demands is a math-
ematical challenge beyond the scope of this book, but it usually entails a unit price
above the firm’s marginal cost.
10.7 Conclusion
We explored a number of different ways in which firms with market power, under
the right conditions, can increase the producer surplus they earn above and beyond
the surplus they can earn by following the standard, one-price market power pricing
rule we focused on in Chapter 9. These pricing strategies are all around us; after
learning about them in this chapter, you will start to recognize them in practice.
You may also find yourself wondering why a particular firm isn’t using one of these
strategies. Just remember that certain conditions must be met for the price discrimi-
nation to work.
These various pricing strategies work in different ways, but there are some common
threads. First, none will work unless the firm has market power. Therefore, any firm
operating in a perfectly competitive market cannot use these strategies because it is a
price taker. Second, the firm must prevent resale. Without the ability to prevent resale,
doing anything besides the single-price monopoly pricing in Chapter 9 is futile. Third,
while price discrimination strategies differ in the specifics of their mechanisms and the
types of markets in which they are applicable, all of these methods work on the basic
principle that the firm can make more producer surplus if it can adjust the price it
charges so that consumers end up paying higher prices for those units of its output that
provide them with greater consumer surplus. Price discrimination also works by charg-
ing higher prices to consumers with less elastic demand and lower prices to consumers
with more elastic demand.
Other pricing strategies, such as block pricing and two-part tariffs, can be used even
in markets where all consumers have the same demand. These strategies work by allow-
ing consumers to buy relatively large quantities at a low price on the margin, but then
grab back producer surplus for the firm through higher up-front payments.
In the next chapter, we examine firms with degrees of market power that fall be-
tween perfect competition and monopoly. We will find that these firms’ decisions are
not made in a vacuum (where they only consider their own costs and their customers’
demands), but are also based on the decisions made by other firms in the same market.
Although many may choose to follow the pricing strategies discussed in this chapter,
each firm has to take into account how its competitors may react to such a move before
determining if the strategy increases its producer surplus.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 432 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 433
1. By using pricing strategies, a firm with market
power can extract more producer surplus from a
market than it can from following the monopoly
pricing rule of Chapter 9 (where the firm produces
the quantity at which marginal revenue equals
marginal cost, and then charges the price at which
buyers would consume that quantity). It can only
do so, however, if the situation satisfies certain
criteria. A crucial factor is that in addition to mar-
ket power, the firm has to be able to prevent resale
among customers. If the firm can prevent resale, the
amount of information it has on its customers de-
termines what kind of pricing strategy it can fol-
low. [Section 10.1]
2. When customers differ and the firm has suffi-
cient information about its customers’ demands
to charge every person a different price, perfect
or first-degree price discrimination is possi-
ble. This direct price discrimination strategy
allows the firm to capture the entire surplus in
the market for itself. It is very rare to have this
kind of information, however. [Section 10.2]
3. If the firm has different types of customers and
can directly identify at least two groups whose
price elasticities of demand differ, it can charge
different prices to the two groups and earn more
producer surplus. The profit-maximizing direct
price discrimination strategy in this case is to
follow the single-price monopoly pricing rule sep-
arately for each group. There are many ways to
directly separate customers, including customer
characteristics, geography, past purchase be-
havior, the timing of the purchase, and so on, a
practice known as segmenting, or third-degree
price discrimination. [Section 10.3]
4. If the company knows that there are different
types of customers but cannot directly identify
which group a customer belongs to before the
purchase, it must rely on indirect (second-
degree) price discrimination. This involves
designing choices that induce customers to sort
themselves into groups. Quantity discounts
can be used if customers who demand a high-
er quantity also have a more elastic demand.
Versioning a product can also work. The key
additional requirement for indirect price dis-
crimination is that the pricing structure has to
be incentive compatible, meaning that each
consumer group wants to take the offer designed
specifically for them. [Section 10.4]
5. If a company sells multiple products and con-
sumers’ demands for the products are negatively
correlated, it can sell the products together as
a bundle and increase producer surplus beyond
what it could earn by selling the products sepa-
rately. Sometimes, particularly if the marginal
cost of producing one of the products exceeds
the value that a customer places on that prod-
uct, the company may be better off using mixed
bundling, which gives customers the choice of
buying individual products at high prices or a
bundle of products at a discount. [Section 10.5]
6. Even when there are not different types of cus-
tomers, a firm can use advanced pricing strate-
gies like block pricing (a discount for buying
extra quantity) or a two-part tariff (a fixed fee
paid up-front in addition to a price per unit of the
good) as a way to capture more producer surplus
than it could earn with standard monopoly pric-
ing. However, each of these strategies is much
more complicated to implement when there are
many consumers with different demand curves.
[Section 10.6]
Summary
Review Questions
1. What are the two requirements of price dis-
crimination?
2. Why is producer surplus maximized under per-
fect price discrimination?
3. What are the two types of direct price dis-
crimination?
4. What are some ways that a firm can segment its
customers?
5. Contrast direct price discrimination and indirect
price discrimination.
6. What is incentive compatibility? Why is it
necessary for an indirect price discrimination
strategy to be incentive compatible?
7. Provide an example of product versioning.
8. What are the differences between the following
three pricing strategies: block pricing, segment-
ing, and quantity discounts?
9. What is the difference between mixed bundling
and pure bundling?
10. What are the two component prices of a two-
part tariff?
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 433 11/5/12 4:01 PM
434 Part 3 Markets and Prices
*1. Consider the demand for schnitzel in the diagram
below. Suppose that there is a single seller of
schnitzel, who acts as a single-price monopolist.
Quantity of
schnitzels
Price
($/schnitzel)
MC
MR D
D
E
F
G
H
I
C
A
B
P
2
P
1
Q
2
Q
1
P
3
a. Indicate the profit-maximizing price and
quantity.
b. List the areas of consumer and producer surplus.
c. Suppose the seller begins perfectly price dis-
criminating. How many schnitzels will she sell?
d. What happens to areas A and B when the
seller begins perfectly price discriminating?
e. What happens to areas E and H when the
seller begins perfectly price discriminating?
2. Indicate whether the following statement is true
or false, and explain your answer: Because the
potential profit from perfect price discrimina-
tion is always higher than the potential profit
from third-degree price discrimination (seg-
menting), firms that practice third-degree price
discrimination must not be maximizing profit.
3. There are seven consumers, each of whom is
hungry for exactly one Butterfinger. The con-
sumers’ maximum willingness to pay is given in
the table below:
Consumer
(age, gender)
Maximum
Willingness
to Pay
Marge (34, female) $2
Homer (38, male) 4
Lisa (6, female) 5
Maggie (2, female) 6
Ned (46, male) 1
Krusty (55, male) 3
Bart (9, male) 7
a. Given that each consumer wants one and
only one Butterfinger, draw the demand
curve for Butterfingers.
b. If Butterfingers are priced at $7, only one
will be sold. Who buys that Butterfinger?
Label the point at $7 on the demand curve
with the name of that buyer.
c. If Butterfingers are priced at $6, a second
buyer will be priced into the market. Who
is that buyer? Label the point at $6 on the
demand curve with the name of that buyer.
d. Continue to label each point on the demand
curve with the name of the buyer represented
by that point.
e. Suppose that you are a monopoly seller of But-
terfingers, which you can produce at a con-
stant marginal and average total cost of $2.
Suppose you charge every customer the same
price for Butterfingers. What price should you
set to maximize your profit? How many But-
terfingers will you sell? Calculate your profit.
Calculate the consumer surplus received by
the buyers. Calculate the deadweight loss.
f. Suppose that every customer that comes into
your Butterfinger store has their maximum
willingness to pay displayed in neon on their
foreheads. You decide to use this information
to increase your profit by practicing first-
degree price discrimination. How many But-
terfingers will you sell? Calculate your profit.
Calculate the consumer surplus received by
the buyers. Calculate the deadweight loss.
g. Where does the consumer surplus go when
you begin price discriminating?
h. What happens to the deadweight loss?
4. Consider the problem faced by the Butterfinger
seller in Problem 3.
a. Assume that the seller is able to prevent re-
sale between customers. In the real world,
why is the seller still unlikely to be able to
perfectly price discriminate?
b. Because of the reason you just indicated, the
Butterfinger seller decides to segment her
customers into two groups, each of which will
be charged a different price. In order to max-
imize profit, should the seller sort by gender
or by age?
c. Based on your answer to (b), determine who
is in each group, and indicate (1) the price the
seller should set for each group, (2) the total
profit received by the seller, (3) total consum-
er surplus, and (4) the deadweight loss.
Problems (Solutions to problems marked * appear at the back of this book. Problems adapted to use calculus are available online at http://worthpublishers.com/GLS1e)
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 434 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 435
d. Is this pricing strategy (segmenting) more
profitable to the seller than perfectly price
discriminating? Is this pricing strategy more
profitable than charging every consumer the
same price?
e. What happens to consumer surplus and
deadweight loss when a single-price monopo-
list begins segmenting in this way?
*5. Promoters of a major college basketball tourna-
ment estimate that the demand for tickets on the
part of adults is given by Q
ad
= 5,000 – 10P, and
that the demand for tickets on the part of stu-
dents is given by Q
st
= 10,000 – 100P. The pro-
moters wish to segment the market and charge
adults and students different prices. They esti-
mate that the marginal and average total cost of
seating an additional spectator is constant at $10.
a. For each segment (adults and students), find
the inverse demand and marginal revenue
functions.
b. Equate marginal revenue and marginal cost.
Determine the profit-maximizing quantity
for each segment.
c. Plug the quantities you found in (b) into the
respective inverse demand curves to find
the profit-maximizing price for each segment.
Who pays more, adults or students?
d. Determine the profit generated by each seg-
ment, and add them together to find the pro-
moter’s total profit.
e. How would your answers change if the arena
where the event was to take place had only
5,000 seats?
6. In Problem 5, you found the profit that a pro-
moter of a major college basketball tournament
would earn if he were to segment the market
into adults and students. Suppose that the pro-
moter’s CEO decides that price discrimination
presents a poor public image, and announces
that everybody will be charged the same price.
His resident economist (you) is tasked with fig-
uring out what that price should be.
a. Find the total demand for tickets by adding
the demand curves of adults and students.
b. Derive the inverse demand curve for tickets,
as well as the associated marginal revenue
curve associated with that demand.
c. Find the profit-maximizing quantity of tick-
ets and the corresponding price.
d. Determine the promoter’s profit.
e. Compare the promoter’s profit when he tries
to price for the entire market, to his profit
when he simply charges the adult price from
the previous problem. Is it better for the
promoter to price for the entire market and
almost fill the arena, or to price for adults
only and have a lot of empty seats?
7. You are the owner of a nail salon. Your female
customer’s price elasticity of demand for mani-
cures is –2.5; your male customer’s price elastici-
ty of demand for manicures is –1.2. The marginal
cost of manicuring a customer’s nails is $12.
a. If you segment the market by gender, what
price should you charge women? What price
should you charge men?
b. Explain intuitively why you should charge
each group a different price.
8. Movie theaters often charge substantially less
for afternoon showings than for evening show-
ings. Explain how theaters use time of day to
segment their customers into low-elasticity and
high-elasticity groups.
*9. Owners of a movie theater have determined that
the elasticity of demand for movie tickets equals
–2.0 for students and –1.5 for adults.
a. If the owners of the theater decide to segment
the market, who should be charged a higher
price, students or adults? Use your knowledge
of microeconomic theory to explain why.
b. Use the Lerner index as described in the text
to determine the ratio of prices. In percent-
age terms, how big a price premium should be
charged to the group that pays the higher price?
10. Owners of a Florida restaurant estimate that
the elasticity of demand for meals is –1.5 for
senior citizens and –1.33 for everyone else.
a. Given this information, how big (in percentage
terms) should the senior citizen discount be?
b. Suppose that the restaurant owners discover
that seniors tend to demand more attention
from their waiters and send back more food
as unsatisfactory, to the extent that the mar-
ginal cost of serving a senior is twice as high as
serving an adult. Accounting for these costs,
how large should the senior citizen discount
be? (Hint: Refer back to the example in the
text, but don’t cancel out marginal costs!)
c. Were your results in part (b) surprising? Ex-
plain them, intuitively.
11. A local golf course’s hired-gun econometrician
has determined that there are two types of golf-
ers, frequent and infrequent. Frequent golfers’
annual demand for rounds of golf is given by
Q
f
= 24 – 0.3P, where P is the price of a round
of golf. In contrast, infrequent golfers’ annual
demand for rounds of golf is given by Q
i
=
10 – 0.1P. The marginal and average total cost
of providing a round of golf is $20.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 435 11/5/12 4:01 PM
436 Part 3 Markets and Prices
a. If the golf course could tell a frequent golfer
from an infrequent golfer, what price would it
charge each type? How many times would each
type golf? How much profit would the golf
course generate?
The greens manager has difficulty telling fre-
quent from infrequent golfers, so she decides to
use second-degree price discrimination (quantity
discounts) to make different types of golfers self-
select into the most profitable pricing scheme.
The course sets a price for individual rounds
of golf, but also offers a quantity discount for
members willing to buy a rather large quantity
of rounds in advance. The course’s owners hope
that frequent golfers will self-select into the dis-
counted plan, and that infrequent golfers will
choose to buy individual rounds.
b. What price should the golf course set for in-
dividual rounds of golf? Why?
c. If the course wishes to maximize profit, what
price and minimum quantity should it estab-
lish for the discounted plan?
d. Which plan will generate the greatest con-
sumer surplus for frequent golfers, the
individual-round plan or the discount plan?
Illustrate your answer by showing and mea-
suring the areas of surplus on frequent golf-
ers’ inverse demand curves.
e. Which plan will generate the greatest consumer
surplus for infrequent golfers, the individual-
round plan or the discount plan? Illustrate your
answer by showing the areas of surplus on in-
frequent golfers’ inverse demand curves.
f. Based on your answers to (d) and (e), will
the plan be successful in making golfers
self-select into the most profitable plan for
the golf course?
g. Suppose that each type of golfer came to the
course with the word “frequent” or “infre-
quent” tattooed on his or her forehead. Is
this information of any value to the golf
course owner? (In other words, can the owner
earn any more profits by segmenting than it
did with its quantity discount plan?)
12. Many textbooks are now available in two ver-
sions, a high-priced “domestic” version and a
low-priced “international” version. Each version
generally contains exactly the same text, but
slightly altered homework problems.
a. Why would a textbook publisher go to the
trouble to produce two versions of the same
text?
b. Discuss whether the publisher’s strategy
would be more effective if it made the altera-
tions secret, or if it announced them boldly.
c. The production of international versions of
textbooks was concurrent with the explosion
of the Internet. Explain why this is likely to
be more than just a coincidence.
13. Rockway & Daughters Piano Co. wishes to sell
a piano to everyone. But some consumers are
budget-conscious, and others are not, and unfor-
tunately, Rockway cannot tell which is which.
So, Rockway produces a premium line of pianos
that it markets under the Rockway name, and
a similar line of pianos that it markets under
the Dundee name. While the cost of producing
these pianos is quite similar, all consumers agree
that Rockway pianos are of higher quality than
Dundee pianos, and would be willing to pay
more for a Rockway. Budget-conscious consum-
ers feel that Dundee pianos are worth $6,000,
and Rockways are worth $8,000. Performance
artists believe that Dundee pianos are worth
$7,000 and Rockways are worth $12,000.
a. Suppose Rockway & Daughters prices its
Dundee pianos at $5,000 and its Rockway
pianos at $10,500. Are these prices incentive
compatible— that is, will more price-conscious
consumers purchase the Dundee line, while
more performance-oriented players choose
the Rockway? Explain.
b. How much must Rockway & Daughters re-
duce the price of its Rockway line in order to
achieve incentive compatibility?
c. Suppose instead that Rockway & Daughters
tries to achieve incentive compatibility by
raising the price of its Dundee line. Can it do
so? And if so, how?
14. London’s Market Bar has a unique pricing system
where a computer sets the price based on demand.
When demand picks up, the computer begins to
gradually reduce prices. This pricing strategy is
puzzling to those who have studied supply and
demand. Celene Berman, the assistant manager,
says a group of “young city-boy types” recently
kept asking why prices “were going the wrong
way around.” Explain, using your knowledge of
block pricing, why the owner’s strategy of reduc-
ing prices as sales increase might actually lead to
increased profit for the bar.
15. Microsoft sells two types of office software, a
word processor it calls Word, and a spreadsheet
it calls Excel. Both can be produced at zero
marginal cost. There are two types of consumers
for these products, who exist in roughly equal
proportions in the population: authors, who are
willing to pay $120 for Word and $40 for Excel,
and economists, who are willing to pay $50 for
Word and $150 for Excel.
*
*
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 436 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 437
a. Ideally, Microsoft would like to charge au-
thors more for Word and economists more
for Excel. Why would it be difficult for Mi-
crosoft to do this?
b. Suppose that Microsoft execs decide to sell
Word and Excel separately. What price should
Microsoft set for Word? (Hint: Is it better to
sell only to authors, or to try to sell to both
authors and economists?) What price should
Microsoft set for Excel? What will Microsoft’s
profit be from a representative group of one
author and one economist?
c. Suppose that Microsoft decides to bun-
dle together Word and Excel in a package
called Office, and not offer them individu-
ally. What price should Microsoft set for the
package? Why? How much profit will Micro-
soft generate from a representative group of
one author and one economist?
d. Does bundling allow Microsoft to generate
higher profit than selling Word and Excel
separately?
16. Three consumers, John, Kate, and Lester, are in
the market for two goods, dates and eggs. Their
willingness to pay for dates and eggs is given in
the table below:
Dates
(1 package)
Eggs
(1 dozen)
John $0.60 $2.00
Kate $1.30 $1.30
Lester $2.00 $0.60
a. If you are a local farmer who can produce
dates and eggs for free, what is the optimal
price for dates and eggs if you price them indi-
vidually? How much profit will you generate?
b. If you bundle dates and eggs together, what
price should you set for a bundle containing
one package of dates and a dozen eggs? How
much profit will you generate?
c. Is there any advantage to mixed bundling in
this case? Why or why not?
d. Suppose that the cost of producing dates and
eggs rises to $1.00 per package and $1.00 per
dozen, respectively. Now is there any advan-
tage to mixed bundling? Why or why not? Ex-
plain your answer with a numerical illustration.
e. What accounts for the change in optimal
strategy when costs change?
17. Elaine makes delicious cupcakes that she mails
to customers across the country. Her cupcakes
are so delicious that she has a great degree of
pricing power. Elaine’s customers have identi-
cal demands for cupcakes. A representative cus-
tomer’s demand is shown in the diagram below.
Elaine can make a cupcake for a constant mar-
ginal and average total cost of $0.50.
