Dissertation Study on Strategic Behaviors and Market Outcomes

Description
A player's strategy, in game theory, refers to one of the options he can choose in a setting where the outcome depends not only on his own actions but on the action of others.[1] A player's strategy will determine the action the player will take at any stage of the game.

ABSTRACT

Title of Document:

STRATEGIC BEHAVIORS AND MARKET OUTCOMES: TWO ESSAYS Li Zou, Ph.D., 2007

Directed By:

Professor Martin E. Dresner and Professor Robert J. Windle Department of Logistics, Business and Public Policy, Robert H. Smith School of Business University of Maryland, College Park

This dissertation is comprised of two essays related, broadly, to themes of competitive dynamics and economic consequences. In Essay One, “Many Fields of Battle: How Cost Structure Affects Competition across Multiple Markets,” a conjectural variation model is developed to examine what role cost structure and product differentiation play in affecting the mutual forbearance outcome arising from multi-market contact. The analytical results show that the degree of collusion (as measured by the price level) enhanced through multimarket contact is greater when multimarket contact occurs between firms with similar production costs and undifferentiated products. This hypothesis is then tested using data from the U.S. airline industry. The empirical results provide support for the view suggesting that multimarket contact blunts the edge of competition between firms. Moreover, it is found that rival carriers with similar production costs are more likely to experience

such collusion facilitating effects from multimarket contact than those with dissimilar production costs. The second essay in this dissertation is entitled, “A Two-Location Inventory Model with Transshipments in a Competitive Environment.” In this study, an analytical model is developed to assess the impact of transshipments on inventory replenishment decisions and the implications for firm profitability in a competitive, uncertain market environment. To incorporate the competition between stocking locations, the analytical model developed in this paper uses a marketing variable, customer’s switching rate, to measure the probability of an individual consumer choosing an alternative source of supply in the event of stockout. In such an environment, firms not only cooperate through the practice of transshipments but also compete for business. A number of interesting conclusions are drawn from numerical optimization results. For instance, it is found that when firms differ in market demand, small firms benefit more from transshipments than do large firms. In addition, it is shown that there is an inverted u-shaped relationship between transshipment price and the profit improvements that large firms gain through transshipments, whereas such benefits are monotonically decreasing with transshipment price for small firms. These findings provide several managerial implications with regard to the role of transshipment price in creating benefits for participating firms.

STRATEGIC BEHAVIORS AND MARKET OUTCOMES: TWO ESSAYS

By Li Zou

Dissertation submitted to the Faculty of the Graduate School of the University of Maryland, College Park, in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy 2007

Advisory Committee: Dr. Martin E. Dresner (Chair) Department of Logistics, Business and Public Policy Dr. Robert J. Windle (Co-chair) Department of Logistics, Business and Public Policy Dr. Philip T. Evers Department of Logistics, Business and Public Policy Dr. Wilbur Chung Department of Logistics, Business, and Public Policy Dr. Gang-Len Chang Department of Civil and Environmental Engineering

© Copyright by Li Zou 2007

Acknowledgements
I am truly thankful to Dr. Martin Dresner, my advisor and co-chair of my dissertation. Martin has provided me with extraordinary help and support, leading me through the challenging and valuable experience that I have had in writing this dissertation required to fulfill my Ph.D. studies at the University of Maryland. He has always been inspiring, encouraging, and supportive. I owe an enormous amount of debt to Martin, who took the time and effort to teach me how to improve my dissertation in each of the following aspects: the development of research ideas, the use of research tools, the exploration of managerial implications from research, and the writing and revision of the paper. Every achievement that I have made at each stage of my dissertation would have been impossible without receiving lots of help and encouragement from Martin.

My heartfelt gratitude also goes to Dr. Robert Windle, the co-chair of my dissertation committee. Bob gave me much help recognizing and correcting several technical mistakes that I have made at earlier stages of my dissertation work. I am grateful to Bob for his patience and guidance in helping me find accurate solutions to these problems. My dissertation has greatly benefited from the many insightful comments and constructive suggestions that Bob made with respect to arriving at good research questions, addressing the questions using appropriate methods, and finding the intuition behind the results.

ii

I am also grateful to Dr. Philip Evers, a key advisor in my study of transshipments. Phil has conducted much research in this field. When I told him about my interests in studying transshipments, he introduced me to much of the previous literature in this area. More importantly, Phil helped me find an interesting question to examine. My idea to study transshipments between rivals was formed during one of our several research meetings. Afterwards, Phil guided and encouraged me to develop an analytical model assessing the benefits from transshipments in a competitive environment. In the future, I hope to follow Phil’s advice and incorporate simulation analyses into my transshipment research. I also owe great thanks to Phil for offering me advice on specific revisions of earlier drafts of my dissertation.

I also would like to extend my deep gratitude to my other committee members – Professors Gang-Len Chang and Wilbur Chung. Their insightful comments and constructive feedback after attending my dissertation proposal have greatly helped me improve my dissertation. I am particularly thankful to Wilbur for giving me valuable advice on paper submissions and the use of STATA in statistical tests. In addition, I would like to acknowledge my appreciation to several other scholars who were not on my dissertation committee but provided me with generous help and suggestions at various stages of my dissertation study: Professors Curt Grimm, Tae Oum, Brian Ratchford, Roland Rust, P.K. Kannan, and Paul Iyogun. I would especially like to thank Curt Grimm for the inspiration and encouragement he gave me in extending my current study of multimarket contact competition to a more general industrial setting. Special thanks, as well, go to Tae Oum for his insightful comments when I presented

iii

an early draft of my mulitmarket contact study at the Allied Social Sciences Association conference in Boston. My gratitude goes, as well, to Brian Ratchford, Roland Rust, and P.K. Kannan, who read an earlier draft of my multimarket paper and provided me with suggestions in developing my analytical model. Finally, special thanks go to Paul Iyogun for his suggestion of studying the practice of transshipments between asymmetric firms, which certainly helped enrich my dissertation.

I would also like to extend my sincere gratitude to my fellow Ph.D. students for their support given to me in my proposal defense and my final dissertation defense. My thanks to Adriana Rossiter Hofer, Christian Hofer, Tobin Porterfield, John Macdonald, Xiang Wan, Dina Ribbink, David Cantor, Chao-Dong Han, and Rodrigo Britto. Lastly, but not least, I am infinitely grateful to my beloved parents, Furong Liu and Pengling Zou, for their understanding and encouragement throughout all these past years when I was away from home studying in pursuit of my Ph.D. degree. This dissertation is dedicated to thank them.