Quantity of cupcakes
Price
($/cupcake)
MC = ATC
0
D
$2.50
0.50
20 25
a. If Elaine is an ordinary monopolist, what
price should she charge for cupcakes? How
many will each customer order? How much
profit will Elaine earn? How much consumer
surplus will the buyer get?
b. Suppose that Elaine decides to offer a quanti-
ty discount according to the following terms:
The first 10 cupcakes can be bought for $1.50
each; any cupcake over 10 will be offered at
a discounted price. What discount price will
maximize Elaine’s profit from this pricing
scheme? (Hint: Draw a new demand curve
for Elaine’s customers’ demand, but since her
customers have already purchased 10, begin
your demand curve at the 11th unit. Alterna-
tively, shift the vertical axis to the right by
10 units.)
c. How many cupcakes will customers order at
full price? How many at the discounted price?
d. What will Elaine’s profit be? How does this
scheme compare to the profit she earned as
an ordinary monopolist?
e. Suppose that Elaine gets super-greedy and
decides to implement a three-tiered pricing
system. What three prices should she choose
to maximize her profit? At what quantities
will the price points change? What will her
profit be?
f. Suppose Elaine decides to charge $2.40 for the
first cupcake, $2.30 for the second, and so on.
How many cupcakes will she sell, and what
will her profit be?
g. What happens to consumer surplus as Elaine
adds more price points? Where does it go?
18. Consider the demand for cupcakes in Problem
17. Suppose Elaine decides to sell cupcakes only
in packages of 20.
*
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 437 11/5/12 4:01 PM
438 Part 3 Markets and Prices
a. How much would customers be willing to pay
to obtain a 20-pack of Elaine’s cupcakes?
(Hint: Remember that the value of each cup-
cake is given by the corresponding point on
the demand curve. Add up those values for
cupcakes 1–20.)
b. How much profit will Elaine earn from each
customer?
c. How does the profit from this scheme com-
pare to the profit Elaine earned in part (f) of
Problem 17?
19. Many gyms offer a mixed two-part tariff pric-
ing scheme. One can join the gym and then
have daily access at a very low cost (often,
free); alternatively, one can choose not to join
and pay a higher daily fee (perhaps $10 or
$15). Explain the rationale for this dual pric-
ing scheme. What must be true of the gym’s
customers’ demands?
20. SmacFone is a major provider of pay-by-the-minute, no contract cellphones that are very popular with or-
dinary consumers. They are also quite popular with drug dealers, who appreciate the anonymity that such
phones provide. The demand curves for talking minutes that SmacFone faces from each type of customer are
given in the diagrams below. SmacFone’s marginal and average total cost of service is 5 cents per minute.
Quantity of minutes
Price
($/minute)
MC
0
D
$0.25
0.05
240 300
(a) Drug dealer’s demand (b) Ordinary person’s demand
Quantity of minutes
Price
($/minute)
MC
0
D
$0.15
0.05
600 900
a. Determine the profit-maximizing price and quantity that SmacFone would like to charge each type of
consumer, and show it on the appropriate graph. Then, determine the potential profit that SmacFone
could generate from each segment.
Because SmacFone cannot tell whether a new customer is an ordinary person or a drug dealer, it decides
to use second-degree price discrimination to separate consumers. SmacFone sets a Plan A price of 15 cents
per minute, but offers a special Plan B price of 10 cents per minute if a customer purchases 300 or more
minutes.
b. Determine how much consumer surplus ordinary consumers would receive under Plans A and B. Which
plan should ordinary consumers choose if they are trying to maximize their surplus?
c. Determine how much consumer surplus drug dealers would receive under Plans A and B. Which plan
should drug dealers choose if they are trying to maximize their surplus?
d. Is the plan SmacFone derived incentive compatible? (In other words, will the plan successfully direct drug
dealers to Plan A and ordinary consumers to Plan B?) How much profit will SmacFone generate with this
set of plans?
e. SmacFone is considering making some adjustments to their plans. One option is to change Plan B to 11
cents per minute with a 240-minute minimum. Determine whether the new plan selection is incentive-
compatible. Why doesn’t SmacFone simply raise the price to 11 cents without altering the 300-minute
minimum? How much profit will the new set of plans generate for SmacFone?
f. Another option that SmacFone is considering is dropping the price of its ordinary service to 14 cents
per minute. Determine whether the new plan selection is incentive compatible. How much profit will
the new set of plans generate for SmacFone?
g. Why does lowering the price of ordinary service work better at creating an incentive-compatible set of
calling plans than raising the price of the large-quantity plan?
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 438 11/5/12 4:01 PM
doc_580425406.pdf
How, exactly, does offering student discounts raise a seller’s producer surplus?From our study of market power in Chapter 9, we know that when a firm can influence
its own price, it makes a higher profit than a perfectly competitive (i.e., pricetaking)
company. The market power pricing rule we came up with, however, requiredthe
firm to charge the same price to all customers. In this chapter, we see that ifa
firm can charge different prices to different groups of customers (e.g., studentsand
nonstudents), it can raise surplus and profit above those earned by a standardmonopolist
charging every customer the same price. There are many ways in whichfirms
with market power can charge different prices for the same good. This chapterexplores
the most common of these strategies and looks at how they affect producersand
consumers in the market.
Y
ou’ve no doubt noticed many places where you can receive price discounts
if you show your student ID. Commonly discounted goods include movie ad-
missions, clothing at the campus bookstore, gym memberships, train fare,
and even computer equipment.
It’s nice of these sellers to give you a price break while you’re getting your education.
School isn’t cheap, and every little bit helps. The sellers’ generosity must say something
about the value that they put on everyone receiving a good education. Right?
Not really. The main motivation behind such student discounts isn’t altruism. Instead, it
is almost surely the sellers’ attempt to extract more producer surplus from the market than
they would otherwise. That’s not to say you’re worse off because they’ve offered these
discounts; in fact, they make it more likely you will be able to consume goods that would
otherwise be too expensive for you. But there’s something in it for the sellers, too — these
discounts increase their producer surplus and improve their bottom lines.
Market Power and
Pricing Strategies
10
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 395 11/5/12 4:01 PM
396 Part 3 Markets and Prices
How, exactly, does offering student discounts raise a seller’s producer surplus?
From our study of market power in Chapter 9, we know that when a firm can influ-
ence its own price, it makes a higher profit than a perfectly competitive (i.e., price-
taking) company. The market power pricing rule we came up with, however, required
the firm to charge the same price to all customers. In this chapter, we see that if
a firm can charge different prices to different groups of customers (e.g., students
and nonstudents), it can raise surplus and profit above those earned by a standard
monopolist charging every customer the same price. There are many ways in which
firms with market power can charge different prices for the same good. This chapter
explores the most common of these strategies and looks at how they affect producers
and consumers in the market.
10.1 The Basics of Pricing Strategy
A pricing strategy is a firm’s plan for setting the price of its product given the mar-
ket conditions it faces and its desire to maximize profit. The pricing strategy for a
perfectly competitive firm is that it charges the equilibrium market price for its prod-
uct and earns no economic profit. The pricing strategy for firms with market power is
more complex. A firm with market power that charges one price to all its customers
sets the market price according to the quantity of output it chooses to produce to
maximize its profit. (Remember that firms operating in markets with barriers to entry
are able to earn economic profits even in the long run.) Some firms with market power,
however, can charge different prices to different customers for the same product using
a pricing strategy called price discrimination. If a firm with market power can price
discriminate, it can earn greater economic profit than a single-price monopoly.
It is important to understand that price discrimination is not the same phenom-
enon as the existence of different prices for different goods. Price differences can
occur across similar products even in a competitive market if the marginal costs of
producing the products are different. For example, if the marginal cost of washing
SUVs at the car wash is higher than that of washing Mini Coopers because SUVs are
bigger, car washes might charge more to wash SUVs. Price discrimination is some-
thing different. It implies the use of market power to charge higher prices for the same
product to those consumers who are willing to pay more for it. Price variations due
to price discrimination do not reflect differences in marginal costs; they exist simply
because the firm with market power has the ability to charge different prices for the
same product.
There are several pricing strategies a company can use depending on its circum-
stances. These range from direct price discrimination to indirect price discrimina-
tion to bundling to two-part tariffs and beyond. The motivation for these strategies is
straightforward: A company with market power charges a higher price for the units of
output that provide consumers with greater consumer surplus. By adjusting the price,
a firm extracts more producer surplus from each transaction.
When Can a Firm Pursue a Pricing Strategy?
All the pricing strategies we discuss in this chapter start from two key requirements:
Requirement 1: The firm must have market power. A company must have market
power to price discriminate. It’s that simple. If the firm you have in mind does not have
market power, you are in the wrong chapter of the book. You should be in Chapter 8 on
perfect competition. Without market power, a firm can’t choose its price at all, much
less choose to charge different prices to different consumers or use more advanced pricing
strategies.
10.1 The Basics of
Pricing Strategy
10.2 Direct Price
Discrimination I:
Perfect/First-
Degree Price
Discrimination
10.3 Direct Price
Discrimination II:
Segmenting/
Third-Degree Price
Discrimination
10.4 Indirect/Second-
Degree Price
Discrimination
10.5 Bundling
10.6 Advanced Pricing
Strategies
10.7 Conclusion
pricing strategy
A ?rm’s method of pricing
its product based on market
characteristics.
price discrimination
The practice of charging
different prices to different
customers for the same
product.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 396 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 397
Requirement 2: The firm must prevent resale and arbitrage. To take advantage of
advanced pricing strategies, a firm must be able to prevent its customers from reselling
its product among themselves. Otherwise, the customers able to buy units at a low price
could purchase a large number of units and resell them to other customers who would
otherwise have had to buy the product from the firm at a higher price. The practice of
taking advantage of price differences for a product by buying at a lower price and resell-
ing at a higher price is called arbitrage.
The ability to engage in arbitrage makes all customers better off. The low-price custom-
ers make a profit on resale, and the high-price consumers can buy the product at a lower
price than the firm would charge. The firm isn’t better off, though. It is effectively shut
out from directly selling to any consumers except those who want to buy at the lowest
price. Because it would then be selling at only one price, however, the firm would be back
in the traditional situation for a firm with market power described in Chapter 9: It should
produce the quantity at which marginal revenue equals marginal cost and charge the price
at which buyers would consume that quantity (and therefore not worry about resellers).
If a firm meets these two requirements, it can attempt to implement more profitable
pricing strategies. Figure 10.1 provides an overview of these strategies.
arbitrage
The practice of reselling a
product at a price higher
than its original selling
price.
Figure 10.1 An Overview of Pricing Strategies
Does the firm have
market power?
Can the firm
prevent resale
and arbitrage?
Do the firm’s
customers
have different
demand curves?
Can the firm directly
identify customers’
demands before they
buy the product?
Direct price
discrimination
Firm has complete
information about
every customer.
Perfect (first-degree)
price discrimination
(Section 10.2)
Perfect competition
produces quantity at which
MR = P = MC (Chapter 8)
Advanced pricing strategies
(Section 10.6)
Monopoly produces
quantity (Q*) at which
MR = MC, sets price P*
where Q* = D(P*) (Chapter 9)
Firm has information
on groups
of customers.
Segmenting (third-degree)
price discrimination
(Section 10.3)
• Block pricing
• Two-part tariff
Indirect (second-degree)
price discrimination
(Section 10.4)
Bundling (Section 10.5)
• Quantity discounts
• Versioning
• Coupons
No
No
No
No Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
A firm’s optimal pricing strategy is deter-
mined by characteristics of the firm, its
product, and its consumers. In particular,
a firm takes into account its degree of
market power, whether the product can be
resold, and its knowledge of its customers’
demand for the product.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 397 11/5/12 4:01 PM
398 Part 3 Markets and Prices
Strategies for Customers with Diferent Demands The first pricing strate-
gies we look at involve price discrimination. For price discrimination to be an option,
a firm needs to have different types of customers with different price sensitivities of
demand. The exact kind of price discrimination the firm should use depends on the kind
of information the firm has.
1. Can a firm identify its customers’ demands before they buy? If the firm has
complete, detailed information about each customer’s own demand curve before she buys
the product, it can practice perfect price discrimination and charge every customer a
different price. If information about its customers is less detailed, a firm may be able to
discriminate by customer group, as in third-degree price discrimination. The key to these
kinds of price discrimination is that a firm must be able to directly identify different
customers or groups of customers (as can a store that requires students to show IDs when
making purchases) and charge different prices to each customer or group of customers.
2. Can a firm identify its customers’ differing demands only after they make a
purchase? If a firm cannot identify different types of consumers before they make their
purchases, it can try more indirect price discrimination, which involves offering different
pricing packages and then identifying the customer’s type from the pricing package she
chooses. These pricing packages can take the form of quantity discounts, different ver-
sions of the product at different prices, or (under the right conditions) bundling together
different products.
Do a Firm’s Customers Have the Same Demand Curves? There is still an-
other set of pricing strategies that a firm can use even if its consumers have the same de-
mand curves. These strategies involve offering different unit prices to the same customer
for different quantities purchased or charging lump-sum fees on top of per-unit prices.
We explore all these strategies in the remainder of this chapter. To help clarify a
firm’s decision, each pricing strategy section has a When to Use It feature that explains
what a firm needs to know about its market and customers to use a given pricing strat-
egy most effectively. By using the best strategy, the firm can extract the most producer
surplus from the market.
10.2
Direct Price Discrimination I:
Perfect/First-Degree Price Discrimination
When to Use It Perfect/First-Degree Price Discrimination
1. The firm has market power and can prevent resale.
2. The firm’s customers have different demand curves.
3. The firm has complete information about every customer and can identify each
one’s demand before purchase.
Let’s start our study of pricing strategies by looking at a firm that has market power,
can prevent resale, and knows that its consumers differ in their willingness to pay and
therefore have different demand curves. To choose a price discrimination strategy that
will allow the firm to reap the greatest benefits of these three characteristics, the firm
must first ask itself whether it can directly identify what type of demand its customers
have before they purchase the product, or whether it can determine this only after they
buy the product. That is, do the buyers have some identifiable characteristic that allows
the firm to observe their sensitivity to price and willingness to pay for the firm’s prod-
uct? If they do, the company can directly identify its customers’ demands beforehand
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 398 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 399
and increase its producer surplus by using direct price discrimination, that is, by
charging different prices to different customers based on something that a firm can
observe directly about its customers’ identities. If it can know its consumers’ demands
only after they buy the product, then the firm has to use indirect price discrimina-
tion, which we discuss later in the chapter.
Let’s first consider the possibilities for a firm that has so much information about
its customers before they buy that it knows each individual buyer’s demand curve
and can charge each buyer a different price equal to the buyer’s willingness to pay.
This type of direct price discrimination is known as perfect price discrimination or
first-degree price discrimination.
Suppose a firm faces a market demand curve like the one labeled D in Figure 10.2.
Panel a shows the outcomes for a perfectly competitive firm and a monopolistic firm. We
know from Chapter 8 that in a perfectly competitive market, the equilibrium price (which
is the same as MR in that case) equals marginal cost MC and the firm produces quantity
Q
c
. Consumer surplus is the area under the demand curve and above the price, A + B + C.
Because we assume that marginal cost is constant, there is no producer surplus.
In Chapter 9, we saw that a firm with market power facing demand curve D and
with no ability to prevent resale produces the quantity where its marginal cost equals its
perfect price
discrimination
(?rst-degree price
discrimination)
A type of direct price dis-
crimination in which a ?rm
charges each customer ex-
actly his willingness to pay.
direct price
discrimination
A pricing strategy in which
?rms charge different
prices to different custom-
ers based on observable
characteristics of the
customers.
(a) A competitive market will set price equal to marginal
cost, producing Q
c
and selling at a price of P
c
. Consumers
will receive a consumer surplus equal to A + B + C and
the firm will earn zero producer surplus. A single-price
monopoly will sell quantity Q
m
at a price of P
m
and re-
ceive a producer surplus equal to B. Consumers will receive
consumer surplus equal to A and the deadweight loss from
market power will be area C.
(b) If a firm with market power can identify each cus-
tomer’s demand curve, then it will charge each customer
her willingness to pay and capture the entire surplus,
A + B + C. For example, the firm will charge a customer
willing to pay P
d
exactly the price P
d
and a customer
willing to pay P
f
the price P
f
. The firm will sell up to
the quantity Q
c
, the perfectly competitive quantity where
P
c
= MC. There is no deadweight loss when a firm prac-
tices perfect price discrimination.
Figure 10.2 Perfect (First-Degree) Price Discrimination
Quantity
Price
($/unit)
(a) Perfect competition and monopoly (b) Perfect price discrimination
D MR
MC
C
B
A
Q
c
Q
m
P
m
P
c
Quantity
Price
($/unit)
D MR
MC
B
C
A
Q
c
P
d
P
f
P
c
Consumer surplus (competition)
Producer surplus (competition)
Consumer surplus (market power)
Producer surplus (market power)
Deadweight loss from market power
= A + B + C
= 0
= A
= B
= C
Consumer surplus
Producer surplus
Deadweight loss from market power
= 0
= A + B + C
= 0
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 399 11/5/12 4:01 PM
400 Part 3 Markets and Prices
marginal revenue, Q
m
, and sets the price P
m
for that quantity from its demand curve. It
charges this single price to everyone in the market. This market power pricing has three
outcomes relative to the competitive pricing: (1) There is now a producer surplus equal
to the rectangle B (far better from the firm’s perspective than the competitive outcome,
no producer surplus); (2) there is now a deadweight loss equal to the triangle C, because
quantity is below its competitive level; and (3) consumer surplus is reduced to area A.
If, however, the firm with market power can prevent resale and directly identify
each and every customer’s demand curve (panel b), the outcome is very different. In
this case, the firm can charge every customer her willingness to pay for every unit (or,
to guarantee she’d take the deal, just a bit below this level). This is perfect price dis-
crimination, and the benefit to the firm is tremendous. For any unit of output where a
customer’s willingness to pay is greater than the firm’s marginal cost of producing it,
the firm captures the whole amount of available surplus. So, for example, a customer
accounting for the portion of the demand curve at P
d
pays that relatively high price,
while another at P
f
pays that relatively low price. In these and all other cases, even
though the prices are different, customers pay the most they are willing to pay, and the
firm gets the entire surplus (the area below demand and above marginal cost).
After all such transactions, the firm will have sold a quantity of Q
c
to various
consumers at different prices depending on each buyer’s willingness to pay. (Because
the firm can prevent resale, customers aren’t able to buy the product from another
customer for a lower price than the firm offers.) The producer surplus the firm earns
as a result equals the entire surplus in the market (A + B + C). This is the maximum
amount of surplus that can be made from the market because no consumer will pay
more than his or her willingness to pay (that rules out the area above the demand curve)
and the firm must pay its costs (that eliminates the area below the marginal cost curve).
It’s good to be a firm that can perfectly price discriminate.
Another interesting feature of perfect price discrimination is that, unlike the single-
price market power outcome, there is no deadweight loss! It is efficient: No potential
surplus is lost from a reduction in the equilibrium quantity. The quantity sold ( Q
c
) is the
same quantity that would be sold if the market were perfectly competitive. Who keeps
the market surplus is very different in the two cases, however: Under perfect competition,
the entire surplus goes to the consumers, while under perfect price discrimination, the
entire surplus goes to the producer. Efficiency is not the same thing as fairness. (We will
further discuss issues of market efficiency and distribution in Chapter 14.)
10.1 ?gure it out
A firm with market power faces an inverse demand
curve for its product of P = 100 – 10Q. Assume
that the firm faces a marginal cost curve of
MC = 10 + 10Q.
a. If the firm cannot price discriminate, what is
the profit-maximizing level of output and price?
b. If the firm cannot price discriminate, what
are the levels of consumer and producer surplus in
the market, assuming the firm maximizes its profit?
Calculate the deadweight loss from market power.
c. If the firm has the ability to practice perfect
price discrimination, what is the firm’s output?
d. If the firm practices perfect price discrimination,
what are the levels of consumer and producer
surplus? What is the deadweight loss from market
power?
Solution:
a. If the firm cannot price discriminate, it maxi-
mizes profit by producing where MR = MC. If the
inverse demand function is P = 100 – 10Q, then the
marginal revenue must be MR = 100 – 20Q. (Re-
member that, for any linear inverse demand function
P = a – bQ, marginal revenue is MR = a – 2bQ.)
? The online appendix
demonstrates ef?ciency for
?rms that practice perfect
price discrimination.
(http://glsmicro.com/appendices)
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 400 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 401
Setting MR = MC, we obtain
100 – 20Q = 10 + 10Q
90 = 30Q
Q = 3
To find the optimal price, we plug Q = 3 into the
inverse demand equation:
P = 100 – 10Q
= 100 – 10(3)
= 100 – 30
= 70
The firm sells 3 units at a price of $70 each.
b. To find consumer and producer surplus, we
need to start with a diagram showing the demand,
marginal revenue, and marginal cost curves:
Quantity
Price
($/unit)
MC
0
MR
D
D B
C
A
$100
10
40
70
4.5 3
Consumer surplus is the area above price and below
demand (area A). Producer surplus is the area above
marginal cost but below the price (area B + C). (Note
that we could just label these two areas as a large
trapezoid, but it is easier to remember the formulas
for the area of a rectangle and a triangle!) We can
calculate the areas:
Area A =
1
_
2
base × height
=
1
_
2
× 3 × ($100 – $70)
= 0.5(3)($30)
= $45
Consumer surplus is $45.
Area B = base × height
To get the height of areas B and C, we need the MC
of producing a quantity of 3:
MC = 10 + 10Q = 10 + 10(3) = $40. So,
Area B = 3 × ($70 – $40)
= 3($30)
= $90
Area C =
1
_
2
× base × height
=
1
_
2
× 3 × ($40 – $10)
= 0.5(3)($30)
= $45
So, Producer surplus = Area B + Area C =
$90 + $45 = $135.
The deadweight loss from market power is the
loss in surplus that occurs because the market is not
producing the competitive quantity. To calculate the
competitive quantity, we set P = MC:
100 – 10Q = 10 + 10Q
90 = 20Q
Q = 4.5
The deadweight loss can be seen on the diagram as
area D:
Area D =
1
_
2
× base × height
=
1
_
2
× (4.5 – 3) × ($70 – $40)
= 0.5(1.5)($30)
= $22.50
The deadweight loss from market power is $22.50.
c. If the firm practices perfect price
discrimination, it will produce where P = MC. As
we saw in part (b) above, this means that the firm
will produce 4.5 units.
d. If the firm practices perfect price
discrimination, consumer surplus will be zero because
every consumer will be charged a price equal to his
willingness to pay. Producer surplus will be the full
area between the demand curve and the marginal
cost curve (area A + B + C + D):
Producer surplus = area A + area B + area C + area D
= $45 + $90 + $45 + $22.50
= $202.50
There is no deadweight loss when the firm perfectly
price discriminates. The competitive output level is
achieved (Q = 4.5). Producers end up with the entire
surplus available in the market.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 401 11/5/12 4:01 PM
402 Part 3 Markets and Prices
Examples of Perfect Price Discrimination
Actual cases of died-in-the-wool perfect price discrimination are rare. What firm really
knows every single customer’s willingness to pay for its product? There are instances,
though, where sellers charge many, many different prices for the same product. Two
classic examples are cars and college education.
When people walk into a car dealership, the salesperson sizes them up and eventu-
ally begins negotiating over price. While the dealer doesn’t have complete information
about each customer’s willingness to pay, haggling differently with every customer is a
lot like perfect price discrimination — the auto dealer is trying to simultaneously learn
about the customer’s valuation of the car and arrive at a price as close as possible to
that level. That’s why you should think twice when you go to buy a car and the sales-
man asks you, “How much are you looking to spend on a car?” That’s an invitation for
you to give up your consumer surplus.
Likewise, families applying for college financial aid are required to submit complete
information about their assets and income along with the student’s assets and income.
From this information, the school has an almost perfect understanding of each student’s
willingness to pay. This allows schools to produce an individually tailored financial aid
plan. But that is another way of saying that they charge a different tuition price to each
student, depending on how much they think the student can afford.
application
How Priceline Learned That You Can’t Price Discriminate
without Market Power
Priceline is the online travel service known in part for originating the “name your own
price” model of online sales. The initial idea was that people would go to Priceline’s
site and enter what they were willing to pay for an airplane ticket— for example, $300
for a round-trip from Los Angeles to Boston on April 10th. Priceline would then see
if there were any airlines willing to supply the ticket to Priceline for less than that. If
so, Priceline would charge the customer’s credit card $300 and issue the ticket, earning
the difference as profit.
The idea was that by asking each person what she was willing to pay, Priceline
could engage in something like perfect price discrimination and therefore make a lot of
money. We can think of its original business model in terms of Figure 10.3. Priceline
figured that, with a marginal cost of tickets of MC and travelers’ willingness to pay
(demand curve) at D, it stood to earn producer surplus approximately equal to the
area A + B. The stock market liked this model, too: Within three years of starting up
its Web site, the company was valued at $13 billion, more than several of the major
airlines combined.
There was a serious problem in Priceline’s approach, however. Priceline wanted to
price discriminate, but it didn’t really have market power in the travel agency industry.
There are thousands of offline travel agencies; several other major online travel firms
like Orbitz, Travelocity, and Expedia; and airlines sell a lot of tickets directly from their
own Web sites. We know from what we’ve just learned that a company can’t price-
discriminate if it doesn’t have market power. Priceline learned this lesson the hard way.
Priceline’s problem was that, because travelers could also get fares at low prices
directly from other travel sites, they wouldn’t offer their true willingness to pay from
their demand curves. Instead, customers would only offer to buy tickets at a lower price
than they could buy them elsewhere.
Priceline’s market demand curve was therefore not the consumer’s demand curve D,
but rather a curve strictly below the market price of tickets at other sites. In the figure,
the outside price occurs at P
out
. So, the actual demand curve facing Priceline was not
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 402 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 403
D but D
act
instead. This kind of price discrimination doesn’t make large profits. It left
Priceline with a surplus of only B, the small area below the actual demand curve and
above marginal cost. Indeed, this demand curve left Priceline with less producer surplus
than that earned by other travel sites (which were charging prices at or above P
out
).
Realizing this, Priceline eventually deemphasized the “name your own price” busi-
ness model and expanded into the conventionally priced online travel business. It has
so far succeeded — its stock market valuation was back up to over $20 billion in 2011
after falling all the way to $225 million in 2000. It had a tough road back. The moral
of the story is, as always: Remember your economics. ?
10.3
Direct Price Discrimination II: Segmenting/
Third-Degree Price Discrimination
When to Use It Segmenting/Third-Degree Price Discrimination
1. The firm has market power and can prevent resale.
2. The firm’s customers have different demand curves.
3. The firm can directly identify specific groups of customers with different price
sensitivities (but not the demand of every individual customer) before purchase.
Because it’s rare for a firm to have the kind of comprehensive information about
customers that it needs to practice perfect price discrimination, a firm can’t gener-
ally capture all of the market surplus using price discrimination. But it can still earn
more profit than a regular monopoly by using a pricing strategy called segmenting
(or third-degree price discrimination), charging different prices to different groups
(segments) of customers based on the identifiable attributes of those groups.
1
With market power, Priceline could use perfect
price discrimination to capture the entire sur-
plus above MC but below D, the area A + B.
However, because it does not have market power,
Priceline’s demand curve D
act
is below demand
curve D. Using perfect price discrimination,
Priceline can only capture B, the area above MC
but below D
act
.
Figure 10.3 Perfect Price Discrimination without Market Power: What Went Wrong
with Naming Your Own Price
Quantity of
airline flights
Price
($/flight)
D
D
act
MC
B
A
P
out
Expected producer surplus
Actual producer surplus
= A + B
= B
1
While third-degree discrimination sounds like a variant of first-degree discrimination, the truth is that
these names were somewhat arbitrarily coined by economist E. H. Chamberlin back in the 1930s.
segmenting
(third-degree price
discrimination)
A type of direct price
discrimination in which
a ?rm charges different
prices to different groups
of customers.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 403 11/5/12 4:01 PM
404 Part 3 Markets and Prices
For this kind of pricing strategy to work, the company must be able to directly
identify groups of customers — students, for example — who have systematically dif-
ferent demands than other buyers. This group-level demand identification is typically
much easier to determine than figuring out every individual customer’s willingness
to pay.
Think about a company that sells a clothing line emblazoned with the logo of a local
university. If the company knows that students typically don’t have a lot of money and
tend to be bargain hunters while their parents or the faculty are less price-sensitive,
the firm will want to charge students a lower price for clothing and parents or faculty a
higher price. To do this, the company needs to be able to identify the groups directly. It
must be able to tell before the sale which customers are students and which are parents
or faculty, as well as prevent parents and faculty from pretending to be students to
get the discount. One way the company can do this is to make showing a student ID a
condition of the lower price.
As with all forms of price discrimination, however, the company must be able
to prevent resale. They can’t sell school sweatshirts at a student discount just to
have the students then turn around and sell them to visiting parents or faculty for
less than the higher price these groups would be charged. As a practical matter,
if such resales became a problem, the company could institute a quota that would
limit the number of sweatshirts a student could buy. Limiting resale is critical to
price discrimination.
The Bene?ts of Segmenting:
A Graphical Approach
If a firm is able to engage in segmenting, how different
should the prices be across the groups, and how much does
the company stand to gain by price discriminating com-
pared to the standard one-price monopoly strategy?
To answer these questions, let’s consider an example
with two consumer groups, the market for entry into the
prestigious Ironman 70.3 Cozumel Triathlon. This triath-
lon is a race that comprises a 1.2-mile swim, a 56-mile
bike ride, and a 13.1-mile run. It may seem like a mas-
ochistic pursuit, but people pay serious money to enter
this race.
There are two kinds of people who want to enter the
Ironman Cozumel: people who live in and around Cozu-
mel, and people who fly in from somewhere else. The two groups’ demand curves for
entering the race are shown in Figure 10.4. Panel a shows the demand ( D
T
) for the
participants traveling to Cozumel for the competition. The travelers mostly come
from the United States; have high incomes and expensive triathlon equipment; and
will have to pay for a plane ticket, a hotel room, food, and a rental car. They don’t
care if the price of their registration for the race is a bit higher, because it’s a small
share of the total cost to them. In other words, the demand curve for the traveling
participants is fairly inelastic.
Panel b of the figure shows the local group’s demand curve, D
L
. The local residents’
demand is more price-sensitive because they have many other activities they can pursue
if the price of entering the race is too high. Thus, their demand curve is flatter and
more elastic.
Preventing resale won’t be a problem for the firm organizing the race as long as it
can tell which athletes are from out of town and which are not. This is easy because
out-of-town athletes have to pay their entrance fees with some form of identification
H
u
g
o
O
r
t
u
ñ
o
S
u
á
r
e
z
/
D
e
m
o
t
i
x
/
C
o
r
b
i
s
How many of these triathletes had to travel to Cozumel
to compete?
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 404 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 405
that gives their address, and they have to prove who they are when claiming their bib
numbers on race day.
The fundamental economic idea of segmenting is simple. If a firm can directly
identify groups that have different demands and charge different prices to each, it
can essentially treat each group as a separate market. The firm then sets its profit-
maximizing quantity for each one of these “markets” where MR = MC and sets
the corresponding single-price profit-maximizing price according to each market’s
demand curve.
Let’s see how the organizers of the Ironman Cozumel competition follow the seg-
menting strategy. The organizers have identified these two different demand curves
and treat each as a separate market. From the demand curve of out-of-town entrants
(travelers) D
T
, the organizers compute marginal revenue, labeled MR
T
in panel a of
Figure 10.4. Then from the point at which MR
T
equals marginal cost MC, the organiz-
ers determine the optimal quantity of entries to sell to out-of-towners ( Q
T
= 600). At
that quantity, the entry fee is P
T
= $220.
The organizers go through the same process for the local entrants. These entrants’
demand curve D
L
in panel b implies a marginal revenue curve MR
L
. The optimal
number of entries for the organizer to offer to locals is Q
L
= 700, the quantity at
which marginal revenue from locals equals marginal cost. (The marginal cost is the
same for either type of racer. It amounts, basically, to the cost of a bib, some extra
Gatorade, some water, a finisher’s medal, and a race T-shirt.) The price, determined
from the locals’ demand curve, is P
L
= $170, significantly lower than the $220 price
for traveling entrants.
(a) The Ironman 70.3 Cozumel Triathlon segments its par-
ticipants into two groups, traveling and local participants.
Traveling participants are relatively insensitive to price
and have an inelastic demand curve D
T
. The number of
traveling participants will be Q
T
= 600, and each will pay
a registration fee of P
T
= $220/entry. Producer surplus,
P S
T
, will be relatively large.
(b) Local participants have a relatively elastic demand
curve D
L
. A greater number of locals will register for the
triathlon ( Q
L
= 700) at a lower price ( P
L
= $170/entry).
Producer surplus for locals, P S
L
, is relatively small.
Figure 10.4 Segmenting Entry Fees at the Ironman 70.3 Cozumel Triathlon
Quantity
of entries
Price
($/entry)
MC
MR
T
PS
T
D
T
0
Q
T
= 600
P
T
= 220
$340
100
(a) Traveling participants (b) Local participants
Quantity
of entries
Price
($/entry)
MC
MR
L
PS
L
D
L
0
Q
L
= 700
P
L
= 170
$240
100
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 405 11/5/12 4:01 PM
406 Part 3 Markets and Prices
That’s all there is to the strategy. As long as a seller can keep people from sneaking
into the lower-price group or keep those in the lower-price group from reselling to the
higher-price group, it can use segmenting to treat each group like a separate market
and set the monopoly price for each market.
A firm following this pricing strategy will not earn as much producer surplus as one
using perfect price discrimination (which would allow it to take the entire surplus from
the market). However, it will earn more surplus than if it acted like a regular monopoly
and charged the same price to everyone, because the strategy gives the firm some ability
to charge a higher price to consumers with relatively inelastic demand and lower prices
to consumers with relatively elastic demand.
Figure 10.5 shows the total Ironman Cozumel demand and marginal revenue that
would face a monopolist forced to set only a single price. As in Chapter 5, we calculate
the market demand as the horizontal sum of the participants’ demand curves — in this
case, the sum of the traveling and local participants’ demands. This results in a kink
in the market demand curve at $240, the demand choke price for local participants. At
prices above $240, no locals purchase tickets, so the market demand curve is just the
traveling racers’ demand curve.
A single-price monopolist race organizer sets the quantity of entries where its mar-
ginal cost equals marginal revenue, and charges the price corresponding to the total
market demand curve. This quantity, 1,300 racers, is shown in Figure 10.5, and the cor-
responding price is $186.67 per entry. Notice how this price falls between the two prices
($170 and $225) that the organizers charge the segments when price-discriminating. Al-
though it might not be obvious from looking at the figure, the producer surplus for the
single-price monopolist is considerably smaller than the surplus the monopolist would
earn by segmenting the market. (We see that this is indeed the case when we calculate
the benefits from segmenting in the next section.)
The Bene?ts of Segmenting:
A Mathematical Approach
To do the same analysis of segmenting using mathematics, we start with the two distinct
demand curves for the Ironman Cozumel. The demand curve of the traveling partici-
pants is given by Q
T
= 1,700 – 5 P
T
, and the locals’ demand curve is Q
L
= 2,400 – 10 P
L
.
A single-price monopolist faces the kinked demand
curve D, equal to the horizontal sum of the de-
mand curves for travelers and local participants.
The race organizer will sell 1,300 entries at a price
of $186.67, between the two prices ($170 and $225)
charged when the market is segmented. The result-
ing producer surplus, rectangle A, is smaller than
the producer surplus under market segmentation.
Figure 10.5 Single-Price Monopolist at the Ironman 70.3 Cozumel Triathlon
Quantity
of entries
Price
($/entry)
MC
MR
D
A
0
1,300 500
240
$340
100
186.67
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 406 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 407
Note that, in accordance with our story, the locals’ quantity demanded is more sensitive
to price than the travelers’ quantity demanded: A $1 increase in the entry fee reduces
the number of local entrants by 10, while it only decreases the number of traveling en-
trants by 5. We assume the marginal cost to the organizer of adding another triathlete
to the race is a constant $100, no matter how many entrants there are.
The mathematical analysis of segmenting is done using the same steps as in the
graphical analysis above. If the race organizers can identify the separate groups
and prevent resale, they can compute the marginal revenue curves for each segment and
solve for the monopoly prices separately for each group.
We can follow the methods discussed in Chapter 9 to find the marginal revenue
curves from linear demand curves. First, we determine the inverse demand curves by
rearranging the demand function to express price in terms of quantity demanded. Doing
so gives us the following equations:
For travelers:
Q
T
= 1,700 – 5 P
T
5 P
T
= 1,700 – Q
T
P
T
= 340 – 0.2 Q
T
For locals:
Q
L
= 2,400 – 10 P
L
10 P
L
= 2,400 – Q
L
P
L
= 240 – 0.1 Q
L
Next, we know that the marginal revenue curve will look like the inverse demand
curve, but the coefficient on quantity will be twice as large. The marginal revenue
curves for the two segments are
For travelers: For locals:
MR
T
= 340 – 0.4 Q
T
and MR
L
= 240 – 0.2 Q
L
The organizers want to sell the quantities at which marginal cost ($100, the same for
both groups of triathletes) equals its marginal revenue. Setting each marginal revenue equa-
tion above equal to marginal cost tells us the optimal number of entrants from each group:
For travelers:
MR
T
= MC
340 – 0.4 Q
T
= 100
240 = 0.4 Q
T
Q
T
= 600
For locals:
MR
L
= MC
240 – 0.2 Q
L
= 100
140 = 0.2 Q
L
Q
L
= 700
The last step is to find the entry fees that correspond to these quantities by plugging
the quantities back into the inverse demand curve:
For travelers:
P
T
= 340 – 0.2 Q
T
= 340 – 0.2(600)
= 340 – 120
= $220
For locals:
P
L
= 240 – 0.1 Q
L
= 240 – 0.1(700)
= 240 – 70
= $170
Therefore, in a segmentation strategy, the race organizers sell 600 entries to out-of-
towners for $220 each and 700 entries to locals at $170 each.