??,?????????,???????????????????? ?????????????????????????????????? ?????????????????????

iv

Table of Contents
Acknowledgements....................................................................................................... ii Table of Contents.......................................................................................................... v List of Tables ............................................................................................................... vi List of Figures ............................................................................................................. vii Chapter 1: Introduction ................................................................................................. 1 Chapter 2: Essay One - Many Fields of Battle: How Cost Structure Affects Competition across Multiple Markets........................................................................... 7 1. Introduction........................................................................................................... 7 2. Theoretical Model............................................................................................... 12 2.1 Model Setup .................................................................................................. 13 2.2 Numerical Examples..................................................................................... 25 3. Empirical Analysis.............................................................................................. 34 3.1 Hypotheses.................................................................................................... 35 3.2 Empirical Models.......................................................................................... 36 3.3 Data ............................................................................................................... 40 3.4 Measurement of Multimarket Contact – MMC ............................................ 41 3.5 Estimation of Airline Expenses/ASM........................................................... 42 4. Results................................................................................................................. 44 5. Conclusions and Implications ............................................................................. 50 Chapter 3: Essay Two - A Two-Location Inventory Model with Transshipments in a Competitive Environment........................................................................................... 53 1. Introduction......................................................................................................... 53 2. The Model........................................................................................................... 60 3. Transshipments in a Competitive Decision-Making Environment..................... 72 3.1 Optimal Inventory Decision without Transshipments .................................. 72 3.2 Optimal Inventory Decision with Transshipments ....................................... 80 4. Transshipments in a Cooperative Decision-Making Environment..................... 86 4.1 Optimal Inventory Decision without Transshipments .................................. 87 4.2 Optimal Inventory Decision with Transshipments ....................................... 91 5. Numerical Examples........................................................................................... 97 5.1 Results for Example 1................................................................................... 98 5.2 Results for Example 2................................................................................. 108 5.3 Results for Example 3................................................................................. 136 6. Conclusions and Future Research..................................................................... 142 Chapter 4: Conclusions ............................................................................................. 144 References................................................................................................................. 151

v

List of Tables
Table II-1: The Values for Market Demand Parameters, ai and ai' , under Various Scenarios ............................................................................................................. 16 Table II-2: The Values for Key Parameters Associated with Firms 1 and 2 .............. 32 Table II-3: Descriptive Statistics for the Key Variables............................................. 42 Table II-4: Low-Cost and Hight-Cost Carriers........................................................... 44 Table II-5: Estimation Results for Model One ........................................................... 45 Table II-6: Estimation Results for Model Two........................................................... 46 Table II-7: Correlation among Market Structure Variables........................................ 47 Table III-1: Notations for Key Parameters and Variables used in the Model ............ 63 Table III-2: Key Values for Events I, II, and III......................................................... 73 Table III-3: Key Values for Events IV, V, and VI...................................................... 73 Table III-4: Variable Notations and Definitions......................................................... 76 Table III-5: Events and Associated Key Values ......................................................... 80 Table III-6: Key Values for Events I, II, and III......................................................... 88 Table III-7: Key Values for Events IV, V, and VI...................................................... 88 Table III-8: Events and Associated Key Values ......................................................... 91 Table III-9: Events and Associated Key Values ......................................................... 95 Table III-10: Notations for Key Parameters ............................................................... 96 Table III-11: Assumed Values for Relevant Cost Parameters .................................... 98 Table III-12: The Impacts of Transshipments on Performance Outcomes............... 110 Table III-13: Event Revenues for Large and Small Firms........................................ 119 Table III-14: Expressions for Key Parameters.......................................................... 134 Table III-15: Expressions for Key Parameters.......................................................... 135 Table III-16: The Impacts of Transshipments on Performance Outcomes............... 142

vi

List of Figures
Figure II-1: Competing, Tacit-colluding Prices in Single and Multimarket Settings. 28 Figure II-2: Competing, Tacit-colluding Prices in Single and Multimarket Settings. 29 Figure II-3: Competing, Tacit-colluding Prices in Single and Multimarket Settings. 30 Figure II-4: Competing, Tacit-colluding Prices for Low-cost Firm in Single and Multimarket Settings........................................................................................... 33 Figure II-5: Competing, Tacit-colluding Prices for High-cost Firm in Single and Multimarket Settings........................................................................................... 34 Figure III-1: An Illustration of the Scenario with Transshipments............................. 64 Figure III-2: An Illustration of the Scenario without Transshipments ....................... 64 Figure III-3: Graphic Illustration of Scenarios ........................................................... 70 Figure III-4: Inventory Level Comparison ................................................................. 99 Figure III-5: Profit Comparison ................................................................................ 100 Figure III-6: Inventory Level Comparison ............................................................... 102 Figure III-7: Profit Comparison ................................................................................ 105 Figure III-8: Inventory Level Comparison ............................................................... 106 Figure III-9: The Performance Impacts of Transshipments...................................... 108 Figure III-10: The Impact of Transshipment on Firm’s Inventory Level................. 112 Figure III-11: The Performance Impacts of Transshipments for Large Firm........... 113 Figure III-12: The Performance Impacts of Transshipments for Small Firm........... 114 Figure III-13: Graphic Illustration of Scenarios for Different Transshipment Prices ........................................................................................................................... 115 Figure III-14: Graphic Illustration of Scenarios for Different Transshipment Prices ........................................................................................................................... 117 Figure III-15: Event Probability and Transshipment Price....................................... 118 Figure III-16: Revenues for Small and Large Firms in Events I, II, and III............. 120 Figure III-17: Revenues for Small and Large Firms in Events IV, V, and VI.......... 124 Figure III-18: Expected Revenues for Small and Large Firms in Events I, II, and III ........................................................................................................................... 125 Figure III-19: Expected Revenues for Small and Large Firms in Events IV, V, and VI ........................................................................................................................... 126 Figure III-20: Expected Revenues vs. Inventory Costs with Transshipments.......... 127 Figure III-21: Expected Profits with Transshipments............................................... 128 Figure III-22: The Performance Impacts of Transshipments in Various Competitive Settings.............................................................................................................. 129 Figure III-23: The Impacts of Transshipments on Joint Inventories of Firms.......... 130 Figure III-24: The Impacts of Transshipments on Joint Profits of Firms ................. 131 Figure III-25: The Profit Impact of the Transshipment Strategy that Maximizes Joint Benfits ............................................................................................................... 132 Figure III-26: Inventory Levels Under Various Competitive Settings ..................... 137 Figure III-27: Profit Outcomes under Various Competitive Settings....................... 138 Figure III-28: Inventory Levels at Various Transshipment Prices ........................... 139 Figure III-29: Profit Outcomes at Various Transshipment Prices ............................ 139 vii

Figure III-30: Inventory Levels for Small Firm with and without Transshipments . 140 Figure III-31: Inventory Levels for Large Firm with and without Transshipments . 140 Figure III-32: Joint Inventories with and without Transshipments .......................... 141

viii

Chapter 1: Introduction
Multimarket contact competition describes a situation where the same firms compete with each other simultaneously in multiple markets. As the foundation of multimarket competition theory, the mutual forbearance view suggests an inverse relationship between multimarket contact and the intensity of interfirm rivalry. According to this view, as compared to a single market competition, multimarket contact endows firms with more opportunities to act in response to the strategic behaviors of rival firms. In other words, multimarket contact competition provides firms with greater opportunities to reward competitors if they “behave” by sustaining collusive outcomes, and to enact punishment if rival firms deviate from the collusive outcomes.

There has been an extensive body of research empirically investigating mutual forbearance and its ability to reduce competitive intensity. For example, Evans and Kessides (1994) estimate the effects of multimarket contact on pricing in the U.S. airline industry. They find that airfares are higher in those city-pair markets served by carriers with extensive inter-route contacts. This result provides support for the mutual forbearance hypothesis, suggesting that multimarket contact reduces the rivalry intensity between firms, thus leading to a high market price. In an analytical study of multimarket contact and tacit collusion, Bernheim and Whinston (1990) also find evidence that multimarket contact facilitates collusive behaviors. Moreover, they show that the market price sustained among mutimarket competitors is even higher when the rival firms have dominant market positions in different markets, an effect known as sphere of influence. A simple illustration of sphere of influence is as 1

follows. When two firms (e.g., Firm 1 and 2) compete in Markets A and B, and the two firms have dominant positions in different markets (i.e., Firm 1 is the main player in Market A, and Firm 2 is the key player in Market B), each firm’s incentive to compete aggressively in the other firm’s focal market is restrained by the retaliatory threat of its rival in the market where the firm has a strong position.

The development of theories about multimarket contact competition has benefited from a growing body of empirical literature and from many well-established theoretical models analyzing firm collusive behaviors. However, none of previous studies has examined the moderating role that cost plays in the relationship between multimarket contact and competitive intensity. An important question is whether the mutual forbearance outcome will be achieved when rival firms incur substantially different production costs and have differentiated products. The rationales for viewing production cost as an important moderating factor are two-fold. First, the conjectural variation1 one firm has with respect to another is presumed to be higher when the two rival firms incur similar production costs than when their production costs are dissimilar. Moreover, it is expected that the cross-price demand elasticities between products provided by firms having similar production costs will be greater than between firms with dissimilar production costs. This presumption is based on the rationale that products have a great degree of substitutability when they are produced by firms with similar production costs. Conjectural variation and cross-price elasticity are two main factors affecting the degree of tacit-collusion that firms sustain in the multimarket contact setting. As a result, the tacit cooperation opportunities
Conjectural variation measures the extent of price movement that one firm expects or perceives the other to make in responding to its own price change.
1

2

enlarged by multimarket contact may be related to the relative costs of the competing firms.

The first essay in this dissertation theoretically and empirically examines the occurrence of multimarket contact between firms with different production costs and its impact on the market price sustained. In the analytical section of Essay 1, a conjectural variation model is developed to explore the pricing decisions made by firms competing simultaneously across multiple markets. In comparing tacitcolluding prices firms sustain in single market competition with those that occur through multimarket contact, the analytical results suggest that the degree of collusion (as measured by the price level) facilitated by multimarket contact is greater between firms with similar production costs. This proposition is then tested using airline data from the top 1,000 U.S. domestic origin and destination routes in 2002. The empirical findings suggest that mutlimarket contact reduces competitive intensity between carriers and leads to higher airfares. This result confirms the long-standing view of mutual forbearance. The findings also suggest that the degree to which multimarket contact impacts airfares depends on the relative costs of the carriers in a market. It is found that multimarket contact has a greater positive effect on price when rival carriers have similar production costs; when rival carriers have dissimilar production costs, multimarket contact has little impact on a carrier’s yields (i.e., average one-way airfare divided by non-stop route distance).

3

The second strategic behavior addressed in this dissertation is the practice of transshipments between competing firms selling in markets with uncertain, asymmetrical demands. Transshipments refer to the practice of transferring goods from the location with excess stock to satisfy the demand at the location with insufficient stock. As a risk-pooling strategy, it has been widely applied in several industries, especially in those industries where the distribution lead time is long, the product selling season is short, the products are high-valued goods, and the local consumer market is unpredictable. Under these circumstances, transshipments are often observed to be made between stores that belong to the same chain. Take fashion or upper-end clothes store as an example. Suppose one Gap store in a local mall is stocked out of a particular size or style of an item, then another Gap store in a nearby mall might transship the product to the out-of-stock store. In this case, transshipments are implemented between firms that operate under the same corporate umbrella. Transshipments are initiated either voluntarily, or mandated by the company’s headquarter. This type of transshipment has been well studied in previous literature.

An alternative setting for transshipments is examined by the second essay in this dissertation. In this setting, transshipments are implemented among firms that compete with one another. An example would be the transshipment of auto vehicles between independent car dealers. In this case, the two dealers may be located in fairly close proximity and distribute the same brand of automobile, but are independently owned. More importantly, the two car dealers not only cooperate through transshipments, but also compete with one another. If one dealer is stocked

4

out of a particular model, potential customers of this dealer might simply divert to a neighboring dealer and make purchase there. From this perspective, these two car dealers are head-to-head competitors. In this case, a critical decision facing each car dealer is whether to implement transshipments with other dealers.

In Essay 2, a two-location distribution model is developed to explore the following questions: (1) How do transshipments between rival firms affect their inventory decision-making and what are the performance outcomes? (2) When does a transshipment strategy benefit firms that are head-to-head competitors? (3) How are the benefits from transshipments shared among the firms? (4) Is there a transshipment price that will allow both competitors to increase their profits?

Through transshipments, firms can save inventory costs without impairing customer service levels, as measured by fill rates or stockouts. It has been well recognized that transshipments enable firms to share inventories and pool demand variability. However, the question that remains whether the strategy of transshipments will provide benefits when firms are direct rivals. In this setting, firms’ ex ante inventory replenishment decisions are interrelated through the implementation of transshipments. Specifically, one firm’s stock level decision has an external negative impact on another firm’s inventory decision. For example, when one firm carries a large inventory, the other firm tends to hold a small inventory because transshipments make it possible for the firm with small inventory to rely upon the large inventory held by the other firm in the event of stockout. As well, when one firm carries a

5

small inventory, the other firm tends to hold a large inventory because transshipments make it easier for the firm with large inventory to dispose of its extra stock when overstocks occur. In these situations, firms will, in most cases, benefit from a coordinated inventory policy. In a competitive setting, however, inventory coordination may not be as feasible. Thus, it is important to see if there exists an incentive mechanism (e.g., the use of an appropriate transshipment price) that can lead to positive outcomes for both firms. Building upon the analytical model, several numerical examples are used in Essay 2 to compare the performance outcomes under various competitive environments. The results suggest that first, transshipment price matters in a competitive environment; secondly, when the two firms are identical, there exists a transshipment price that is optimal for both firms; and finally, when the two firms are not identical, the smaller firm will prefer a lower transshipment price, and will achieve greater benefits from transshipments.

The remainder of this dissertation is organized as follows. Chapter II presents the study of multimarket contact for firms having different production costs and selling differentiated products. In Chapter III, the practice of transshipments between two rival firms is modeled and the results from numerical examples are provided. Chapter IV summarizes a number of key findings and managerial implications that are drawn from this dissertation.

6

Chapter 2: Essay One - Many Fields of Battle: How Cost Structure Affects Competition across Multiple Markets
1. Introduction
Multimarket contact refers to situations when the same firms simultaneously compete in multiple markets. This type of competition occurs when firms produce multiple product lines, diversify into several industries, or operate in different geographical markets. When firms compete in a multimarket context, potential and actual interactions across markets serve to affect the strategic behaviors of firms. Edwards (1955) is the first to make the point: When two firms meet in multiple product or geographic markets, they may hesitate to contest a given market vigorously for fear of retaliatory attacks in other markets that erodes the prospective gain in that market. Since then, this mutual forbearance view has become the fundamental theory of multipoint competition research and has found consistent support in the context of many industries, especially in the airline industry (e.g., Evans & Kessides 1994; Morrison et al 1996; Baum & Korn 1996 and 1999; Gimeno 1999). According to mutual forbearance theory, firms that meet simultaneously in multiple markets will compete less intensely with one another. Evans and Kessides (1994) are among the first authors to examine empirically the effect of multimarket contact on pricing in the U.S. airline industry. They find that airfares are higher on city-pair routes served by carriers with more overlapping routes in common.

As an extension of mutual forbearance theory, the spheres of influence view suggests that the inverse relationship between multimarket contact and rivalry intensity is greater when multimarket competitors have dominant positions in different markets.

7

The presence of asymmetric territorial interests endows firms with opportunities to retaliate in markets that are more important to their competitors. In this way, a firm behaves less aggressively in a rival firm’s dominant market in exchange for the rival firm’s similar subordination in its turf market. Gimeno (1999) offers empirical evidence for the spheres of influence argument. Using data from the U.S. airline industry, Gimeno (1999) finds that airlines restrain their competitive behaviors in their rival firms’ important markets so as to reduce the competitive intensity of those rival firms in the airline’s own dominant markets.