The total producer surplus the organizers earn is the difference between the price and
the marginal cost for each segment times the number of entries sold to that segment. In
Figure 10.4, those surpluses are rectangles PS
T
for the segment of nonlocal triathletes
and PS
L
for the local triathletes. Using the results we computed above, we have
For travelers:
PS
T
= (220 – 100) × 600
= 120(600)
= $72,000
For locals:
PS
L
= (170 – 100) × 700
= 70(700)
= $49,000
for a combined producer surplus of $121,000 to the race organizer.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 407 11/5/12 4:01 PM
408 Part 3 Markets and Prices
In our graphical analysis, we contended that the price-discriminating monopolist
earns more producer surplus than the single-price monopolist. This makes intuitive
sense, because a firm that segments the market can charge higher prices to more price-
inelastic customers and capture more of their consumer surplus. But how can we show
this algebraically?
First, we can see that the marginal cost curve intersects demand at the part of the
demand curve below the kink — the portion of the demand curve that is the sum of
the local and nonlocal demand:
Q = 1,700 – 5P + 2,400 – 10P = 4,100 – 15P
The inverse demand curve at this intersection is then P =
4,100
____
15
–
Q
__
15
, and the mar-
ginal revenue curve has twice the slope, or MR =
4,100
____
15
–
2Q
___
15
. We set MR equal to the
marginal cost to solve for the optimal number of participants under the single-pricing
strategy:
4,100
_
15
–
2Q
_
15
= 100
4,100 – 2Q = 1,500
Q = 1,300
Note that 1,300 is exactly the sum of the local and traveling participants under the
previous pricing system. Single-price monopolists and those who segment differ in
the prices they set, but not always in the quantity they provide. That doesn’t mean the
firm would be selling to the same group of individuals, however. The new price will
be lower than the segmented price for travelers (inducing more to buy than in the
segmented case) and higher than the segmented price for locals (excluding some locals
from buying). Just what is the price in this instance? Plug the quantity into the inverse
demand curve:
P =
4,100
_
15
–
1,300
_
15
= $186.67
Thus, although locals face a slightly higher price, the travelers get a bargain relative to
the segmented outcome.
To calculate the producer surplus, we find the area of the rectangle A in Figure 10.5:
PS = (186.67 – 100) × 1,300
= 86.67(1,300) = $112,671
If the monopolist organizers segment the market for triathlon entries, they earn
$121,000 in producer surplus; if they must charge a single price, they earn $112,671.
Just by segmenting the market, the monopolist organizers can increase their producer
surplus by $8,329, or about 7%.
How Much Should Each Segment Be Charged?
Because the standard market power pricing rule applies in each segment, it also means
that the Lerner index, the basic markup formula we derived in Chapter 9, applies in
each market. Recall that this formula relates the price elasticity of demand to the
markup of price over marginal cost:
(P– MC)
_
P
= –
1
_
E
D
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 408 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 409
If the firm sells the same good to both segments of the market, the marginal cost
of producing for each segment is the same. In this case, the only reason to charge
different prices to customers in different segments is because they have different
demand elasticities. To see what the Lerner index implies for the ratio of the prices
in the two segments (label them 1 and 2), first solve the Lerner index for price in
each segment:
( P
1
– MC)
_
P
1
= –
1
_
E
1
D
P
1
– MC = –
1
_
E
1
D
× P
1
P
1
+
(
1
_
E
1
D
× P
1
)
= MC
P
1
(
1 +
1
_
E
1
D
)
= MC
P
1
(
E
1
D
_
E
1
D
+
1
_
E
1
D
)
= MC
P
1
=
(
E
1
D
_
1 + E
1
D
)
× MC
Likewise,
P
2
=
(
E
2
D
_
1 + E
2
D
)
× MC
Now, we can compute the ratio of these prices:
P
1
_
P
2
=
[ E
1
D
/(1 + E
1
D
)] × MC
__
[ E
2
D
/(1 + E
2
D
)] × MC
=
[ E
1
D
/(1 + E
1
D
)]
__
[ E
2
D
/(1 + E
2
D
)]
As the demand in Segment 1 becomes less elastic relative to Segment 2 (i.e., E
1
D
becomes smaller than E
2
D
in absolute value), the ratio P
1
/ P
2
will rise. That is, the
greater the difference in price sensitivities between the segments, the greater should be
the ratio in their prices.
Returning to our Ironman Cozumel example, suppose we know that the elasticity
of demand for travelers is –1.83 and the elasticity for locals is –2.43.
2
We can imme-
diately determine what the ratio of prices should be by plugging these elasticities into
the formula:
P
1
_
P
2
=
–1.83
_
–1.83 + 1
_
–2.43
_
–2.43 + 1
=
–1.83
_
–0.83
_
–2.43
_
–1.43
=
2.2
_
1.7
= 1.29
In other words, the race organizer should set the price travelers face to be almost
1.3 times (i.e., 30% higher than) the price for locals. This is in fact the ratio between
the $220 and $170 optimal entry fees we computed earlier.
2
If you remember the calculation of elasticity from Chapter 2, you can verify these values.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 409 11/5/12 4:01 PM
410 Part 3 Markets and Prices
make the grade
We mentioned this before, but it bears repeating: Al-
ways be careful about the distinction between price
discrimination, when firms charge different prices
for the same product, and price differences. It’s often
surprisingly hard to tell them apart. Prices can dif-
fer across different customer groups if a firm with
market power price discriminates, but prices can
also differ across the groups if the marginal cost
of supplying the groups differs, even in a perfectly
competitive market.
For example, a bottle of Coca-Cola, which is basi-
cally just carbonated water plus syrup, is often less
expensive than a bottle of carbonated water alone.
Perhaps this price difference reflects price discrimi-
nation because the kinds of people who buy bot-
tled water are less price-sensitive than the people
who buy soda. But maybe the cost of bottling fancy
carbonated water is greater than the cost of bottling
soft drinks (a lot more people buy soda than carbon-
ated water and there might be some economies of
scale, for example). You can’t tell just from the prices.
The only way to tell the difference between price
discrimination and price differences due to costs in
competitive markets (without actually being able to
observe the firm’s marginal cost) is to find something
that changes the price elasticity of demand without
changing the cost. Price discrimination implies that
a firm with market power sets its price based on the
elasticity of demand and the marginal cost of produc-
ing. Price in a competitive market depends only on
marginal cost. (This is related to the distinction we
discussed in Chapter 9 about how firms with market
power react differently than competitive firms to rota-
tions in demand.)
Is it really price discrimination?
10.2 ?gure it out
You manage a hair salon that has two locations: one
in a large city in Ohio with several competing salons,
and another in a small city in Pennsylvania with less
competition. In Ohio, your customer’s price elasticity
of demand is –3, while for your Pennsylvania custom-
ers it is –2. Assume that the marginal cost of produc-
ing a haircut is $30 regardless of location.
a. What are your salon’s optimal markups and
prices in each location?
b. Why do they differ?
Solution:
a. The Lerner index provides us with a formula
for seeing the relationship between pricing and the
price elasticity of demand:
(P – MC)
_
P
= –
1
_
E
D
Substituting for marginal cost (= $30) and the price
elasticity of demand for Ohio customers (= –3), we get
(P – $30)
_
P
=
1
_
–(–3)
P = 3(P – $30)
2P = $90
P = $45
Repeating the same steps for Pennsylvania gives
(P – $30)
_
P
=
1
_
–(–2)
P = 2(P – $30)
P = $60
Customers in Ohio will be charged a price of $45 per
haircut, while those in Pennsylvania will be charged a
price of $60 per haircut.
b. Because demand is relatively more elastic in
Ohio than in Pennsylvania (the absolute value of the
price elasticity of demand is greater), customers in
Ohio are more price-sensitive. Therefore, they will be
charged a lower price.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 410 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 411
Ways to Directly Segment Customers
There are many ways firms directly identify customer segments for the purposes of
price discrimination. Here are some of the most common ones.
By Customer Characteristics Firms sometimes price according to customer
characteristics such as age (e.g., senior citizen discounts at the movies or child discounts
at a hotel), gender, or whether the customer is a student or local resident. The basic
idea remains to identify the more price-sensitive customers and charge them less. Firms
need to be careful when pricing based on consumer characteristics in certain countries
because in some cases this may be prohibited by laws against discrimination based on
age, gender, race, physical disabilities, and so on.
Segmenting can even be based on the user’s species. Doctors and veterinarians some-
times use the same medicines. Drug makers recognize that Grandma’s willingness to
pay for the arthritis medication Lodine probably well exceeds someone’s willingness
to purchase Lodine for her arthritic dog Rover (and not only because Grandma’s sav-
ings are larger than Rover’s collection of buried rawhides). This difference in willing-
ness to pay probably explains why a congressional investigation found that the price of
Lodine for humans was almost three times higher than for dogs. Indeed, it determined
that manufacturers priced almost every comparable medication significantly higher for
people than for animals.
3
freakonomics
Victoria’s Not-So-Secret Price Discrimination
Sometimes price discrimination can end up being costly not just to consum-
ers, but also to producers. In 1996 Denise Katzman of New York City sued
Victoria’s Secret for gender discrimination and asked for millions of dollars
in damages. In alleging gender discrimination, Katzman didn’t object to the
catalog’s pages of scantily clad women. Rather, she pointed to the promo-
tional coupon on the catalog’s back page.
The problem? While Ms. Katzman’s catalog offered her $10 off an order of $75, an al-
most identical catalog for a male friend offered $25 off the same amount. Was her catalog
out of date? Nope. The folks at Victoria’s Secret were just engaging in a little “naked” price
discrimination.
Although the company kept its reasons for the different promotions a secret, we can
speculate on why it might employ such price discrimination using our economics reason-
ing. We know that price discrimination occurs when a company uses its market power to
charge higher prices to people who are willing to pay more. In this case, Victoria’s Secret
recognized that its practice of sending out catalogs gave it the opportunity to segment its
customers and advertise different prices to different types of customers. Women might be
willing to purchase $75 of fancy underwear for a price of $65, but men are probably not
as willing to shell out that kind of money for underwear for their wives or girlfriends. They
might only pay $50 for the same order. Because most people don’t end up reading through
their friends’ catalogs, this form of price discrimination could easily go undetected.
Ms. Katzman never did collect her millions in damages, however. Neither did fellow
New Yorker Roy Den Hollander who in 2007 brought suit against bars that sponsor Ladies’
Nights, which Hollander termed “invidious.” He lost his suit, and bars everywhere continue
to advertise gender-based price discrimination with weekly Ladies’ Nights.
3
http://lobby.la.psu.edu/010_Insuring_the_Uninsured/Congressional_Statements/House/
H_Thurman_031600.htm
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 411 11/5/12 4:01 PM
412 Part 3 Markets and Prices
Customer characteristics can also apply to firms or other corporate organiza-
tions in business-to-business transactions. Academic journals, for example, know that
individuals are much more price sensitive to subscription prices than libraries, so the
publishers charge significantly more for institutional subscriptions than for individual
ones. Elsevier, for example, one of the largest publishers of academic journals, charges
individuals $112 for a year’s subscription to the International Journal of Industrial
Organization (don’t all rush to order it at once), but the publisher charges libraries
$1,720 for the same subscription.
By Past Purchase Behavior Consumers reveal a lot about their willingness to pay
when they buy other products, and many sellers use that information to segment cus-
tomers. In industries like auto insurance or direct-broadcast satellite TV, where people
don’t like switching companies once they decide on a provider, existing customers tend
to be less price-sensitive than potential new customers. As a result, it is common for
firms in these industries to give special discounts to new customers, such as reduced
premiums during the first policy period or the first three months of a subscription free.
These are ways to price discriminate based on whether the customer has bought the
product before.
For some other products, the price sensitivity of new customers is lower than that of
past purchasers. For example, it is notoriously difficult to convince people to upgrade
their software to a new version. When Microsoft releases a new version of Windows, the
price of upgrading an older version is typically much lower than buying the new ver-
sion outright. With this low price, Microsoft is trying to entice the more price-sensitive
customers to purchase the new version.
By Location Customers living in one area may have a hard time getting to another
to take advantage of a lower price, or they might not even have knowledge of the prices
in other locations. This often allows sellers to charge different prices in different loca-
tions, depending on the price sensitivity of local demand.
Over Time One way to price discriminate in certain markets is to take advantage of
the different kinds of people who buy a product at different times. When a new genera-
tion of computer CPUs first hits the market, for example, the new CPUs usually sell at
a substantial premium, sometimes hundreds of dollars more than the last generation’s
chips. Yet only a few months later, they are available for a fraction of their original price.
Maybe marginal cost fell that much, you say? Perhaps. But how about movies in first-
run theaters that cost $10 but then cost only $4 when the same movie runs at a discount
movie house several weeks later? Or hardcover books that cost $26.95 while their paper-
back versions cost only $10.95, when the actual difference in production cost is only about
a dollar? These are all cases in which the kinds of people who want the latest, greatest,
most current version of a product—PC gamers, big movie fans, and active readers—tend
to be less sensitive to price than the folks who enter the market later.
In other cases, demand can become less price-sensitive (more inelastic) over time, and
price discrimination will lead to price increases over time. Many goods and services that
have initially uncertain quality have this feature. For example, tickets to a new play
or musical that hasn’t been reviewed are often relatively inexpensive. But once local
reviewers have given the play a “thumbs up,” demand can become much more inelastic
and the producers raise the price accordingly.
In either situation, a firm that prices the same good differently in two different time
periods applies the basic segmentation rules and uses the standard monopoly pricing
rule as it applies to the state of demand in each period.
However, there is one complication in pricing across time that is worth keeping in
mind. Technically, pricing across time is only segmenting if the seller directly assigns
customers to a given time period. That is, in segmentation strategies, the seller is effec-
tively saying, “You buyers over here, this is your price. You buyers over there, you have
a different price.” Buyers are stuck paying the price designated for their group (assum-
ing again as we have throughout this chapter that the seller can prevent resale). With
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 412 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 413
time-based segmentation, however, if customers are forward-looking, meaning that they
consider what the seller might do in the future even as they decide whether to buy
today, then the seller is not actually directly segmenting its customers. The seller can-
not prevent its customers from changing groups; the buyers choose when to buy. So, for
example, if buyers believe that the seller is charging a high price today but will reduce
the price in the future, they might consider waiting to purchase, even if they had the
type of relatively inelastic demand that the seller was trying to take advantage of with
the high current price. In cases like this, the seller needs to consider how the different
prices it plans to charge over time will affect the consumer’s decision of when to buy.
For instance, Intel might want to initially price its fast new CPU at an extremely
high level to take advantage of a segment of high-horsepower PC gamers with really
inelastic demand, while making deep discounts thereafter. But if gamers realize Intel is
likely to do this, they might be willing to trade off waiting to purchase the new CPU
in exchange for enjoying the deep discount. This potential response will limit Intel’s
ability to segment the market in the first place. It could lead to Intel having to charge
a lower initial price than it would have otherwise, and perhaps also reduce the discount
applied to that price later.
The more forward-looking consumers are, the more segmenting across time actually
becomes something known as indirect price discrimination, the pricing strategy we
discuss next.
Segmenting by Location in the European Market for Cars
Car manufacturers like Volkswagen and BMW who do a lot of
business in Europe sell the same car in many different coun-
tries. The customers in these countries have very different
incomes and tastes in cars. Because the automakers in this
market likely have some market power, this is an excellent op-
portunity for segmenting if the automakers can prevent their
customers in one country from selling to those in another.
Manufacturers could then segment their customers by country,
selling the same car at different prices in each country using
the price discrimination methods we’ve been discussing. This
practice would allow these manufacturers to earn higher pro?ts
and more producer surplus than they could by selling their cars
at the same price everywhere.
It turns out the auto companies have many options for pre-
venting resale across countries. First, they can print all manuals
and documents only in the country’s language. Swedish drivers
don’t want manuals in Greek, and vice versa. Second, they can
forbid servicing a car in a country other than the one in which
it was purchased. No one wants to get towed to Romania when
their car experiences problems in Spain. Third, they can punish dealers who sell cars to
people from a different country.
Economists Pinelopi Goldberg and Frank Verboven gathered evidence on car prices in
Europe to investigate this issue.
*
They found that the price of the same car could vary sub-
stantially across countries. For example, in 2003, the price of a VW Golf in Germany was
10% higher than in Portugal and almost 25% more expensive than in Greece.
Goldberg and Verboven concluded that some of the price differences across coun-
tries in Europe arose from differences in the taxation of autos, but that much of the price
theory and data
A
P
P
h
o
t
o
/
F
o
c
k
e
S
t
r
a
n
g
m
a
n
n
/
d
a
p
d
A VW Golf bought in Hannover, Germany costs more than
the same car bought in Portugal or Greece.
*
Pinelopi K. Goldberg and Frank Verboven, “Cross-Country Price Dispersion in the Euro Era: A Case Study of the Euro-
pean Car Market,” Economic Policy 19, no. 40 (October 2004): 483 – 521.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 413 11/5/12 4:01 PM
414 Part 3 Markets and Prices
10.4
Indirect/Second-Degree
Price Discrimination
When to Use It Indirect/Second-Degree Price Discrimination
1. The firm has market power and can prevent resale.
2. The firm’s customers have different demand curves.
3. The firm cannot directly identify which customers have which type of demand
before purchase.
We’ve seen how firms with market power can use direct price discrimination to increase
their producer surplus above the amount they could earn by charging only a single price.
The key is to charge higher prices to customers with relatively inelastic demand and
lower prices to those with more elastic demand. However, being able to directly observe
a customer’s demand type before purchase (as required with direct price discrimination)
is often difficult. A firm might know that its customers have different price sensitivities,
but it may not be able to tell to which group any particular customer belongs.
Even without this knowledge, a firm can still earn extra producer surplus through
price discrimination by using a pricing strategy called indirect price discrimination,
also known as second-degree price discrimination. In this pricing strategy, a firm
gives its customers various pricing choices and allows the customers to choose among
them.
There are many different kinds of indirect price discrimination techniques a company
can use. The principle that underlies all of them, however, is the need to set up the
pricing options to convince customers to pick the “right” choice; that is, to purchase
the option meant for their group rather than another option for a different group. For
example, airlines choose ticket rules and prices so that business travelers with inelastic
demand pay more, on average, for their tickets than leisure travelers with relatively
more elastic demand. At the same time, however, the airline wants to keep business
travelers from deciding that tickets meant for them are too expensive and instead buy-
ing up cheaper tickets intended for leisure travelers.