The cooperation facilitating effect of multimarket contact has also been extended to study the dynamic characteristics of competitive interactions among multimarket competitors. Morrison et al. (1996) estimate the effect of multimarket contact on the probability of an airline fare war. According to the mutual forbearance theory, multimarket contact facilitates carrier cooperation and thus reduces the occurrence of fare wars. On the other hand, multimarket contact exposes carriers to competition over more routes on which one carrier’s price cuts could initiate retaliation from rival carriers on other routes, thereby leading to a greater likelihood of fare wars. Analyzing the quarterly fare changes on the top 1,000 U.S. domestic routes in 1993, Morrison et al. (1996) find no empirical evidence for the mutual forbearance hypothesis. Instead, their results indicate that multimarket contact increases the likelihood of a fare war on a given route.

8

Recently, an inverted U-shape relationship between multimarket contact and competitive interactions among multimarket rivals has been proposed and received empirical support (Baum & Korn 1996 and 1999; Fuentelsaz and Gomez 2006). Baum and Korn (1996 and 1999) find that an increase in multimarket contact raises an airline’s rate of market entry into and exit from other airlines’ markets when the level of multimarket contact between rival carriers is low; multimarket contact, however, has a negative impact on an airline’s rates of entry into and exit from other airlines’ routes when multimarket contact between rival carriers grows beyond a threshold level. As pointed out by Fuentelsaz and Gomez (2006), the strategies of entry into new markets or exit from existent markets are purposefully utilized by firms to increase or decrease the extent of multimarket contact with their rivals. The findings of an inverted U-shape relationship between multimarket contact and entry rates provide support for the argument that when the level of multimarket contact between two rival firms is low, both firms intentionally use entry strategy to establish a foothold in the rival’s markets so as to signal capabilities to retaliate against any aggressive attacks. Once the level of multimarket contact rises beyond a certain level, rival firms get more familiar with one another and are better able to recognize the interdependence of competing simultaneously across multiple markets. As such, multimarket contact serves to restrain aggressive actions and deter further entries of multimarket rivals (Fuentelsaz and Gomez 2006; Karnani and Wernerfelt 1985).

Most anecdotal evidence so far provides empirical support for a negative relationship between multimarket contact and the intensity of rivalry (e.g., Heggestad and

9

Rhoades, 1976; Feinberg 1985; Singal 1996; Jan and Rosenbaum 1996; Parker and Roller 1997; Fernandes and Marin 1998; Gimeno and Woo 1999). In these prior studies, several moderating factors have been incorporated into studying the negative effect of multimarket contact on rivalry intensity, as measured by the price level. Such factors include firm size (Baum and Korn 1999), market concentration (Jans and Rosenbaum 1996; Fernandes and Marin 1998), and spheres of influence (Gimeno 1999). However, there has been no attempt to investigate the impact of firm cost structure on the relationship between multimarket contact and the intensity of competition.

In this article, we first investigate the question as to whether multimarket contact reduces competitive intensity when it occurs between firms producing outputs at the same marginal cost, which is invariant throughout markets, and when markets are identical. Under these circumstances, Bernheim and Whinston (1990) suggest that multimarket contact is irrelevant and does not facilitate collusion. On the contrary, we show that when the conjectural variations firms have with respect to each other and the cross price elasticity between rival firms are positive, multimarket contact always restrains competitive behavior, thus facilitating tacit collusion. The non-zero values for conjectural variation and cross price elasticity make strategic interactions between multimarket rivals interdependent across markets: the optimal price firms choose in one market depends on prices realized in other markets. The question of whether aggressive pricing by a firm in one of its markets leads to loss or gain in other markets depends on two factors. First, the positive value for conjectural variation a

10

firm has with respect to its rival firms indicates the degree of retaliation that the firm perceives or expects its rival firms might take in any market. Second, the positive cross-price elasticities between the firm and its competing firms imply that their products are strategic substitutes, rather than complements. As such, the counterattacking prices initiated by rival firms lead to demand loss and reduce the firm’s profitability in other markets. Under these two conditions, the punishing effects occurring simultaneously in more than one market are greater than the aggregate effects of those retaliations arising from any individual market and, as a result, multimarket contact serves to restrain competitive behaviors and fosters implicit colluding actions.

The second question to be addressed in this paper is whether multimarket contact between firms with similar production costs has a different competitive effect than multimarket contact between firms with dissimilar production costs. To analyze the collusion-facilitating effect of multimarket contact, we develop a conjectural variation model in which the tacit-colluding price in the single market setting is compared with the price in a multimarket contact setting. The analytical results reveal first, firms benefit more from a high tacit-colluding price in the multimarket contact setting, as compared to the single market setting; and second, the profit improvements resulting from tacit collusive pricing in the context of multimarket contact are greater when multimarket rivals have similar production costs than the case when multimarket rivals have dissimilar production costs.

11

Our empirical analysis in the context of the U.S domestic airline industry bears out the theoretical propositions. The results support the longstanding view that multimarket contact reduces interfirm rivalry intensity. Moreover, the collusionenhancing effect of multimarket contact is more likely to be found between carriers with similar production costs. By contrast, there is no such effect when multimarket contact occurs between carriers having dissimilar production costs.

The remainder of this essay is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the analytical model and the results drawn from a series of numerical examples. In Section 3, we discuss hypotheses, empirical models, data and methodology. Section 4 summarizes the findings from our empirical analysis. The final section concludes and discusses implications for management and regulations.

2. Theoretical Model
In this section, we develop a conjectural variation model2 to analyze firm collusive behavior in the setting of multimarket contact. To examine the potential effects of multimarket contact on collusive behavior, we compare the single market tacit colluding price with the tacit colluding price under multimarket contact. Although we focus on the case of two firms competing in two markets, the analysis and its conclusion can be extended to the case where n-firms meet with one another in mmarkets.

2

In this model, the conjectural variable is incorporated into the price equilibrium analysis.

12

2.1 Model Setup

Consider two firms, referred to as Firm 1 and Firm 2, competing in Market A or Market B, when they meet in a single market; and competing in Markets A and B when they meet in multimarkets. First, we assume that Firms 1 and 2 have identical production costs and that their products are highly substitutable. By comparing the tacit-colluding prices that firms sustain in single and multimarket settings, we investigate the question of whether multimarket contact facilitates collusive behavior when firms produce outputs at the same marginal cost, which is invariant across markets. Then, we consider that Firm 1 is a low-cost firm producing inferior goods, whereas Firm 2 is a high-cost firm providing superior goods. In this case, we assume that their products become less substitutable and the conjectural variations one firm has with respect to the other are lower as compared to those associated with the first scenario. The demand functions we use for Firms 1 and 2 in Market A or B are:
q1 = a1 ? e1 p1 + dp2
q2 = a2 ? e2 p2 + dp1

(1.1) (1.2)

where p1 and p2 are the prices charged by Firms 1 and 2, respectively. These demand functions have been used by Singh and Vives (1984) to study the price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly setting and by Dixit (1979) to analyze the entry choice of new firms producing differentiated products and facing an established firm with demand (cost) advantage. To derive demand structures in a duopoly setting for firms producing differentiated products, we follow Dixit (1979) and Singh and Vives (1984) by assuming that there is an economy consisting of two sectors: a monopolistic sector in which two firms each produce a differentiated product and a

13

competitive numeraire3 sector. Since there is no income effect on the duopoly section, the demand for each firm can be determined by partial derivative equilibrium analysis of the utility function (i.e., U (q1 , q 2 ) ), which represents the level of satisfaction that consumers derive from consuming qi amount of goods of Firm i (i =1, 2). The quadratic and strictly concave utility function, U (q1 , q 2 ) , is specified as the following when the products are produced by two firms with identical production costs.
2 )/2 U (q1 , q2 ) = ?1q1 + ? 2 q2 ? ( ?1q12 + 2?q1q2 + ? 2 q2

(1.3)

where ? i , ? i , and ? are all positive, indicating, respectively, that these two products are normal goods, satisfy the property of decreasing marginal utility, and substitute with one another. Building upon this utility formation, we can express the parameters in demand functions (1.1) and (1.2) as the following: ai =

? j? i ? ?? j ?j , ei = , 2 ?i ? j ? ? ?i ? j ? ? 2

and d =

? ?i ? j ? ? 2

for i, j =1, 2, and i ? j .

In these demand functions, the positive sign on parameters e1 , e2 suggests that market demand for the products of Firm 1 (2) decreases with the firm’s own price p1 ( p2 ) ; the positive parameter d indicates that demand for the products of Firm 1 or 2 increases with the price of the competitor, as their products are substitutes.

In partial equilibrium analysis, the entire economy is considered as a two-good model. In this model, the expenditure on all commodities other than that under consideration is assumed as a single composite commodity. Such a hypothetical composite commodity is known as numerial commodity and the assumption on numerial commodity helps the exclusion of income effect, thereby simplifying the market equilibrium analysis.

3

14

For the second scenario where Firms 1 and 2 sell products of different qualities incurring different production costs, we incorporate service premium, s, and substitution degrading factor, h, into the utility function (1.3). Herein, the revised utility function that applies to the case when two firms produce outputs with different production costs can be written as:
2 U ' (q1 , q2 ) = ?1q1 + (? 2 + s)q2 ? [ ?1q12 + 2(? ? h)q1q2 + ? 2 q2 ]/ 2

(1.4)

This utility function differs from (1.3) in two aspects. First, the positive parameter, s, represents the quality/service premium that is associated with products provided by the high-cost firm, or Firm 2. Secondly, the positive value for parameter h implies that as a result of such product differentiation, the degree of substitutability between a high quality product and a low quality product is less than that between two high or two low quality products.

Using utility Function (1.4), we get the inverse demand functions for Firms 1 and 2 under the condition that the two firms have different production costs and their products are different in service or product quality. The inverse demand functions are:

q1 = a1' ? e1' p1 + d ' p2
' ' q2 = a2 ? e2 p2 + d ' p1

(1.5) (1.6)

In these functions, a1' =

? 2?1 ? (? ? h)(? 2 + s) ' ?1 (? 2 + s) ? (? ? h)?1 , a2 = , ?1? 2 ? (? ? h) 2 ?1? 2 ? (? ? h) 2

ei' =

?j (? ? h) , and d ' = for i, j =1, 2, and i ? j . Comparing 2 ? i ? j ? (? ? h) ? i ? j ? (? ? h) 2

15

these parameters with those derived in the scenario where Firms 1 and 2 have identical production cost, we find first, d ' < d , indicating that the cross-price effects on demand are smaller when two firms have distinct production costs; second, ei' < ei , implying that the own-price effects on demand are smaller when two firms have different production costs; and finally, the sign for the difference between ai and ai' is determined by service premium, s, and substitution degrading factor, h. For example, if h=0, and s>0, then the demand for Product 1 decreases by

?s ?1? 2 ? ? 2

as the

production costs and the resulting product qualities of the two firms become dissimilar. On the other hand, the demand for Product 2, which is a high quality good, increases by

?1s . Table 1, below, presents the values for ?1? 2 ? ? 2

parameters ai and ai' , as derived from utility Functions (1.3) and (1.4), respectively. Table II-1: The Values for Market Demand Parameters, ai and ai' , under Various Scenarios Low-cost Firm (Firm 1) High-cost Firm (Firm 2) Non-differentiated products Differentiated products

a1 = a1' =

? 2?1 ? ?? 2 ?1? 2 ? ? 2 ? 2?1 ? (? ? h)(? 2 + s) ?1? 2 ? (? ? h) 2

a2 =
' a2 =

?1? 2 ? ??1 ?1? 2 ? ? 2 ?1 (? 2 + s) ? (? ? h)?1 ?1? 2 ? (? ? h) 2

The parameters shown in the top row of Table 1 are for the case when the products provided by Firms 1 and 2 are of same quality. The bottom row in the table presents the parameters associated with differentiated products under the assumption that the low-cost firm provides low quality goods, while the high-cost firm provides high quality goods. Based on the results in Table 1, we find that the product differentiation 16

strategy implemented by the high-cost firm has both positive and negative impacts on its market demand. On the positive side, the product produced by the high-cost firm becomes more appealing to customers because of the enhanced quality; on the other side, such added quality or service premium makes the high-end products less substitutable with the low-end products. Jointly, these two effects might enlarge or shrink the market demand for the products provided by the high-cost firm, depending upon the increased value for service premium, s, relative to the degree of decreased substitutability, as measured by h.

We also find that although the low-end products are less attractive to consumers, the low-cost firm might, instead, face an enlarged market demand as a result of the reduction in product substitutability. Specifically, it can be shown that the low-cost firm has greater demands in the differentiated product market as compared to the nondifferentiated product market if the following condition holds:

? s (? ? h) < h( ? ? ? + h) ? + ?

when ?1 = ? 2 = ? and ?1 = ? 2 = ? ; in addition, the high-cost firm has greater demands in the differentiated product market as compared to the non-differentiated product market if the following condition holds:

s h(? ? ? ? h)

<

? when ? (? + ? )

?1 = ? 2 = ? and ?1 = ? 2 = ? . Finally, it can be shown that when the following
equality ? 2?1 ? ?1? 2 = ? (? 2 ? ?1 ) holds, Firms 1 and 2 have identical demand parameters (i.e. a1 = a2 ) for the scenario where the two firms compete in the nondifferentiated product market. For the scenario where these two firms compete in the

17

' differentiated product market, they have identical demand parameters (i.e., a1' = a2 )

when ?1 ( ? 2 + ? ? h) = (? 2 + s )( ?1 + ? ? h) .

Now we assume that firms have constant marginal costs in Markets A and B. Firm 1’s marginal cost is denoted by c1 . The marginal cost for Firm 2 is c 2 . There are no fixed costs for Firms 1 and 2 in either Market A or B.

Given the above cost assumptions and inverse demand Functions (1.1) and (1.2), the profit for Firm 1 in Market A can be written as the following when Firms 1 and 2 are assumed to have identical production costs:

? 1A = (a1 ? e1A p1A + d A p2A )( p1A ? c1 )

(1.7)

Under the scenario where Firms 1 and 2 have identical production costs, Firm 2’s profit in Market A is:

? 2A = (a2 ? e2A p2A + d A p1A )( p2A ? c2 )

(1.8)

For Firm i (i =1, 2) to achieve positive profit outcomes, it is required that the price charged by Firm i be greater than its marginal cost (i.e., piA ? ci > 0 ) and the demand

for Firm i’s output be positive (i.e., ai ? eiA piA + d A p A j > 0 ).

In the following section, we first derive the tacit-colluding prices for firms having identical production costs in both settings of single market and multimarket contact. In a similar way, we next derive the tacit-colluding prices for firms having different production costs in both single and multimarket contexts. As for the latter case, where

18

the two firms have different production costs, we use inverse demand functions specified in (1.5) and (1.6) to derive the profit functions for Firms 1 and 2, separately.