Indirect Price Discrimination through
Quantity Discounts
The most basic type of indirect price discrimination is the quantity discount, a pricing
strategy in which customers who buy larger quantities of a good pay a lower per-unit
price. For quantity discounting to work, customers who purchase larger quantities of a
product need to have relatively more elastic demands than consumers who buy smaller
quantities. If the consumers in the market do not have these elasticity characteristics,
difference was due to basic direct price discrimination by segmenting. The auto firms were
varying their markups depending on the conditions of local demand. The VW Golf pricing
patterns are consistent with the theory that demand in Germany is less elastic than in Por-
tugal or Greece, so VW charged its German customers more.
Goldberg and Verboven had some good news for European consumers (especially those
in high-demand countries), though. They uncovered clear evidence that, as Europe has
become more economically integrated, it has been much more difficult for car sellers to
prevent resale or arbitrage across boundaries and the price differences have narrowed.
indirect price
discrimination
(second-degree price
discrimination)
A pricing strategy in which
customers pick among a
variety of pricing options
offered by the ?rm.
quantity discount
The practice of charging
a lower per-unit price to
customers who buy larger
quantities.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 414 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 415
the firm would be trying to find a way to raise prices on the people who buy greater
quantities, the opposite of a quantity discount.
To illustrate the idea, let’s say there are two types of customers of the online broker-
age house E*TRADE. One type of customer is not very interested in trading stocks.
Because of this, these customers don’t have a big incentive to shop across different
online trading houses in search of lower commission rates (the fees they pay a broker-
age firm to facilitate a trade). Thus, their demands are relatively inelastic with respect
to the commission charged. The demand curve for uninterested traders is D
u
in panel a
of Figure 10.6. The other type of customer is obsessed with trading stocks. Because
these individuals trade many times each day, they are very sensitive to the commis-
sion rate. Thus, their demands are relatively elastic with respect to the commission.
The demand curve for these obsessed traders is shown as D
o
in panel b. The marginal
revenue curves for each group are MR
u
and MR
o
, respectively. The marginal cost is
the same for both groups.
E*TRADE would like to charge higher commissions to the uninterested traders with
an inelastic demand than it charges the obsessed traders with the more elastic demand.
This third-degree price discrimination (segmenting) would bring E*TRADE more pro-
ducer surplus, but the company cannot pursue this strategy because it cannot tell which
type of trader each person is when she signs up for an account. What E*TRADE does
know, however, is what the demand curves of the two groups look like, even if it can’t
identify to which group any given trader belongs. Based on the demand curve D
u
, for
example, E*TRADE would want to set its standard profit-maximizing quantity and price
(commission per trade) for uninterested traders where MR
u
equals MC: For Q
u
trades
per month, E*TRADE would charge uninterested traders $30 per trade. For obsessed
traders, E*TRADE would like to follow the same procedure and charge them a price of
$9 per trade; at that commission, the obsessed traders would make Q
o
trades per month.
(a) The online brokerage company E*TRADE has two
types of customers: uninterested traders and obsessed
traders. Uninterested traders have a relatively inelastic
demand curve D
u
. E*TRADE would like to charge un-
interested traders the profit-maximizing commission rate
P
u
= $30 per trade and sell quantity Q
u
trades per month.
(b) Obsessed traders have a relatively elastic demand curve
D
o
. E*TRADE would like to charge them the lower com-
mission rate P
o
= $9 per trade. Although E*TRADE cannot
directly identify which group any particular trader belongs
to, it can set different prices for the two groups using a
quantity discount by requiring traders to make at least Q
o
trades per month to get a reduced commission rate.
Figure 10.6 Quantity Discounts at E*TRADE
Quantity of trades
(per month)
Price
($/trade)
0
Q
u
P
u
= $30
(a) Uninterested traders (b) Obsessed traders
MC
MR
u
D
u
Quantity of trades
(per month)
Price
($/trade)
0
Q
o
P
o
= $9
MC
MR
o
D
o
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 415 11/5/12 4:01 PM
416 Part 3 Markets and Prices
If E*TRADE could segment the market, it would charge each group P
u
and P
o
per trade, and at those prices, each group would make Q
u
and Q
o
trades per month.
However, E*TRADE can’t directly assign different commission rates to different trad-
ers. And it can’t just offer new customers a choice of whether to pay $30 or $9 com-
missions no matter how much or little they trade because every customer would choose
the cheaper option. What can E*TRADE do to take as much of each trader’s surplus
for itself? Rather than offer all customers a $9 per trade commission, E*TRADE can
tie that commission rate to a requirement that the customer make at least Q
o
trades
per month. For customers who do not want to make at least Q
o
trades per month,
E*TRADE can offer a $30 per trade commission plan that allows them to trade as little
or much as they’d like in one month.
The idea behind this strategy is that an obsessed trader, who demands a high quan-
tity of trades and has a more elastic demand, will choose the $9 plan that requires a
purchase of at least Q
o
trades each month. An uninterested trader, on the other hand,
will choose the $30 per trade plan. In other words, traders from both groups will sort
themselves into the price and quantity combinations designed for them, even though
E*TRADE cannot directly identify either type. This is the essence of any kind of suc-
cessful indirect price discrimination strategy: The firm must set its prices so that a
customer doesn’t try to fake her demand type and buy the package meant for another
customer type. We discuss this requirement for the successful implementation of all
indirect price discrimination (including quantity discounts) next.
Incentive Compatibility The plan to charge uninterested traders a higher com-
mission than obsessed traders is logical, but for such a plan to work well and allow
E*TRADE to reap the maximum producer surplus available to it, E*TRADE needs to
make sure that the uninterested trader won’t want to switch from her $30/ Q
u
package
to the $9/ Q
o
package designed for the obsessed traders. That is, the $9 commission deal
can’t be so good that the uninterested trader will make extra trades just to obtain the
lower price. E*TRADE has to be sure that the uninterested trader’s consumer surplus is
bigger with the $30 per trade package than with the $9 package that requires a purchase
of at least Q
o
trades. The offers need to be internally consistent so that each type of
buyer actually chooses the offer designed for it.
Economists have a term for this type of internal consistency: incentive
compatibility. In this example, the two packages are incentive compatible if:
1. An uninterested trader prefers the $30 package over the $9 package (and she will make
this choice if the $30 package gives her greater consumer surplus than the $9 package).
2. An obsessed trader prefers the $9 package because it offers her more consumer surplus
than the $30 package.
Let’s see whether this set of offers is incentive compatible. First, we need to show that
the uninterested trader’s consumer surplus from trades at $30 each is greater than her
surplus from making Q
o
trades at $9 each. Finding the consumer surplus from the first
offer is familiar territory. As shown in Figure 10.7, at a price of $30 per trade, an unin-
terested trader makes quantity Q
u
trades, and the consumer surplus is the area under the
uninterested trader’s demand curve and above the $30 price. This is triangle A in panel a.
Finding the uninterested trader’s consumer surplus for the $9 package offer is a
bit trickier. The first thing we need to do is put the $9 package’s price and quantity
combination in the diagram showing the demand for trades of an uninterested trader.
Call this point X, as shown in panel a. Notice that point X lies above the uninterested
trader’s demand curve. That means if an uninterested trader were to make trade num-
ber Q
o
(at a commission of $9), she would actually lose consumer surplus by doing so.
At a price of $9, an uninterested trader really only wishes to purchase Q
max
trades, the
quantity demanded at that price.
The fact that Q
max
is less than Q
o
implies that the uninterested trader’s willingness
to pay for the trades between Q
max
and Q
o
is lower than the $9 she would have to pay
incentive
compatibility
The requirement under an
indirect price discrimina-
tion strategy that the price
offered to each consumer
group is chosen by that
group.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 416 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 417
for them. In fact, all trades for which her demand curve (which indicates her willingness
to pay) lies below $9 will result in a loss of consumer surplus. In panel a, these surplus-
destroying trades are those between Q
max
and Q
o
, and the total consumer surplus lost
is the area labeled L. (The demand curve just runs along the horizontal axis once it
hits the axis, because willingness to pay for higher quantities is zero.) That area is the
downside for an uninterested trader accepting the lower-commission offer. There is an
upside, however. The first Q
max
trades she conducts create consumer surplus, area A
+ B in the figure. This consumer surplus is quite a bit larger than her surplus under
the $30 per trade offer (area A) because the price is so much lower. The net consumer
surplus an uninterested trader gets from taking the $9 package offer is therefore area
A + area B – area L.
Comparing the uninterested trader’s consumer surpluses from the two offers, we can
now see that she will choose the $30 per trade offer over the $9 package offer if
area A > area A + area B – area L
0 > area B – area L
area B < area L
That is, an uninterested trader will take the offer designed for her ($30 per trade) if the
extra consumer surplus she would obtain from the lower commission rate (area B) is
smaller than the loss she suffers from having to buy a larger quantity than she would
have otherwise at the lower offered price (area L).
For uninterested traders, we have outlined under what conditions the offers are
incentive compatible. Will an obsessed trader choose the $9 package meant for her?
(a) Before charging a quantity discount to obsessed trad-
ers, E*TRADE needs to ensure that its pricing strategy
is incentive compatible. At P
u
= $30 per trade, uninter-
ested traders make Q
u
trades and receive surplus A. At
the quantity and price offered to obsessed traders ( Q
o
, P
o
),
their surplus is reduced by area L but increases by
area B. Uninterested traders will choose to pay $30 per
trade if area B is greater than area L.
(b) Under the pricing policy for uninterested traders,
obsessed traders would have to pay both a higher price
( P
u
= $30 > P
u
= $9) and make fewer trades per month
( Q
o
> Q
u
). Therefore, the quantity discount is incentive-
compatible for these traders.
Figure 10.7 Incentive Compatibility
Quantity
of trades
(per month)
Price
($/trade)
0
Q
u
Q
max
Q
o
P
u
= $30
P
o
= 9
(a) Uninterested traders (b) Obsessed traders
MC
A
B
L
X
D
u Quantity
of trades
(per month)
Price
($/trade)
0
Q
o
P
o
= $9
MC
D
o
Consumer surplus at P
u
= A
Consumer surplus at P
o
= A + B – L
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 417 11/5/12 4:01 PM
418 Part 3 Markets and Prices
We know that at a commission rate of $9 per trade, an obsessed trader earns con-
sumer surplus on every trade up to Q
o
; she is happy to trade that much at that price.
Taking the $30 offer would require her to make a smaller quantity of trades than Q
o
at a
higher price per unit. Having to consume a smaller quantity even holding the price fixed
at $9 per trade would make an obsessed trader worse off, because it would eliminate
surplus-creating trades she would have made otherwise at that price. Even worse, how-
ever, would be that the trader would have to pay $30 instead of $9 for each of the trades
she did make. Both the quantity restriction and the increase in price reduce the obsessed
trader’s consumer surplus. Thus, the $9 package offer is better for obsessed traders.
We saw that an uninterested trader also faces a higher price and lower quantity if she
takes the $30 per trade offer instead of the $9 package. So, why isn’t an uninterested trader
automatically worse off by taking the $30 offer as is an obsessed trader? The reason is that
if an uninterested trader faced a price of $9 per trade but got to choose how many trades
she made, she would never choose to make Q
o
trades. She would only choose to make Q
max,
the quantity of trades demanded at a price of $9 per trade. Any trades between Q
max
and
Q
o
destroy consumer surplus for an uninterested trader because the price is higher than
her willingness to pay. It is the potential consumer surplus-destroying trades tied to the $9
package that make it likely that an uninterested trader would prefer the $30 offer.
10.3 ?gure it out
Suppose you are a pricing analyst for MegaDat
Corporation, a firm that recently developed a new
software program for data analysis. You have two
types of clients who use your product. Type A’s
inverse demand for your software is P = 120 – 10Q,
where Q represents users and P is in dollars per user.
Type B’s inverse demand is P = 60 – 2Q. Assume
that your firm faces a constant marginal cost of
$20 per user to install and set up this software.
a. If you can tell which type of buyer is buying
the product before a purchase is made, what prices
will you charge each type?
b. Suppose instead that you cannot tell which type
of buyer the client is until after the purchase. Suggest
a possible way to use quantity discounts to have buyers
self-select into the pricing scheme set up for them.
c. Determine whether the pricing scheme you
determined in part (b) is incentive-compatible.
Solution:
a. To maximize profit, set MR = MC for each
type. Therefore, we first need to solve for the mar-
ginal revenue curves for each type. Because we have
linear inverse demand curves, we know that the MR
curves will have the same vertical intercept but twice
the slope. This means that MR = 120 – 20Q for
Type A buyers and MR = 60 – 4Q for Type B
buyers. Now set MR = MC to find the
profit-maximizing quantity for each type:
For Type A:
120 – 20 Q
A
= 20
20 Q
A
= 100
Q
A
= 5
For Type B:
60 – 4 Q
B
= 20
4 Q
B
= 40
Q
B
= 10
At these quantities, the prices will be
For Type A:
P
A
= 120 – 10 Q
A
= 120 – 10(5)
= $70
For Type B:
P
B
= 60 – 2 Q
B
= 60 – 2(10)
= $40
b. The firm could charge $70 per user for a
package where the buyer can purchase any quantity
she wishes and a price of $40 for any buyer willing to
purchase 10 or more units.
c. This plan is incentive-compatible for Type B
users. They are willing to continue to purchase Q = 10
at a price of $40 each.
For a Type A consumer, we need to consider the
amount of consumer surplus she receives under each
scheme. We can do this with the help of a diagram
showing the Type A demand curve and the two
prices, $70 and $40.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 418 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 419
Indirect Price Discrimination through Versioning
Airline tickets are a classic example of what we call versioning—offering a range of
products that are all varieties of the same core product. Airlines have a group of business
travel customers who are not very sensitive to prices and a group of leisure travelers who
are highly sensitive to price. Airlines want to charge different prices to the two passenger
groups, but they can’t tell who is flying on business when a customer buys a ticket. So, the
airlines instead offer different versions of the product (tickets on a given flight) available at
different prices. The cheaper version, with many restrictions, is intended for leisure travel-
ers who buy generally well in advance of the travel date, stay over a Saturday night, and
book a round-trip flight. The more expensive version has fewer restrictions and is intended
D
B
C
A
Quantity of software (users)
Price
($/user)
0
$120
40
20
70
8 5 10
L
At a price of $70, a Type A buyer would choose to
purchase 5 units. Consumer surplus would equal area
A, the area below the demand curve but above price.
If a Type A buyer were to opt to purchase the
other package (10 units at a price of $40 each), her
consumer surplus would be the area above the price
and below demand (areas A + B + C), but she
would also lose consumer surplus because she would
be buying units that she values less than the price of
$40. This would be area L in the diagram.
Thus, opting for the quantity discount would
change the Type A buyer’s consumer surplus by
area B + area C – area L. The $40 10-unit package
would be incentive-compatible only if area L >
area B + area C. Let’s calculate those values:
Area B = base × height
= (5)($70 – $40)
= (5)($30)
= $150
To calculate area C, we need to determine the base
of the triangle. This means that we need to know the
quantity at which the Type A buyer’s willingness to
pay is exactly $40:
P = 120 – 10Q
40 = 120 – 10Q
10Q = 80
Q = 8
Area C =
1
_
2
× base × height
= (0.5)(8 – 5)($70 – $40)
= (0.5)(3)($30)
= $45
Therefore, area B + area C = $150 + $45 = $195.
To calculate area L, we need to be able to deter-
mine the height of the triangle. To do so, we need
the price at which a Type A buyer would be willing
to purchase Q = 10 units:
P = 120 – 10Q
= 120 – 10(10)
= 120 – 100
= $20
Area L =
1
_
2
× base × height
= (0.5)(10 – 8)($40 – $20)
= (0.5)(2)($20)
= $20
So, we know that area B + area C = $150 + $45 =
$195 and area L = $20.
Because area A + area B > area L, the $40
10-unit pricing scheme is not incentive-compatible
for Type A buyers. These buyers will want to receive
the quantity discount and will purchase 10 units at
a price of $40 each. Thus, this pricing scheme would
not be successful at making the buyers self-select into
the pricing scheme established for their types.
versioning
A pricing strategy in which
the ?rm offers different
product options designed
to attract different types of
consumers.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 419 11/5/12 4:01 PM
420 Part 3 Markets and Prices
for business travelers who generally don’t like spending a weekend away from home, often
need to buy their tickets at the last minute, and may choose to purchase a one-way flight
for each segment to provide them with added flexibility. By offering two versions of tickets
for a given flight, the airline attempts to make the two types of customers sort themselves
(and by doing so, the airline captures more producer surplus).
For this scheme to work, the airlines need to make sure the prices of each version are
incentive compatible. If the airline sets the prices for each group based on the markup
formula it would use with direct price discrimination, the restricted-travel version might
be too cheap relative to the ticket with fewer restrictions. In this case, business travelers
might actually bite the bullet and start planning trips earlier or stay at their destination
over the weekend. In some cases, business travelers might try to skirt the rules altogether.
For example, it’s possible to avoid the Saturday stay requirement by buying what is
known as “back-to-back” tickets. For example, a business traveler wishing to fly from
Philadelphia to Orlando and back for a Wednesday meeting might buy one Philadelphia-
Orlando round-trip with a departure on Wednesday morning and a return on Sunday, and
an Orlando-Philadelphia round-trip with a Wednesday evening departure and a Sunday
return. The traveler would only use the first leg of each trip. As you might expect, this
kind of behavior is intensely hated by the airlines, which try to forbid it in every way they
can, but, basically, it’s just the market’s normal response to indirect price discrimination.
Versioning and Price-Cost Margins With versioning, the different versions’
marginal costs do not need to be the same. All that is necessary for versioning to work
is for the markup of price over marginal cost to be bigger for the versions bought by
customers with less elastic demand.
Consider the example of an automaker like Toyota, which sells a lot of midsize sedans.
Some of Toyota’s buyers in this segment will not be very price-sensitive. Maybe they are
status-conscious, or just have a particular taste for cars with many fancy features. Oth-
ers will be more price-sensitive. If Toyota could tell which type of customer was which
when they walked through the door, Toyota could just use direct price discrimination and
charge different prices according to the strategy we discussed in Section 10.3. In reality,
however, it’s not always easy to tell what type of customer comes through the door at
any particular time. So, Toyota uses indirect price discrimination and designs two differ-
ent versions of the car that it can sell at different markups, hoping to induce buyers to
segment themselves based on their sensitivity to price and tastes for features.
For example, Toyota makes the Camry, one of the highest-selling cars in the world. It
sells, nicely equipped, for about $25,000 in the United States. But Toyota also makes the
Lexus ES 350, which is built on the same platform and in the same plant as the Camry. It
is similar in many ways to the Camry but is more luxurious. Think of the ES 350 as being
a Camry but with a sun roof, dual-zone climate control, a GPS navigation system, xenon
headlights, and a premium stereo system. The ES 350 sells for around $38,000.