We make a further assumption that each firm perceives the price set by its rival as a function of its own price. Thus, each firm has an expectation on the direction and magnitude of the rival firm’s price movement in responding to its own price change. Two variables, denoted as v1A , and v 2A , measure, respectively, the conjectural variation for Firm 1 and Firm 2 in Market A. Specifically, we have v1A =
dp 2A ? 0, dp1A

dp1A and v = A ? 0 . Then the first-order condition for Firm 1 to maximize its profit in dp 2
A 2

Market A can be written as:
?? 1A = (?e1A + d1A v1A )( p1A ? c1 ) + (a1 ? e1A p1A + d1A p 2A ) ?p1A

(1.9)

For Firm 2, the corresponding condition is:
?? 2A = (?e2A + d 2A v 2A )( p 2A ? c 2 ) + (a 2 ? e2A p 2A + d 2A p1A ) A ?p 2

(1.10)

Solving a system of equations (1.9) = 0, and (1.10) =0, we get the single market tacitcolluding prices for Firms 1 and 2 as the following:
p1A = f 1 A (a1 , a 2 , e1A , e2A , d1A , d 2A , v1A , v 2A , c1 , c 2 ) e2A (2e1A c1 + d1A c 2 + 2a1 ) + d1A (a 2 ? 2e2A c1v1A ) ? d 2A v 2A (e1A c1 + a1 + (c 2 ? c1v1A )d1A ) = 4e1A e2A ? 2e2A d1A v1A ? 2e1A d 2A v 2A ? d1A d 2A + d1A d 2A v1A v 2A

(1.11)

19

p 2A = f 2A (a1 , a 2 , e1A , e2A , d1A , d 2A , v1A , v 2A , c1 , c 2 )

=

e1A (2e2A c 2 + d 2A c1 + 2a 2 ) + d 2A (a1 ? 2e1A c 2 v 2A ) ? d1A v1A (e2A c 2 + a 2 + (c1 ? c 2 v 2A )d 2A ) 4e1A e2A ? 2e2A d1A v1A ? 2e1A d 2A v 2A ? d1A d 2A + d1A d 2A v1A v 2A

(1.12) The second-order condition requires that the conjectural variations for Firms 1 and 2 satisfy the following inequalities: d Av1A < e1A , and d Av2A < e2A . The restrictions imposed on these parameters imply that the firm’s own price change impacts its demand level more than does the rival firm’s follow-up retaliating price movement. Similar results can be drawn for Market B.

Now, consider the case when Firms 1 and 2 compete in multiple markets; i.e., Markets A and B. Given the above assumptions on demand functions and marginal costs, the total profit that Firm 1 obtains from selling to both Markets A and B is written as:
B ? 1A& B = (a1 ? e1A p1A + d1A p 2A )( p1A ? c1 ) + (b1 ? e1B p1B + d1B p 2 )( p1B ? c1 )

(1. 13)

When Firms 1 and 2 compete in Markets A and B simultaneously, Firm 1’s pricing behavior in Market A might initiate its rival’s reaction not only in Market A but Market B as well. We use v1AA to denote the pricing responses that Firm 1 perceives Firm 2 would take in Market A as a reaction to its price change made in Market A, and v1BA to denote the perceived pricing response of Firm 2 in Market B following Firm 1’s pricing action in Market A. Further, v1AB and v1BB represent the expected pricing reaction of Firm 2 in Market A, and B, respectively, as a response to Firm 1’s 20

pricing action in Market B. Similarly, Firm 2 has its conjectural variations denoted
BA BB . by: v2AA , v2 , v2AB , and v2

Differentiating (1.13) with respect to p1A , p1B , we obtain the first-order-conditions for Firm 1 to maximize its joint profit in Markets A and B as:
?? 1A& B = (?e1A + d Av1AA )( p1A ? c1 ) + (a1 ? e1A p1A + d A p2A ) + (d B v1BA )( p1B ? c1 ) A ?p1 ?? 1A& B B = (?e1B + d B v1BB )( p1B ? c1 ) + (b1 ? e1B p1B + d B p2 ) + (d Av1AB )( p1A ? c1 ) B ?p1

(1.14)

(1.15)

Equation (1.14) shows us how the aggregate profit for Firm 1 in Markets A and B changes with the price that Firm 1 sets in Market A. By comparing expression (1.14) with (1.9), we can easily find that the profit effect of the price change by Firm 1 in Market A when Firm 1 competes with Firm 2 in both markets is different from the effect when these two firms meet merely in a single market; i.e., Market A.

In the single market setting, Firm 1’s price change affects its profit in two ways. First, the market demand for Firm 1’s output varies with its price, as determined by the firm’s own price elasticity, and indirectly, the demand also shifts resulting from the reaction of the rival firm in responding to Firm 1’s price movement, as determined by cross-price demand elasticity. Second, the net profit margin per output is affected by the unit price. In comparison, when two firms simultaneously meet in more than one market, the price change for Firm 1 in one of these markets (e.g., Market A) has an extra impact on its profit as a result of the potential price responses taken by its rival firm in other markets (e.g., Market B). Specifically, when Firm 1 cuts its price in 21

Market A, it gets more demand in Market A, while the demand for its output in Market B might be reduced, as Firm 2 might decrease its price in Market B to retaliate against Firm 1’s aggressive pricing in Market A. This counterattack by Firm 2 in Market B is taken into consideration by Firm 1 when deciding its price in Market A. The part d B v1BA in Expression (1.14) measures the magnitude of the demand loss that Firm 1 is expected to suffer in Market B if it cut its price in Market A. The greater the perceived loss of demand in Market B, the less incentive for Firm 1 to price aggressively in Market A. According to the same rationale, Firm 1’s aggressive pricing behavior in Market B is restrained by the potential demand deteriorating effect arising from Firm 2’s counterattack in Market A. Therefore, the rivalry experienced by firms meeting in two markets simultaneously is less intense than when they compete in any of the two markets alone.

To find tacit-colluding prices in the setting of multimarket contact, we use the total profit expression for Firm 2 in Markets A and B and then differentiate this equation
B . with respect to p 2A , and p 2 B B B ? 2A& B = (a2 ? e2A p2A + d A p1A )( p2A ? c2 ) + (b2 ? e2 p2 + d B p1B )( p2 ? c2 )

(1.16)

Given a set of non-zero conjectural variations for Firm 2, we get the first-ordercondition for Firm 2’s total profit maximization problem as:
?? 2A& B BA B = (?e2A + d Av2AA )( p2A ? c2 ) + (a2 ? e2A p2A + d A p1A ) + d B v2 ( p2 ? c2 ) ?p2A

(1.17)

22

?? 2A& B B BB B B B = (?e2 + d B v2 )( p2 ? c2 ) + (b2 ? e2 p2 + d B p1B ) + d Av2AB ( p2A ? c2 ) B ?p2

(1.18)

Solving a system of equations (1.14) = 0, (1.15) = 0, (1.17) = 0, and (1.18) = 0, we
B ˆ 1A , p ˆ 1B , p ˆ 2A and p ˆ2 for Firms 1 and 2 in a multimarket get the tacit-colluding prices p

contact setting. The second-order condition for the profit maximization problem requires that the underlying parameters satisfy the following inequalities:
BB B B d < e2 ; (v) (i) v1AAd A < e1A ; (ii) v1BB d B < e1B ; (iii) v2AAd A < e2A ; (iv) v2

(2d Av1AA ? 2e1A )(2d B v1BB ? 2e1B ) > (d Av1AB + d B v1BA ) 2 ; and (vi)
BB B BA 2 (2d Av2AA ? 2e2A )(2d B v2 ? 2e2 ) > (d Av2AB + d B v2 ) .

Now, we can study the competition restraining effects of multimarket contact by comparing tacit colluding prices in a single market setting with those determined in a multimarket contact setting. Moreover, we can investigate whether multimarket contact has differential effects on collusive behavior when firms have dissimilar costs rather than identical costs. For this purpose, several numerical examples are drawn to show under what conditions the collusion enhancing effects of multimarket contact are different when firms produce differentiated goods at different levels of production costs.