While a sunroof, xenon headlights, and all those extra options raise Toyota’s marginal
cost of producing an ES 350, it’s unlikely that this increase in marginal cost would amount
to $13,000 per car. Toyota charges more than the cost difference because the different ver-
sions split its customers into groups based
on their price sensitivities. The Lexus group
has less elastic demand, so Toyota’s markup
over marginal cost can be higher, just like
the Saturday-night stay splits an airline’s
customers into leisure and business travelers.
To be incentive compatible, Toyota can’t
make the deal for the cheap version so good
that it convinces the luxury customers to pur-
chase Camrys instead. Quantitatively, think
of it the following way. Suppose there are just
two types of customers whose willingness to
pay for each car is listed in Table 10.1.
Toyota Camry Lexus ES 350
Budget consumer $27,000 $30,000
Luxury consumer $28,000 $42,000
Table 10.1 Consumer Valuations for Camrys
and ES 350s
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 420 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 421
Notice that both consumers believe the Lexus is worth more than the Camry. It’s
not that Toyota has made a version that one group likes and the other doesn’t. The
budget consumers value a Lexus more than a Toyota, but not very much more: $30,000
versus $27,000. The luxury consumers, however, value the ES 350 a lot more than the
Camry: $42,000 versus $28,000.
If Toyota prices the Camry at $25,000 and the Lexus ES 350 at $38,000, the budget
consumers get $2,000 of consumer surplus from buying the Camry and –$8,000 from buy-
ing the Lexus (it costs more than they value it), so they will buy the Camry. The luxury
consumers get $3,000 of surplus from buying the Camry and $4,000 from the Lexus, so
they go with the Lexus. Each group chooses the version designed to take advantage of
the nature of their demand curves. That means these prices are incentive compatible.
What would happen if Toyota priced the Lexus at $40,000 rather than $38,000?
The budget consumers would still buy the Camry. Now, however, the status consumers
would get more consumer surplus from buying the Camry ($3,000) than from buying
the Lexus ($2,000), so they would also decide to buy the Camry. That $2,000 price
increase for the Lexus would cause Toyota to lose $13,000 (losing a sale of a $38,000
Lexus at the old price for a $25,000 Camry instead) for each luxury consumer. (Or
worse: The luxury consumers might go buy another automaker’s luxury car.) By charg-
ing the group with the less elastic demand too high a price, Toyota would not be setting
incentive-compatible prices and its attempt at indirect price discrimination would fail.
One detail that is important to note is that it is not the mere existence of custom-
ers with inelastic demand that allows Toyota (or any other firm) to indirectly price-
discriminate with versioning. What is required is that differences exist in demand
elasticities across customer groups. If different consumer groups had the same price
elasticities of demand, even if relatively inelastic, then designing versions specifically
for each group will not help a firm price discriminate. Automakers offer cars with dif-
ferent paint colors, for example, but there is rarely price discrimination based on paint
color because the price sensitivities of people who like blue cars and silver cars are
no different.
There is virtually no limit to the kinds of versioning a company can implement to
get its customers to self-select into groups based on their price sensitivities. Now that
you understand this kind of price discrimination, you will start to see it everywhere
you look. Some firms offer “enhanced” features, such as the way Intuit does with its
TurboTax software. It has a bare-bones version that is actually free online, versions
with special Q&A features, and a small business application package that includes the
ability to handle more complex structures like partnerships. The marginal cost differ-
ence between editions is trivial, but by offering “bells and whistles” versions, Intuit is
able to get the less price-sensitive business customers to pay more.
Indirect Price Discrimination through Coupons
Coupons are also a form of indirect price discrimination. Retailers would like to charge
shoppers who have less elastic demands more for products while setting a lower price
for consumers who are more sensitive to price. Again, however, they have no way of
directly identifying and separating these different groups when they buy, so they have
to get the groups to do it themselves. Coupons are the device they use to do so.
The key to the way coupons work is that the trouble of using coupons — searching
for the right site or deal online, combing through junk mail, or searching through news-
paper inserts — is more likely to be borne by consumers who have more elastic demand.
Because both the willingness to do the work clipping the coupons and the willingness
to shop around for cheaper groceries are determined by the consumers’ perceived value
of time, coupon clipping and the price elasticity of demand are likely to be correlated.
That way, the people who actually end up getting a price discount from a coupon are
those consumers with more elastic demand — exactly the group to whom the retailers
would like to offer lower prices. The shoppers who are less sensitive to price end up
paying the higher, undiscounted price.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 421 11/5/12 4:01 PM
422 Part 3 Markets and Prices
That’s why coupons usually aren’t right next to (or especially already attached to)
the items to which they apply. If they were, it would be easy for even the shoppers with
less elastic demand to use them, and everyone would receive the discount. The fact that
firms require consumers to expend a little effort to use a coupon is not coincidence; it
is exactly the point. Mail-in rebates work on the same principle: Only those consumers
willing to go through the trouble of filling out the form and sending it in — presumably
the most price-sensitive ones — will receive the discount.
4
10.5 Bundling
When to Use It Bundling
1. A firm has market power and can prevent resale.
2. A firm sells a second product and consumers’ demand for that product is negatively
correlated with their demand for the first product.
Another indirect price discrimination strategy that firms with market power can use
to increase their producer surplus over the standard monopoly pricing surplus is called
bundling. This strategy involves putting together two or more products that a firm
produces and selling them as a single package with its own price.
When you subscribe to cable or satellite television, for example, you are buying a
bundled good. You pay a single monthly fee for service, and the cable or satellite com-
pany delivers a number of networks together. You don’t pick and choose every channel
individually. For your $45 per month, you get, say, 90 channels rather than paying $6
per month for ESPN, $4 a month for MTV, and so on.
Sometimes, things can be bundled just because people really prefer buying things
together. Think about a pair of basketball shoes. Although shoemakers could sell shoes
individually, there really isn’t much demand for single shoes or for mixing a Nike basket-
ball shoe for the left foot with an Under Armour shoe for the right. People want to buy
both shoes together. This sort of bundling, which occurs because the goods are strong
complements to one another (i.e., one good raises the marginal utility of the other), is
not a price discrimination strategy. Nike and Under Armour would bundle their left and
right shoes together even if they operated in a perfectly competitive market.
In this chapter, we’re interested in ways that companies can use bundling as a
way to price discriminate. To explain how bundling can be a strategic pricing deci-
sion, it is vital that we first clear up an extremely common misconception. Bundling
will generally not allow a company with market power in one product to leverage
its market power into a second product. To illustrate what we mean, let’s look at a
specific example.
Take a cable company providing TV channels to your home. To make it easy, let’s
say there are only two cable networks: ESPN and the soap opera network SOAPnet
(ESPN is among the most watched cable networks, and SOAPnet is not). Why would
the cable company force you to buy both as a bundle for some price rather than just
sell them separately?
At first glance, people tend to think it’s a way for the cable company to leverage
market power/high demand for ESPN to force people to pay more for the lesser product
(SOAPnet). But this “forcing it down their throat” argument usually does not make
sense. To see why, suppose there are two customers (Jack and Dakota) in the market.
4
That said, there is occasionally a coupon right next to (or even attached to) an item. In this case, the
point of the coupon is not to price discriminate as much as it is to advertise. It’s essentially a little
sign that says, “Buy me . . . I’m cheaper than usual.”
bundling
A pricing strategy in which
the ?rm sells two or more
products together at a
single price.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 422 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 423
Both like ESPN a lot and SOAPnet less, as reflected in
Table 10.2. Jack values ESPN at $9 per month and Dakota
values it at $10 per month. Jack values SOAPnet at $1 per
month, while Dakota values it at $1.50. For simplicity, let’s
assume the marginal cost of supplying the networks is zero.
Does the cable company raise its producer surplus by
bundling the prized ESPN with SOAPnet? If it sells the
channels separately, it would have to price each channel at
the lower of the two customers’ valuations for each channel
($9.00 for ESPN and $1.00 for SOAPnet). Otherwise, the
company would sell to only the one customer and would
lose the revenue from the other.
5
Thus, it sells ESPN for
$9 per month and SOAPnet for $1 per month, earning a
total surplus of $20 per month (2 × $9) + (2 × $1) from selling the channels separately.
Now suppose the cable company sells the channels as a bundle. The combined value
the customers put on the bundle ($10.00 per month for Jack and $11.50 for Dakota)
means the company will again set the price at the lower valuation so it won’t lose half
of the market. It therefore prices the bundle at $10 and sells it to both customers. This
yields a surplus of (2 × $10), or $20 per month, the same amount it earned selling the
networks separately. Bundling has not raised the firm’s surplus.
Furthermore, if the company combines ESPN with something customers don’t actu-
ally want at all (say, e.g., that the valuation on SOAPnet was zero or even negative),
then the amount that customers would be willing to pay for that network plus ESPN
would be that much lower. As a general matter, then, a company can’t make extra
money by attaching a highly desired product to an undesired one.
How should a firm bundle products to make more producer surplus? Suppose that,
instead of the valuations being what they are in Table 10.2, the two valuations for
SOAPnet are switched. Both customers value ESPN far more, but now Jack has a higher
valuation for SOAPnet ($1.50 per month) than does Dakota ($1.00). The key thing that
has changed, as will become clear in a minute, is that the willingness to pay for the two
goods is now negatively correlated across the consumers. This means that one of the
customers has a higher willingness to pay for one channel than the other customer, but a
lower willingness to pay for the other channel. In our example, Jack has lower willingness
to pay for ESPN than Dakota but greater demand for SOAPnet, as shown in Table 10.3.
With this change, the firm receives more producer surplus using the bundling strategy.
If the cable company sells the channels separately, the calculation is the same as before:
ESPN for $9 per month, SOAPnet for $1, and earns a total of $20 of surplus per month.
If the firm bundles the channels, however, it can sell the package to both customers for
$10.50 per month. This earns the company (2 × $10.50) or
$21 of producer surplus per month, more than the $20 per
month from selling the channels separately.
The reason why bundling works in the second scenario
is the negative correlation between the two customers’ will-
ingness to pay, which occurs because Dakota values one
part of the bundle (ESPN) more than Jack, while Jack
values SOAPnet more than Dakota. If the cable company
wants to sell to the entire market, it can only set a price
equal to the smaller of the two customers’ willingness to
pay, whether pricing separately or as a bundle. In the first
example with positively correlated demand (when Dakota
had a higher willingness to pay for both channels), the
ESPN SOAPnet Bundle
Jack $9.00 $1.50 $10.50
Dakota $10.00 $1.00 $11.00
Table 10.3 Negatively Correlated
Valuations per
Subscriber-Month
5
In reality, most network owners like Disney, which owns ESPN and SOAPnet, do not own the cable
company, so they actually bundle the channels they sell to the cable company that then passes along
that bundle to you. The point is the same, however.
ESPN SOAPnet Bundle
Jack $9.00 $1.00 $10.00
Dakota $10.00 $1.50 $11.50
Table 10.2 Positively Correlated
Valuations per
Subscriber-Month
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 423 11/5/12 4:01 PM
424 Part 3 Markets and Prices
lower of the customers’ valuations for the bundle ($10 per subscriber for Jack) is smaller
by $1.50 than the larger valuation ($11.50 per month for Dakota) because it reflects
Jack’s lower valuations for both channels. Therefore, if the cable company wants to sell
the channels as a bundle, it must offer Dakota a discount that embodies the fact that Jack
has a lower willingness to pay for both channels. As a result, the cable company does no
better than having sold the channels separately.
With a negative correlation of demands across customers, there is less variation (only
$0.50) in each customer’s willingness to pay for the bundle: $10.50 per month for Jack
and $11.00 per month for Dakota. This reduced variation means the cable company
doesn’t need to give as large a discount to Dakota to sell to both customers. Bundling
has reduced the difference in total willingness to pay across the customers. What’s im-
portant is that the smaller of the two combined valuations is larger when the channel
demands are negatively correlated. Jack will pay $10.50 instead of only $10, which al-
lows the company to raise its price. In this way, bundling allows sellers to “smooth out”
variations in customers’ demands, raises the prices sellers can charge for their bundled
products, and increases the amount of surplus they can extract.
Mixed Bundling
The previous example shows why a firm might choose to sell two products as a bundle
instead of separately. Sometimes, however, firms simultaneously offer the products
separately and as a bundle and then let the consumer choose which to buy. This indi-
rect pricing strategy is called mixed bundling. The Extra Value Meals at McDonald’s
include a sandwich, fries, and a drink at one price. McDonald’s also offers these three
things individually. This is where mixed bundling acts as a form of indirect price dis-
crimination because the firm offers different choices and lets customers sort themselves
in ways that increase producer surplus.
Mixed bundling is a lot like the bundling strategy we’ve just discussed (offering only
the bundle is often called pure bundling). It is useful in the same type of situations, but
is better than pure bundling when the marginal cost of producing some of the components
is high enough that it makes sense to let some customers opt out of buying the entire
bundle.
Returning to our cable network example, let’s suppose there are four customers and
that they value the networks according to Table 10.4. The willingness to pay is negatively
correlated across the networks, so we know bundling can work as a pricing strategy.
Now suppose instead of marginal costs being zero, the marginal cost of supplying ESPN
is $6.00 per month and SOAPnet is $1.00 per month. Therefore, the marginal cost of pro-
ducing the bundled package is $7.00. If the cable company sells the bundle for $12.15 (the
minimum valuation of the bundle across
the customers), it will sell the bundle to all
four customers. Subtracting costs, this will
net a per-customer producer surplus of $5.15
per month for a total of (4 × $5.15), or $20.60.
But look more closely at Penny and Shel-
don. Their relative values for the two channels
are extreme. Penny really values ESPN and
barely values SOAPnet, while the opposite
is true for Sheldon. And crucially, the value
they put on one of these channels is below
the marginal cost of supplying it: SOAPnet
for Penny and ESPN for Sheldon. As we will
see, in these cases it makes sense for the cable
company to try to split these customers off
from the bundle, because it does not want to
supply channels to customers who value them
at less than the cost of providing them.
ESPN
(MC = $6)
SOAPnet
(MC = $1)
Bundle
(MC = $7)
Penny $12.00 $0.50 $12.50
Leonard $11.00 $1.15 $12.15
Raj $9.00 $3.15 $12.15
Sheldon $5.00 $7.75 $12.75
Table 10.4 Negatively Correlated Valuations
When the Marginal Cost Exceeds
the Valuation for Some Customers
mixed bundling
A type of bundling in which
the ?rm simultaneously of-
fers consumers the choice
of buying two or more
products separately or as
a bundle.
pure bundling
A type of bundling in which
the ?rm offers the products
only as a bundle.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 424 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 425
Figuring out the right mixed bundling strategy is slightly complicated because of
incentive compatibility, so we’ll take it one step at a time. Given the issues we just dis-
cussed, the cable company would like to end up selling the bundle to Leonard and Raj,
only ESPN to Penny, and only SOAPnet to Sheldon. Because both Leonard and
Raj value the bundle at $12.15 per month, that’s a reasonable starting point for think-
ing about the price of the bundle. If this is the price of the bundle, however, the com-
pany can’t charge Sheldon his full $7.75 valuation for SOAPnet. If it tried to, Sheldon
would choose the bundle instead because it would give him 60 cents more consumer
surplus ($12.75 – $12.15) than if he bought only SOAPnet (consumer surplus of zero if
priced at $7.75). A price of $7.75 for SOAPnet is therefore not incentive compatible. To
set an incentive-compatible price for SOAPnet, the cable company has to leave Sheldon
with at least 60 cents of consumer surplus per month. Thus, the incentive-compatible
price for the purchase of SOAPnet alone would be $7.75 – $0.60, or $7.15 per month.
And because Leonard and Raj value SOAPnet at less than $7.15, both will buy the
bundle rather than take the SOAPnet-only option, so incentive compatibility holds in
the other direction, too.
We can do the same type of calculations with ESPN and Penny. The cable company
can’t charge $12.00 for ESPN alone, because Penny would opt for the bundle to get 35 cents
($12.50 – $12.15) of consumer surplus rather than zero from buying ESPN at $12.00. So, the
company has to leave Penny with at least 35 cents of surplus from buying just ESPN. The
highest price that will achieve this is $12.00 – $0.35, or $11.65. Again, offering this option won’t
move Leonard and Raj away from the bundle, because both value ESPN at less than $11.65.
So with those three prices — ESPN alone for $11.65, SOAPnet alone for $7.15, and
the bundle for $12.15 — the cable company will sell two bundles (to Leonard and Raj)
to earn a producer surplus (subtracting out the marginal costs) of $5.15 per month
for each bundle. Additionally, it will sell ESPN alone to Penny to earn a surplus of
$11.65 – $6.00 = $5.65 and SOAPnet alone to Sheldon for a surplus of $7.15 – $1.00 =
$6.15. The total monthly producer surplus from using mixed bundling is therefore
(2 × $5.15) + $5.65 + $6.15 = $22.10. That is more than the $20.60 per month the
cable company would make by using pure bundling.
Producer surplus has increased because the cable company has saved itself the trou-
ble of delivering a product to a customer who values it at less than it costs to produce.
10.4 ?gure it out
Fit Club, Inc. is a health club that offers two types of equipment: weight machines and a
swimming pool. There are currently three customers (Abe, Betty, and Chris), whose will-
ingness to pay for using each type of equipment per month is listed in the table below:
Willingness to Pay (per month)
WEIGHT MACHINES INDOOR POOL
Abe $60 $50
Betty $50 $125
Chris $25 $140
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 425 11/5/12 4:01 PM
426 Part 3 Markets and Prices
The weight room and the swimming pool each have a constant marginal cost of $20 per
month. In the case of the pool, the marginal cost is the price of the water and chemicals
used, while the marginal cost of the weight machines is the cost of cleaning and maintain-
ing them. Each customer is considering monthly access to each type of equipment, and the
firm has to decide what type of membership package to offer the customers.
a What price will the firm charge for each product if it wishes to sell a health club
membership to all three customers? What is the firm’s producer surplus if it sells separate
access to the weight room and the pool room at these prices?
b. What price will the firm charge for a bundle of access to both the weight room
and the swimming pool if it wishes to sell the bundle to all three customers? How much
producer surplus will Fit Club, Inc. earn in this case?
c. Suppose the firm is considering offering its customers a choice to either purchase
access to the weight room and the swimming pool separately at a price of $60 for the weight
machine and $140 for the pool, or to purchase a bundle at a price of $175. Which option will
each customer choose? How much producer surplus will Fit Club, Inc. earn in this situation?
Solution:
a. To sell access to the weight machines to all three customers, the health club must
charge a price no greater than $25, the lowest willingness to pay of the customers (Chris).
For the same reason, the price for the pool will be $50.
At these prices, the firm’s producer surplus for its sales of access to the weight ma-
chines will be
Producer surplus for weight machine = (Price – marginal cost) × quantity
= ($25 – $20) × 3
= ($5)(3) = $15
For access to the pool, producer surplus will be
Producer surplus for the pool = ($50 – $20) × 3
= ($30)(3) = $90
Total producer surplus will be $15 + $90 = $105.
b. To determine the price of the bundle, we need to calculate each buyer’s willingness
to pay for the bundle. This is done simply by summing the customers’ willingness to pay
for each product as shown in the table below:
Willingness to Pay (per month)
WEIGHT MACHINES INDOOR POOL BUNDLE
Abe $60 $50 = $60 + $50 = $110
Betty $50 $125 = $50 + $125 = $175
Chris $25 $140 = $25 + $140 = $165
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 426 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 427
10.6 Advanced Pricing Strategies
When to Use It Block Pricing and Two-Part Tariffs
1. The firm has market power and can prevent resale.
2. The firm’s customers may have either identical or different demand curves.
In the previous sections, we analyzed pricing strategies based on price discrimination,
the ability of a firm to charge more for units of output sold to those willing to pay more
and, as a result, extract producer surplus by departing from the single-price monopoly
pricing discussed in Chapter 9. In this section, we look at how firms with market power
can achieve that goal not by charging a given price per unit, but by varying unit prices
offered to the same customer or charging lump-sum fees on top of per-unit prices. We
start with a return to our discussion of quantity discounts.
So, the maximum price the health club can charge for its bundle (and still sell to all
three buyers) is $110. It will sell 3 bundles at this price. Therefore, its producer surplus
will be
Producer surplus for bundle = (price – marginal cost) × quantity
= ($110 – $40) × 3
= ($70)(3) = $210
c. We need to compare each buyer’s willingness to pay to the prices set for purchasing
access to each room separately and the price of the bundle.
Abe will only purchase a weight machine membership. His willingness to pay for the
pool is below the price of $140. The same is true for the bundle, which he values only at
$110. Therefore, the health club will only sell Abe access to the weight machines.
Betty will not be willing to buy either membership separately, because her willingness
to pay for each is below the set price. However, Betty’s willingness to pay for the bundle
($175) is exactly equal to the price, so she will purchase the bundle.
Chris will only purchase access to the indoor pool. His willingness to pay for weight
machines is only $25, far below the price of $60. Likewise, Chris is willing to pay at most
$165 for the bundle. Thus, the health club will only be able to sell pool access to Chris.
Total producer surplus will therefore be:
Producer surplus for weight machines = (price – marginal cost) × quantity
= ($60 – $20) × 1
= $40
Producer surplus for the pool = ($140 – $20) × 1
= $120
Producer surplus for bundle = ($175 – $40) × 1
= $135
Total producer surplus when the health club offers customers a choice of bundling or sepa-
rate prices is $40 + $120 + $135 = $295.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 427 11/5/12 4:01 PM
428 Part 3 Markets and Prices
Block Pricing
We call the strategy in which a firm reduces the price of a good if the customer buys
more of it block pricing. You see this sort of thing all the time. Buying a single 12-oz
can of Pepsi might cost $1, but a six-pack of 12-oz cans costs only $2.99. However, un-
like indirect price discrimination (such as quantity discounts), block pricing does not
require that buyers have different demand curves and price sensitivities. All buyers of
Pepsi may, in fact, have the same demand curve, but Pepsi could still gain producer
surplus from providing buyers with an option to buy a larger quantity of soda at a
lower price.
Consider Figure 10.8, which shows a demand curve for Walmart’s photo holiday
cards. Here, we assume this is the demand curve of just one customer (or we could
suppose all customers have this same demand curve), so the firm is not trying to price-
discriminate across customers with different types of demand, as would be the case if
Walmart offers quantity discounts. If Walmart follows the pricing rule for firms with
market power in Chapter 9, it will pick the quantity at which marginal revenue equals
marginal cost and charge a price equal to the height of the demand curve at that quan-
tity. In the figure, the monopoly quantity is 100 cards and the price is 25 cents per card.
Walmart’s producer surplus from pricing at that point equals the area of rectangle A.
If Walmart can prevent resale, however, it doesn’t have to charge a single price.
Suppose it offers the first 100 holiday cards for sale at 25 cents each, but then allows a
consumer to buy as many as 25 more cards (numbers 101–125) at a lower per-unit price
of 20 cents each. The customer will take advantage of this offer because the incremental
purchase at the lower price yields an additional consumer surplus equal to the area of
triangle B. Walmart is better off, too, because it adds an additional amount of producer
surplus equal to the area of rectangle C.
Walmart could keep offering discounted prices on larger quantities. For example, it
could offer the next 50 cards, up to the 175th photo card, for 10 cents each. Again, the
consumer will take the deal because the consumer surplus from that block of cards (area D
in the figure) is positive. Walmart also comes out ahead because it earns producer sur-
plus E. Note that the price strategy we just described could also be expressed in the
following way: 100 units are $25, 125 units are $30, and 175 units are $35. Even if all
customers have this same demand, all will opt to purchase 175 cards at a price of $35
and Walmart still increases its producer surplus. (This is why block pricing is different
D is the demand curve of an individual consumer
of Walmart’s photo cards. Under monopoly pricing,
Walmart sells at the point on the demand curve
corresponding to the quantity where MR = MC
(Q = 100 photo cards, P = $0.25 per card). When
Walmart can prevent resale, it can use a block pric-
ing strategy instead. It could still sell the first 100
at a price of $0.25 per card, while charging a lower
price of $0.20 each for the next 25 photos purchased
(for a total quantity of 125 cards) and $0.10 each
for the next 50 cards (for a total of 175 cards).
Producer surplus increases from area A to A + C
to A + C + E, respectively, and consumer surplus
increases by area B and areas B + D, respectively.
Figure 10.8 Block Pricing
Quantity of
photo cards
Price
($/photo card)
MC
D
A
B
C
D
E
0
175 125 100
0.20
$0.25
0.05
0.10
MR
block pricing
The practice of reducing
the price of a good when
the customer buys more
of it.
? The online appendix ?nds
pro?t-maximizing block prices.
(http://glsmicro.com/appendices)
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 428 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 429
from the quantity discounts we saw when discussing indirect price discrimination. Here,
no customer sorting needs to occur for Walmart to gain producer surplus.)
A block-pricing strategy like this raises more producer surplus for a firm than does
the conventional single-price monopoly strategy because it allows a firm to better match
the prices of different quantities of its output to consumers’ valuations of those quanti-
ties. For the first set of units that customers buy — the units for which customers have
a high willingness to pay — the firm charges a relatively high price. With block pricing,
the firm doesn’t have to completely give up selling a large number of units by charging
that initial high price. Block pricing lets it sell additional units of its product, those for
which consumers have lower willingness to pay, at lower prices.
This example shows how block pricing can work for even a single customer type,
though if there were lots of identical customers, the firm would need to be able to pre-
vent resale to avoid being undercut by its own customers.
Two-Part Tarifs
Another pricing strategy available to firms with market power and identical consumers is
the two-part tariff, a pricing strategy in which a firm breaks the payments for a product
into two parts. One component is a standard per-unit price. The second is a fixed fee that
must be paid to buy any amount of the product at all, no matter how large or how small.
For example, a lot of mobile phone “unlimited service” calling plans have this struc-
ture. You might pay, say, $50 a month for service and then be able to make as many
calls as you would like at no additional cost. Here, the fixed fee portion of the two-part
tariff is $50 and the per-unit price is zero (though for other markets and products, the
per-unit price is often positive). A video game system such as Microsoft’s XBox is like
a two-part tariff, too. Here, the cost of the console itself is the fixed fee and the cost of
the individual games represents the per-unit price.
To see why using a two-part tariff can be advantageous for a firm with market
power, consider the market in Figure 10.9. It shows the demand for mobile phone ser-
vice offered by the firm, the marginal revenue curve corresponding to demand, and the
firm’s constant marginal cost.
The firm’s conventional single-price monopoly profit-maximizing quantity is found
where marginal revenue equals marginal cost. The quantity at which this condition
holds is 300 minutes per month, and the price at which consumers are willing to
As a single-price monopoly, a mobile phone service
will sell 300 minutes of mobile service per month at
a price of $0.10 per minute. Using a two-part tariff,
however, the firm can increase its producer surplus
from rectangle B to the triangle A + B + C. To
do this, it will charge the per-unit price of $0.05 per
minute, where D = MC, and set a fixed fee equal
to the consumer’s surplus at this quantity, the area
A + B + C. Under this pricing scheme, the firm
will sell 600 minutes of mobile service per month.
Figure 10.9 Two-Part Tarif
Quantity of mobile service
(minutes per month)
Price
($/minute)
MC
D
A
B
C
0
600 300
$0.10
0.05
MR
two-part tariff
A pricing strategy in which
the payment has two com-
ponents, a per-unit price
and a ?xed fee.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 429 11/5/12 4:01 PM
430 Part 3 Markets and Prices
purchase that quantity is 10 cents per minute. At the price of 10 cents per minute, the
consumer surplus is area A and the firm’s producer surplus is rectangle B.
Now suppose instead that the firm uses the following two-part tariff pricing structure.
First, it reduces the per-unit price all the way to marginal cost, 5 cents. This change
increases the number of units it sells from 300 minutes to 600, but drives per-unit profit
to zero. However, the firm knows that each customer will buy a quantity of 600 minutes
per month of air time at this price and have a consumer surplus equal to area A + B +
C as a result. Knowing that this consumer surplus represents the willingness of the con-
sumers to pay above the market price, the firm will set a fixed fee to try to capture that
consumer surplus. Therefore, the firm decides to set the fixed-fee portion of the two-part
tariff equal to A + B + C. This fee is not per minute; it’s a one time per month fee for
any consumer who wants to buy any number of units at 5 cents per minute.
What happens under this two-part tariff pricing structure? At a unit price of
5 cents per minute, the consumer buys 600 minutes of air time. This part of the price
structure doesn’t make the phone company any money, because its marginal cost of
delivering service is also 5 cents per minute. However, the company is also charging the
fixed fee A + B + C. And importantly, the consumer is willing to pay that, because
if she uses 600 minutes of air time, she will enjoy consumer surplus equal to the same
area. The company has set the size of the fixed fee so that the consumer is no worse off
(and actually it could make her strictly better off if it charged just a touch less than
A + B + C) than if she bought nothing. By using a two-part tariff, the firm captures
the entire surplus in the market for itself, as opposed to only area B under standard
market power pricing.
Again, if you spread this insight to a market with many identical customers, the abil-
ity to prevent resale would be crucial for making the pricing strategy work. If the phone
company couldn’t prevent resale, one customer could pay the fixed fee, buy up a huge
amount of minutes at marginal cost, sell off these extra minutes at a small markup to
other consumers who did not pay the fixed fee, and make lots of money. For example,
if the consumer could rig her phone so other people would pay her 6 cents per minute
to make calls on it when she wasn’t using the phone, this would defeat the company’s
strategy.
10.5 ?gure it out
You have been hired as an intern at the Golden
Eagle Country Club Golf Course. You have been as-
signed the task of creating the pricing scheme for the
golf course, which typically charges an annual mem-
bership fee and a per-use cost to its customers. Each
of your customers is estimated to have the following
demand curve for rounds of golf per year:
Q = 300 – 5P
If Golden Eagle can provide rounds of golf at a con-
stant marginal cost of $50 and charges that amount per
round of golf, what is the most that members would be
willing to pay for the annual membership fee?
Solution:
This pricing scheme, with an annual membership
fee and a per-unit price, is a two-part tariff. If the
price per round of golf is set at P = $50, then each
member will want to play
Q = 300 – 5P
= 300 – 5(50)
= 300 – 250
= 50 rounds per year
With this knowledge, we can determine the maxi-
mum annual membership fee each customer is willing
to pay. This will be equal to the amount of consumer
surplus the customer will get from playing 50 rounds
of golf each year at a price of $50 per round.
To calculate consumer surplus, it is easiest to
draw a diagram, plot the demand curve, and find
the area of consumer surplus. To simplify matters,
let’s rearrange the demand function into an inverse
demand function:
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 430 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 431
Being able to capture the entire surplus in the market is great if you’re running a
firm, but it’s important to realize that a firm can attain this extreme result only if
its customers have the same demand curve. The problem is much more complicated
when there are customers with different demand curves.
For this more advanced two-part tariff pricing case, think about a firm that faces
two kinds of customers whose demand curves for the firm’s product are shown in
Figure 10.10. Panel a shows the demand curve of the firm’s relatively low-demand
(a) For low-demand customers, the firm would want
to sell a quantity of Q
cL
, charge a per-unit price of P
cL
and a fixed fee equal to the consumer surplus A + B + C.
Since this is much lower than the consumer surplus for
high-demand customers (D + E + F in panel b), such
a pricing strategy will leave a lot of surplus to the high-
demand customers in the market.
(b) For high-demand customers, the firm would want to
sell a quantity of Q
cH
, and charge a per-unit price of P
cH
and a fixed fee equal to D + E + F. Since this fixed fee
is higher than the consumer surplus for low-demand
customers, low-demand customers won’t buy anything.
Figure 10.10 Two-Part Tarif with Diferent Customer Demands
Quantity
Price
($/unit)
MC
A
B
C
D
E
F
MR
L
D
L
Q
mL
Q
cL
P
mL
P
cL
(a) Low-demand customer (b) High-demand customer
Quantity
Price
($/unit)
MC
MR
H
D
H
Q
mH
Q
cH
P
mH
P
cH
Q = 300 – 5P
5P = 300 – Q
P = 60 – 0.2Q
Rounds of golf
(per year)
Price
($/round)
MC
0
D
A
$60
P = 50
50
The vertical intercept is 60 and the consumer sur-
plus is the area below the demand curve and above
the price of $50, area A. We can calculate the area
of triangle A:
Area of A =
1
_
2
× base × height
=
1
_
2
× 50 × ($60 – $50) = 0.5(50)($10)
= $250
If the golf course set the price of a round of golf at
$50, the consumer would purchase 50 rounds per
year. This gives the golfer a consumer surplus equal
to $250. Therefore, customers would be willing to
pay up to $250 for an annual membership.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 431 11/5/12 4:01 PM
432 Part 3 Markets and Prices
customers, while panel b shows the demand of the firm’s relatively high-demand cus-
tomers. If the firm tries to use a two-part tariff where it sets the unit price at marginal
cost MC and the fixed fee at A + B + C, it will capture all of the surplus from the
relatively low-demand customers in panel a but leave a lot of surplus to the relatively
high-demand customers in panel b, because area A + B + C is much smaller than area
D + E + F. If the firm instead sets the fee at D + E + F to capture the surplus of
the high-demand customers, low-demand customers won’t buy at all. This is not neces-
sarily better than the first strategy. If the firm has a lot of low-demand customers, this
could be a big loss for the firm, even if the reduction in profit from losing any given
low-demand customer might be small. So, neither approach is perfect. Computing the
profit-maximizing two-part tariff when consumers have different demands is a math-
ematical challenge beyond the scope of this book, but it usually entails a unit price
above the firm’s marginal cost.
10.7 Conclusion
We explored a number of different ways in which firms with market power, under
the right conditions, can increase the producer surplus they earn above and beyond
the surplus they can earn by following the standard, one-price market power pricing
rule we focused on in Chapter 9. These pricing strategies are all around us; after
learning about them in this chapter, you will start to recognize them in practice.
You may also find yourself wondering why a particular firm isn’t using one of these
strategies. Just remember that certain conditions must be met for the price discrimi-
nation to work.
These various pricing strategies work in different ways, but there are some common
threads. First, none will work unless the firm has market power. Therefore, any firm
operating in a perfectly competitive market cannot use these strategies because it is a
price taker. Second, the firm must prevent resale. Without the ability to prevent resale,
doing anything besides the single-price monopoly pricing in Chapter 9 is futile. Third,
while price discrimination strategies differ in the specifics of their mechanisms and the
types of markets in which they are applicable, all of these methods work on the basic
principle that the firm can make more producer surplus if it can adjust the price it
charges so that consumers end up paying higher prices for those units of its output that
provide them with greater consumer surplus. Price discrimination also works by charg-
ing higher prices to consumers with less elastic demand and lower prices to consumers
with more elastic demand.
Other pricing strategies, such as block pricing and two-part tariffs, can be used even
in markets where all consumers have the same demand. These strategies work by allow-
ing consumers to buy relatively large quantities at a low price on the margin, but then
grab back producer surplus for the firm through higher up-front payments.
In the next chapter, we examine firms with degrees of market power that fall be-
tween perfect competition and monopoly. We will find that these firms’ decisions are
not made in a vacuum (where they only consider their own costs and their customers’
demands), but are also based on the decisions made by other firms in the same market.
Although many may choose to follow the pricing strategies discussed in this chapter,
each firm has to take into account how its competitors may react to such a move before
determining if the strategy increases its producer surplus.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 432 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 433
1. By using pricing strategies, a firm with market
power can extract more producer surplus from a
market than it can from following the monopoly
pricing rule of Chapter 9 (where the firm produces
the quantity at which marginal revenue equals
marginal cost, and then charges the price at which
buyers would consume that quantity). It can only
do so, however, if the situation satisfies certain
criteria. A crucial factor is that in addition to mar-
ket power, the firm has to be able to prevent resale
among customers. If the firm can prevent resale, the
amount of information it has on its customers de-
termines what kind of pricing strategy it can fol-
low. [Section 10.1]
2. When customers differ and the firm has suffi-
cient information about its customers’ demands
to charge every person a different price, perfect
or first-degree price discrimination is possi-
ble. This direct price discrimination strategy
allows the firm to capture the entire surplus in
the market for itself. It is very rare to have this
kind of information, however. [Section 10.2]
3. If the firm has different types of customers and
can directly identify at least two groups whose
price elasticities of demand differ, it can charge
different prices to the two groups and earn more
producer surplus. The profit-maximizing direct
price discrimination strategy in this case is to
follow the single-price monopoly pricing rule sep-
arately for each group. There are many ways to
directly separate customers, including customer
characteristics, geography, past purchase be-
havior, the timing of the purchase, and so on, a
practice known as segmenting, or third-degree
price discrimination. [Section 10.3]
4. If the company knows that there are different
types of customers but cannot directly identify
which group a customer belongs to before the
purchase, it must rely on indirect (second-
degree) price discrimination. This involves
designing choices that induce customers to sort
themselves into groups. Quantity discounts
can be used if customers who demand a high-
er quantity also have a more elastic demand.
Versioning a product can also work. The key
additional requirement for indirect price dis-
crimination is that the pricing structure has to
be incentive compatible, meaning that each
consumer group wants to take the offer designed
specifically for them. [Section 10.4]
5. If a company sells multiple products and con-
sumers’ demands for the products are negatively
correlated, it can sell the products together as
a bundle and increase producer surplus beyond
what it could earn by selling the products sepa-
rately. Sometimes, particularly if the marginal
cost of producing one of the products exceeds
the value that a customer places on that prod-
uct, the company may be better off using mixed
bundling, which gives customers the choice of
buying individual products at high prices or a
bundle of products at a discount. [Section 10.5]
6. Even when there are not different types of cus-
tomers, a firm can use advanced pricing strate-
gies like block pricing (a discount for buying
extra quantity) or a two-part tariff (a fixed fee
paid up-front in addition to a price per unit of the
good) as a way to capture more producer surplus
than it could earn with standard monopoly pric-
ing. However, each of these strategies is much
more complicated to implement when there are
many consumers with different demand curves.