23

Proposition 1. Multimarket contact facilitates tacit collusion and thus

restrains aggressive pricing behavior when the cross-price demand effect in both Markets A and B are positive (i.e., d A , d B > 0) and firms have positive conjectural variations with respect to one another (i.e., viAB , viBA > 0, i = 1, 2).

To prove this proposition, we simply need to examine whether tacitly colluding in price makes both firms more profitable in a multimarket contact setting than in a single market setting. By comparing Equation (1.14) with Equation (1.9), we find that the presence of term d B v1BA ( p1B ? c1 ) in Equation (1.14) suggests that the price change of Firm 1 in Market A has a different effect on its profitability when Firm 1 competes with Firm 2 in both Markets A and B as compared to when the two firms compete only in Market A. For a positive profit outcome, it is reasonable to assume that Firm 1’s price in Market B, p1B , is greater than its marginal production cost, c1 . Therefore, the positive value for d B v1BA implies that Firm 1 would get more profits through a tacit-colluding price in Market A when it meets Firm 2 in both markets as compared to when it meets Firm 2 in Market A alone. Similarly, the positive sign for
d Av1AB suggests that the benefits arising from a tacit-colluding price in Market B are

greater for Firm 1 when it meets Firm 2 in both markets than when it meets Firm 2 in Market B alone. The comparison of Equation (1.17) with (1.10) leads to the same
BA > 0 and d Av2AB > 0 . results for Firm 2 as long as the following conditions hold: d B v2

24

2.2 Numerical Examples

We start a series of numeral examples with a symmetric one, in which the demand structure, marginal production cost and conjectural variations for Firm 1 are identical to those for Firm 2. We also assume the cross-price demand effect, the own-price demand effect and the conjectural variations for each firm are constant across markets. As for the conjectural variation, we make a further assumption that when a firm competes in multiple markets, its conjectural variation in a given market (e.g.,
v1AA ) would be the same as if it only competed in a single market (e.g., v1A ). In fact,

an empirical question remains as to whether the values for conjectural variation become smaller or larger when there is multimarket contact formed between rival firms.

To help make the example realistic, we use the calculated average expense/available seat from our U.S. airline dataset as the value for marginal production cost ci , and the average market yield to derive values for the market size-related variables ai and bi . The set of parameters are assumed to have values as follows:
c1 = c 2 = 142 (dollars per passenger) a1 = a 2 = 107, b1 = b2 = 107
B e1A = e2A = 1 , e1B = e2 =1

d A = 0 .6 , d B = 0 .6
BA BB v1AA = v 2AA = 0.6 , v1BA = v 2 = 0.6 , v1AB = v 2AB = 0.6 , v1BB = v 2 = 0.6

25

Using these values, we get the tacit-colluding prices for Firm 1 in Market A, p1A = ˆ 1A = 215.82 under a multimarket contact setting. 190.27 in a single market setting; p This result shows that the tacit-colluding price for Firm 1 in Market A is greater when Firm 1 competes with Firm 2 in two markets than the tacit-collusive price sustained in a single market setting. Further, we can calculate the non-tacit-colluding Nash equilibrium in both single and multimarket contact settings. By assuming that all conjectural variations are zero, i.e., vijk = 0 (i =1, 2, j, k = A, B), we follow the
expression for p1A to get the non-tacit-colluding price of Firm 1 in Market A in the ˆ 1A to get the corresponding non-tacitsingle market setting, and the expression for p colluding price for a multimarket contact setting. It can be easily shown that Equation (1.14) has the same expression as Equation (1.9) when all conjectural variations are equal to zero. Under this particular case, the competitive price for Firm 1 in the single market setting has the same value as the price sustained in a multimarket contact setting. Using the assumed set of parameters, we get the competitive price ~ p1A = 177.86 , which is less than the tacit colluding price in both single and multimarket environments.

Next, we decrease the assumed values for the cross-price demand effect from 0.6 to 0.4, holding other parameters unchanged4. Using d A = 0.4 , d B = 0.4 , and other parameters assumed herein, we get the tacit-colluding price in the single market

From the utility function (see Equation 1.3), we derive the expression for parameters including ownprice demand effect, ei and cross-price demand effect denoted as d. It can be shown that the difference between ei and d is a constant. Therefore, the value for ei changes with d. As in the baseline example, the difference between ei and d is invariantly fixed at 0.4.

4

26

setting, p1A = 194.29 ; the tacit-colluding price in a multimarket contact setting, ˆ 1A = 211.72 ; and the competitive price ~ p p1A = 183.83. Consistent with Proposition 1, this result implies that multimarket contact leads to a higher tacit-colluding price, or, lower rivalry intensity than does single market competition. Moreover, we observe that the tacit colluding price enhanced through multimarket contact declines as crossprice demand effects (i.e., d A , d B ) decrease while holding other parameters invariant.

The above results suggest that the reduction in competition from multimarket contact, as evidenced by the higher equilibrium price, is increasing with the value for crossprice elasticity, ceteris paribus. As the products of Firm 1 and Firm 2 get more substitutable, firms obtain greater additional benefits from tacit collusion in the multiple market context compared to the single market context. Figure 1 graphically illustrates this point, showing that the difference in the tacit colluding price between the multimarket and single market settings enlarges with the parameter for the crossprice demand effect, or, d j (j = A, B). Note that the feasible range for d j (j = A, B) is within [0.25, 0.85] when the set of conjectural variation parameters takes the value of 0.6. The restrictions imposed on d j (j = A, B) serve to guarantee the strictly concave property of the profit function and a price that is, at least, as great as marginal cost.

27

Figure II-1: Competing, Tacit-colluding Prices in Single and Multimarket Settings
225

Multimarket colluding price for Firm 1 in Market A

215

205

195

Single-market colluding price for Firm 1 in Market A

185

175

Non-colluding price for Firm 1 in Market A
0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 0.55 0.6 0.65 0.7 0.75 0.8 0.85

165

Cross-price effect (d)

It can also be shown that that the difference in tacit-colluding prices between the multimarket context and the single market setting varies with the levels of conjectural variation, ceteris paribus. When two rival firms form high conjectural variations with respect to each other, they perceive greater response threats. As a result, the benefits from tacit-collusion in the multimarket context increase. Figure 2 presents the tacitcolluding prices for Firm 1 in Market A for the multimarket contact and single market settings. It reveals that the tacit-colluding price facilitated through multimarket contact rises with conjectural variation, which ranges from 0.05 to 0.8 given a fixed cross-price parameter d j of 0.6 (j=A, B). Under the assumed values for other key parameters, the non-tacit-colluding price for Firm 1 in Market A is constant at ~ p1A = 177.857 and is always less than the tacit colluding prices associated with both multimarket and single market settings.

28

Collusion, when successful, will raise price above the competitive level under single market competition. The more inelastic the demand for the product at the competing price level, the higher the collusive price that is expected to hold in the market (Rosenbaum and Manns 1994). As shown in Figure 3, the tacit-colluding price in a single market context rises when consumer demands for each firm become more inelastic. In contrast, the tacit-colluding price in a multimarket contact setting decreases as price elasticity, ei, falls from 1.35 to 0.8, ceteris paribus5. Figure 3 also reveals that at a given level of own-price elasticity, the tacit-colluding price for Firm 1 in a multimarket contact setting is higher than when Firm 1 competes with Firm 2 in a single market. Moreover, such an increase in price due to multimarket contact gets larger as the demands for Firm 1 (2)’s products become less elastic with Firm 1(2)’s own price.