[Section 10.6]
Summary
Review Questions
1. What are the two requirements of price dis-
crimination?
2. Why is producer surplus maximized under per-
fect price discrimination?
3. What are the two types of direct price dis-
crimination?
4. What are some ways that a firm can segment its
customers?
5. Contrast direct price discrimination and indirect
price discrimination.
6. What is incentive compatibility? Why is it
necessary for an indirect price discrimination
strategy to be incentive compatible?
7. Provide an example of product versioning.
8. What are the differences between the following
three pricing strategies: block pricing, segment-
ing, and quantity discounts?
9. What is the difference between mixed bundling
and pure bundling?
10. What are the two component prices of a two-
part tariff?
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 433 11/5/12 4:01 PM
434 Part 3 Markets and Prices
*1. Consider the demand for schnitzel in the diagram
below. Suppose that there is a single seller of
schnitzel, who acts as a single-price monopolist.
Quantity of
schnitzels
Price
($/schnitzel)
MC
MR D
D
E
F
G
H
I
C
A
B
P
2
P
1
Q
2
Q
1
P
3
a. Indicate the profit-maximizing price and
quantity.
b. List the areas of consumer and producer surplus.
c. Suppose the seller begins perfectly price dis-
criminating. How many schnitzels will she sell?
d. What happens to areas A and B when the
seller begins perfectly price discriminating?
e. What happens to areas E and H when the
seller begins perfectly price discriminating?
2. Indicate whether the following statement is true
or false, and explain your answer: Because the
potential profit from perfect price discrimina-
tion is always higher than the potential profit
from third-degree price discrimination (seg-
menting), firms that practice third-degree price
discrimination must not be maximizing profit.
3. There are seven consumers, each of whom is
hungry for exactly one Butterfinger. The con-
sumers’ maximum willingness to pay is given in
the table below:
Consumer
(age, gender)
Maximum
Willingness
to Pay
Marge (34, female) $2
Homer (38, male) 4
Lisa (6, female) 5
Maggie (2, female) 6
Ned (46, male) 1
Krusty (55, male) 3
Bart (9, male) 7
a. Given that each consumer wants one and
only one Butterfinger, draw the demand
curve for Butterfingers.
b. If Butterfingers are priced at $7, only one
will be sold. Who buys that Butterfinger?
Label the point at $7 on the demand curve
with the name of that buyer.
c. If Butterfingers are priced at $6, a second
buyer will be priced into the market. Who
is that buyer? Label the point at $6 on the
demand curve with the name of that buyer.
d. Continue to label each point on the demand
curve with the name of the buyer represented
by that point.
e. Suppose that you are a monopoly seller of But-
terfingers, which you can produce at a con-
stant marginal and average total cost of $2.
Suppose you charge every customer the same
price for Butterfingers. What price should you
set to maximize your profit? How many But-
terfingers will you sell? Calculate your profit.
Calculate the consumer surplus received by
the buyers. Calculate the deadweight loss.
f. Suppose that every customer that comes into
your Butterfinger store has their maximum
willingness to pay displayed in neon on their
foreheads. You decide to use this information
to increase your profit by practicing first-
degree price discrimination. How many But-
terfingers will you sell? Calculate your profit.
Calculate the consumer surplus received by
the buyers. Calculate the deadweight loss.
g. Where does the consumer surplus go when
you begin price discriminating?
h. What happens to the deadweight loss?
4. Consider the problem faced by the Butterfinger
seller in Problem 3.
a. Assume that the seller is able to prevent re-
sale between customers. In the real world,
why is the seller still unlikely to be able to
perfectly price discriminate?
b. Because of the reason you just indicated, the
Butterfinger seller decides to segment her
customers into two groups, each of which will
be charged a different price. In order to max-
imize profit, should the seller sort by gender
or by age?
c. Based on your answer to (b), determine who
is in each group, and indicate (1) the price the
seller should set for each group, (2) the total
profit received by the seller, (3) total consum-
er surplus, and (4) the deadweight loss.
Problems (Solutions to problems marked * appear at the back of this book. Problems adapted to use calculus are available online at http://worthpublishers.com/GLS1e)
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 434 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 435
d. Is this pricing strategy (segmenting) more
profitable to the seller than perfectly price
discriminating? Is this pricing strategy more
profitable than charging every consumer the
same price?
e. What happens to consumer surplus and
deadweight loss when a single-price monopo-
list begins segmenting in this way?
*5. Promoters of a major college basketball tourna-
ment estimate that the demand for tickets on the
part of adults is given by Q
ad
= 5,000 – 10P, and
that the demand for tickets on the part of stu-
dents is given by Q
st
= 10,000 – 100P. The pro-
moters wish to segment the market and charge
adults and students different prices. They esti-
mate that the marginal and average total cost of
seating an additional spectator is constant at $10.
a. For each segment (adults and students), find
the inverse demand and marginal revenue
functions.
b. Equate marginal revenue and marginal cost.
Determine the profit-maximizing quantity
for each segment.
c. Plug the quantities you found in (b) into the
respective inverse demand curves to find
the profit-maximizing price for each segment.
Who pays more, adults or students?
d. Determine the profit generated by each seg-
ment, and add them together to find the pro-
moter’s total profit.
e. How would your answers change if the arena
where the event was to take place had only
5,000 seats?
6. In Problem 5, you found the profit that a pro-
moter of a major college basketball tournament
would earn if he were to segment the market
into adults and students. Suppose that the pro-
moter’s CEO decides that price discrimination
presents a poor public image, and announces
that everybody will be charged the same price.
His resident economist (you) is tasked with fig-
uring out what that price should be.
a. Find the total demand for tickets by adding
the demand curves of adults and students.
b. Derive the inverse demand curve for tickets,
as well as the associated marginal revenue
curve associated with that demand.
c. Find the profit-maximizing quantity of tick-
ets and the corresponding price.
d. Determine the promoter’s profit.
e. Compare the promoter’s profit when he tries
to price for the entire market, to his profit
when he simply charges the adult price from
the previous problem. Is it better for the
promoter to price for the entire market and
almost fill the arena, or to price for adults
only and have a lot of empty seats?
7. You are the owner of a nail salon. Your female
customer’s price elasticity of demand for mani-
cures is –2.5; your male customer’s price elastici-
ty of demand for manicures is –1.2. The marginal
cost of manicuring a customer’s nails is $12.
a. If you segment the market by gender, what
price should you charge women? What price
should you charge men?
b. Explain intuitively why you should charge
each group a different price.
8. Movie theaters often charge substantially less
for afternoon showings than for evening show-
ings. Explain how theaters use time of day to
segment their customers into low-elasticity and
high-elasticity groups.
*9. Owners of a movie theater have determined that
the elasticity of demand for movie tickets equals
–2.0 for students and –1.5 for adults.
a. If the owners of the theater decide to segment
the market, who should be charged a higher
price, students or adults? Use your knowledge
of microeconomic theory to explain why.
b. Use the Lerner index as described in the text
to determine the ratio of prices. In percent-
age terms, how big a price premium should be
charged to the group that pays the higher price?
10. Owners of a Florida restaurant estimate that
the elasticity of demand for meals is –1.5 for
senior citizens and –1.33 for everyone else.
a. Given this information, how big (in percentage
terms) should the senior citizen discount be?
b. Suppose that the restaurant owners discover
that seniors tend to demand more attention
from their waiters and send back more food
as unsatisfactory, to the extent that the mar-
ginal cost of serving a senior is twice as high as
serving an adult. Accounting for these costs,
how large should the senior citizen discount
be? (Hint: Refer back to the example in the
text, but don’t cancel out marginal costs!)
c. Were your results in part (b) surprising? Ex-
plain them, intuitively.
11. A local golf course’s hired-gun econometrician
has determined that there are two types of golf-
ers, frequent and infrequent. Frequent golfers’
annual demand for rounds of golf is given by
Q
f
= 24 – 0.3P, where P is the price of a round
of golf. In contrast, infrequent golfers’ annual
demand for rounds of golf is given by Q
i
=
10 – 0.1P. The marginal and average total cost
of providing a round of golf is $20.
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 435 11/5/12 4:01 PM
436 Part 3 Markets and Prices
a. If the golf course could tell a frequent golfer
from an infrequent golfer, what price would it
charge each type? How many times would each
type golf? How much profit would the golf
course generate?
The greens manager has difficulty telling fre-
quent from infrequent golfers, so she decides to
use second-degree price discrimination (quantity
discounts) to make different types of golfers self-
select into the most profitable pricing scheme.
The course sets a price for individual rounds
of golf, but also offers a quantity discount for
members willing to buy a rather large quantity
of rounds in advance. The course’s owners hope
that frequent golfers will self-select into the dis-
counted plan, and that infrequent golfers will
choose to buy individual rounds.
b. What price should the golf course set for in-
dividual rounds of golf? Why?
c. If the course wishes to maximize profit, what
price and minimum quantity should it estab-
lish for the discounted plan?
d. Which plan will generate the greatest con-
sumer surplus for frequent golfers, the
individual-round plan or the discount plan?
Illustrate your answer by showing and mea-
suring the areas of surplus on frequent golf-
ers’ inverse demand curves.
e. Which plan will generate the greatest consumer
surplus for infrequent golfers, the individual-
round plan or the discount plan? Illustrate your
answer by showing the areas of surplus on in-
frequent golfers’ inverse demand curves.
f. Based on your answers to (d) and (e), will
the plan be successful in making golfers
self-select into the most profitable plan for
the golf course?
g. Suppose that each type of golfer came to the
course with the word “frequent” or “infre-
quent” tattooed on his or her forehead. Is
this information of any value to the golf
course owner? (In other words, can the owner
earn any more profits by segmenting than it
did with its quantity discount plan?)
12. Many textbooks are now available in two ver-
sions, a high-priced “domestic” version and a
low-priced “international” version. Each version
generally contains exactly the same text, but
slightly altered homework problems.
a. Why would a textbook publisher go to the
trouble to produce two versions of the same
text?
b. Discuss whether the publisher’s strategy
would be more effective if it made the altera-
tions secret, or if it announced them boldly.
c. The production of international versions of
textbooks was concurrent with the explosion
of the Internet. Explain why this is likely to
be more than just a coincidence.
13. Rockway & Daughters Piano Co. wishes to sell
a piano to everyone. But some consumers are
budget-conscious, and others are not, and unfor-
tunately, Rockway cannot tell which is which.
So, Rockway produces a premium line of pianos
that it markets under the Rockway name, and
a similar line of pianos that it markets under
the Dundee name. While the cost of producing
these pianos is quite similar, all consumers agree
that Rockway pianos are of higher quality than
Dundee pianos, and would be willing to pay
more for a Rockway. Budget-conscious consum-
ers feel that Dundee pianos are worth $6,000,
and Rockways are worth $8,000. Performance
artists believe that Dundee pianos are worth
$7,000 and Rockways are worth $12,000.
a. Suppose Rockway & Daughters prices its
Dundee pianos at $5,000 and its Rockway
pianos at $10,500. Are these prices incentive
compatible— that is, will more price-conscious
consumers purchase the Dundee line, while
more performance-oriented players choose
the Rockway? Explain.
b. How much must Rockway & Daughters re-
duce the price of its Rockway line in order to
achieve incentive compatibility?
c. Suppose instead that Rockway & Daughters
tries to achieve incentive compatibility by
raising the price of its Dundee line. Can it do
so? And if so, how?
14. London’s Market Bar has a unique pricing system
where a computer sets the price based on demand.
When demand picks up, the computer begins to
gradually reduce prices. This pricing strategy is
puzzling to those who have studied supply and
demand. Celene Berman, the assistant manager,
says a group of “young city-boy types” recently
kept asking why prices “were going the wrong
way around.” Explain, using your knowledge of
block pricing, why the owner’s strategy of reduc-
ing prices as sales increase might actually lead to
increased profit for the bar.
15. Microsoft sells two types of office software, a
word processor it calls Word, and a spreadsheet
it calls Excel. Both can be produced at zero
marginal cost. There are two types of consumers
for these products, who exist in roughly equal
proportions in the population: authors, who are
willing to pay $120 for Word and $40 for Excel,
and economists, who are willing to pay $50 for
Word and $150 for Excel.
*
*
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 436 11/5/12 4:01 PM
Market Power and Pricing Strategies Chapter 10 437
a. Ideally, Microsoft would like to charge au-
thors more for Word and economists more
for Excel. Why would it be difficult for Mi-
crosoft to do this?
b. Suppose that Microsoft execs decide to sell
Word and Excel separately. What price should
Microsoft set for Word? (Hint: Is it better to
sell only to authors, or to try to sell to both
authors and economists?) What price should
Microsoft set for Excel? What will Microsoft’s
profit be from a representative group of one
author and one economist?
c. Suppose that Microsoft decides to bun-
dle together Word and Excel in a package
called Office, and not offer them individu-
ally. What price should Microsoft set for the
package? Why? How much profit will Micro-
soft generate from a representative group of
one author and one economist?
d. Does bundling allow Microsoft to generate
higher profit than selling Word and Excel
separately?
16. Three consumers, John, Kate, and Lester, are in
the market for two goods, dates and eggs. Their
willingness to pay for dates and eggs is given in
the table below:
Dates
(1 package)
Eggs
(1 dozen)
John $0.60 $2.00
Kate $1.30 $1.30
Lester $2.00 $0.60
a. If you are a local farmer who can produce
dates and eggs for free, what is the optimal
price for dates and eggs if you price them indi-
vidually? How much profit will you generate?
b. If you bundle dates and eggs together, what
price should you set for a bundle containing
one package of dates and a dozen eggs? How
much profit will you generate?
c. Is there any advantage to mixed bundling in
this case? Why or why not?
d. Suppose that the cost of producing dates and
eggs rises to $1.00 per package and $1.00 per
dozen, respectively. Now is there any advan-
tage to mixed bundling? Why or why not? Ex-
plain your answer with a numerical illustration.
e. What accounts for the change in optimal
strategy when costs change?
17. Elaine makes delicious cupcakes that she mails
to customers across the country. Her cupcakes
are so delicious that she has a great degree of
pricing power. Elaine’s customers have identi-
cal demands for cupcakes. A representative cus-
tomer’s demand is shown in the diagram below.
Elaine can make a cupcake for a constant mar-
ginal and average total cost of $0.50.
Quantity of cupcakes
Price
($/cupcake)
MC = ATC
0
D
$2.50
0.50
20 25
a. If Elaine is an ordinary monopolist, what
price should she charge for cupcakes? How
many will each customer order? How much
profit will Elaine earn? How much consumer
surplus will the buyer get?
b. Suppose that Elaine decides to offer a quanti-
ty discount according to the following terms:
The first 10 cupcakes can be bought for $1.50
each; any cupcake over 10 will be offered at
a discounted price. What discount price will
maximize Elaine’s profit from this pricing
scheme? (Hint: Draw a new demand curve
for Elaine’s customers’ demand, but since her
customers have already purchased 10, begin
your demand curve at the 11th unit. Alterna-
tively, shift the vertical axis to the right by
10 units.)
c. How many cupcakes will customers order at
full price? How many at the discounted price?
d. What will Elaine’s profit be? How does this
scheme compare to the profit she earned as
an ordinary monopolist?
e. Suppose that Elaine gets super-greedy and
decides to implement a three-tiered pricing
system. What three prices should she choose
to maximize her profit? At what quantities
will the price points change? What will her
profit be?
f. Suppose Elaine decides to charge $2.40 for the
first cupcake, $2.30 for the second, and so on.
How many cupcakes will she sell, and what
will her profit be?
g. What happens to consumer surplus as Elaine
adds more price points? Where does it go?
18. Consider the demand for cupcakes in Problem
17. Suppose Elaine decides to sell cupcakes only
in packages of 20.
*
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 437 11/5/12 4:01 PM
438 Part 3 Markets and Prices
a. How much would customers be willing to pay
to obtain a 20-pack of Elaine’s cupcakes?
(Hint: Remember that the value of each cup-
cake is given by the corresponding point on
the demand curve. Add up those values for
cupcakes 1–20.)
b. How much profit will Elaine earn from each
customer?
c. How does the profit from this scheme com-
pare to the profit Elaine earned in part (f) of
Problem 17?
19. Many gyms offer a mixed two-part tariff pric-
ing scheme. One can join the gym and then
have daily access at a very low cost (often,
free); alternatively, one can choose not to join
and pay a higher daily fee (perhaps $10 or
$15). Explain the rationale for this dual pric-
ing scheme. What must be true of the gym’s
customers’ demands?
20. SmacFone is a major provider of pay-by-the-minute, no contract cellphones that are very popular with or-
dinary consumers. They are also quite popular with drug dealers, who appreciate the anonymity that such
phones provide. The demand curves for talking minutes that SmacFone faces from each type of customer are
given in the diagrams below. SmacFone’s marginal and average total cost of service is 5 cents per minute.
Quantity of minutes
Price
($/minute)
MC
0
D
$0.25
0.05
240 300
(a) Drug dealer’s demand (b) Ordinary person’s demand
Quantity of minutes
Price
($/minute)
MC
0
D
$0.15
0.05
600 900
a. Determine the profit-maximizing price and quantity that SmacFone would like to charge each type of
consumer, and show it on the appropriate graph. Then, determine the potential profit that SmacFone
could generate from each segment.
Because SmacFone cannot tell whether a new customer is an ordinary person or a drug dealer, it decides
to use second-degree price discrimination to separate consumers. SmacFone sets a Plan A price of 15 cents
per minute, but offers a special Plan B price of 10 cents per minute if a customer purchases 300 or more
minutes.
b. Determine how much consumer surplus ordinary consumers would receive under Plans A and B. Which
plan should ordinary consumers choose if they are trying to maximize their surplus?
c. Determine how much consumer surplus drug dealers would receive under Plans A and B. Which plan
should drug dealers choose if they are trying to maximize their surplus?
d. Is the plan SmacFone derived incentive compatible? (In other words, will the plan successfully direct drug
dealers to Plan A and ordinary consumers to Plan B?) How much profit will SmacFone generate with this
set of plans?
e. SmacFone is considering making some adjustments to their plans. One option is to change Plan B to 11
cents per minute with a 240-minute minimum. Determine whether the new plan selection is incentive-
compatible. Why doesn’t SmacFone simply raise the price to 11 cents without altering the 300-minute
minimum? How much profit will the new set of plans generate for SmacFone?
f. Another option that SmacFone is considering is dropping the price of its ordinary service to 14 cents
per minute. Determine whether the new plan selection is incentive compatible. How much profit will
the new set of plans generate for SmacFone?
g. Why does lowering the price of ordinary service work better at creating an incentive-compatible set of
calling plans than raising the price of the large-quantity plan?
Goolsbee1e_Ch10.indd 438 11/5/12 4:01 PM
doc_580425406.pdf