Figure II-2: Competing, Tacit-colluding Prices in Single and Multimarket Settings
($) 275 260 245 230 215 200 185 170 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 0.55 0.6 0.65 0.7 0.75 0.8

Multimarket colluding price for Firm 1 in Market A Single-market colluding price for Firm 1 in Market A Non-colluding price for Firm 1 in Market A

Conjectural variations (v)

As indicated in the previous note, the value for the cross-price demand effect, d, varies with ownprice demand effect, ei. The difference between these two parameters is fixed at 0.4, as prescribed in the baseline model.

5

29

The finding that the collusion enhancing impact of multimarket contact is greater when a firm has a higher own-price demand effect can be explained as follows. In a single market setting, the nature of demand price-elasticity affects firms in making collusive or aggressive decisions. In a particular market environment, where demand is less sensitive to price, it is more likely for firms to collude. On the contrary, firms tend to compete more intensely in price when demand has a higher price elasticity. Under this situation, there will be greater potential for collusion enhancing effects from multimarket contact. Therefore, the increase in tacit-colluding prices as a result of multimarket contact will get larger as demands throughout markets become more sensitive to product price.

235

($) Multimarket colluding price for Firm 1 in Market A

225

215

205

Single-market colluding price for Firm 1 in Market A

195

185

175

Non-colluding price for Firm 1 in Market A
0.8 0.85 0.9 0.95 1 1.05 1.1 1.15 1.2 1.25 1.3 1.35

165

Own-price demand effect (ei)

Figure II-3: Competing, Tacit-colluding Prices in Single and Multimarket Settings So far, we have shown that when markets are identical, and rival firms have identical positive conjectural variations and positive cross-price effects on their demand functions, the tacit-colluding price for firms meeting simultaneously in two markets is always higher than what the price when the two firms meet in only one market. In the

30

following section, we explore whether multimarket contact has a greater impact on competitive behavior between two rival firms having similar production costs as compared to firms having dissimilar production costs.

Proposition 2. The tacit-collusion enhancing effects of multimarket contact

are greater when it occurs between firms with similar production costs than when it occurs between firms with dissimilar productions costs.

In the preceding section, we showed that when two firms produce differentiated products incurring different levels of production costs, the degree of substitutability between a high quality and a low quality product is less than that between two high quality products or two low quality products. With the presence of a positive substitution degrading factor, h, the cross-price effect on demand (as denoted by d) will be smaller when firms have dissimilar production costs compared to when they have identical production costs. As products provided by the two rival firms become less substitutable, it is also reasonable to assume that the conjectural variation one firm has with respect to another declines in value. From the analytical results, we find that the collusion enhancing effects of multimarket contact are jointly determined by the value of the cross-price demand parameter, d, and the conjectural variation, v. The greater these parameters, the more effective multimarket contact is at facilitating collusive behavior. As such, the degree of implicit collusion enhanced through multimarket contact is greater when multimarket contact is formed between firms with similar production costs than between firms with dissimilar production costs.

31

To graphically illustrate Proposition 2, we develop numerical examples in which the differences in production costs between Firms 1 and 2 are gradually amplified from zero to $56.80 (i.e., 40% of the marginal cost incurred by the high-cost firm). Table 2 lists a set of values for conjectural variation, v, that decrease in sync with the crossprice demand parameter, d, as the cost differences between the two firms become larger. For example, when Firms 1 and 2 have identical costs of $142 per passenger, the values for d and v are assumed to be at the highest level of 0.8. As Firms 1 and 2 become dissimilar in their production costs, the values for d and v are linearly reduced from 0.8 to zero. Table II-2: The Values for Key Parameters Associated with Firms 1 and 2 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

C1 C2

142 142 0.8 0.8

135.5 142 0.7 0.7

129 142 0.6 0.6

122.5 142 0.5 0.5

116 142 0.4 0.4

109.5 142 0.3 0.3

103 142 0.2 0.2

96.5 142 0.1 0.1

90 142 0 0

dj
vijk

Other parameters used in these examples are assumed to have the following values.
a1 = a 2 = 185, b1 = b2 = 185
B e1A = e2A = 1.3 , e1B = e2 = 1.3 6

Using this specification, we calculate, for each pair of firm production cost levels, the competing prices for Firms 1 and 2 in Market A, and their corresponding tacitcolluding prices in both single market and multimarket contact settings. Results
6

In the baseline Example (1), the value for own-price demand effect

eij is 1.3, which ensures the

satisfaction of the second-order condition for the profit maximization problem. In other examples from (2) to (9), the values for fixed at 0.5.

eij decline with d j , holding the difference between these two parameters

32

plotted in Figure 4 are for Firm 1 under various scenarios from (1) to (9). Figure 5 presents the results for Firm 2. Figure II-4: Competing, Tacit-colluding Prices for Low-cost Firm in Single and Multimarket Settings
($) 375

350

325

300

Multimarket tacit-colluding price for Firm 1 in Market A
Single-market tacit-colluding price for Firm 1 in Market A
Non-colluding price for Firm 1 in Market A
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

275

250

225

200

Note that the left-most example in Figure 4 represents Scenario (1), where Firms 1 and 2 have identical marginal production costs. With the reduction in Firm 1’s production cost from Scenario (2) through (9), Firms 1 and 2 have widening differences in their production costs, holding Firm 2’s production cost at a fixed level. Consistent with Proposition 2, we find from Figure 4 that the collusion facilitating effects of multimarket contact are greater when rival firms have identical production costs than when they have different levels of production cost. We also find that such impacts of multimarket contact on firm collusive behavior erode as the production costs of the two rival firms become more dissimilar.

33

Figure II-5: Competing, Tacit-colluding Prices for High-cost Firm in Single and Multimarket Settings
($) 375

350

325

Multimarket tacit-colluding price for Firm 2 in Market A
Single-market tacit-colluding price for Firm 2 in Market A

300

275

250

225

Non-colluding price for Firm 2 in Market A
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

200

As shown in Figure 5, similar results hold for the high-cost firm, Firm 2. Comparing results in Figure 5 with those shown in Figure 4, we find that the high-cost firm experiences a similar pattern of collusion decreasing impacts from multimarket contact; that is, multimarket contact becomes less effective in facilitating collusive pricing behavior when the rival firms have greater dissimilarity in their production costs.

3. Empirical Analysis
The conjectural variation model and several numerical examples developed in Section 2 illustrate how multimarket contact serves to facilitate tacit-collusive pricing behaviors for firms under various scenarios. The analytical results suggest that the mutual forbearance effect arising from multimarket contact is moderated by marketrelated characteristics such as own-price and cross-price demand elasticities, and the level of a firm’s production cost, relative to its rival’s. In the following section, we

34

develop two hypothesis and use data from the U.S. airline industry to test them. Empirical evidence provides validation of the analytical results.
3.1 Hypotheses

The mutual forbearance view suggests that rival firms with a high degree of multimarket contact tend to collude rather than compete as a result of the mutual deterrence effect (see Proposition 1). According to this view, the rivalry intensity experienced by an airline on a given route is negatively related to the extent of multimarket contact the carrier has with its focal market rivals. In the airline industry, one widely used measure for rivalry intensity is yields, or airfares per mile flown (e.g., Evans and Kessides 1994, Gimeno 1999, and Gimeno et al. 1999). Generally speaking, the more intense the competition between carriers, the lower the yields that are expected on a given route, ceteris paribus. Therefore, Hypothesis 1 is formally stated as:

H1. The yields for a carrier on a given route are higher when the carrier has a greater extent of multimarket contact with its rival carriers.

Through multimarket contact, firms are endowed with more opportunities to deter their rivals from pricing aggressively. The mutuality of such forbearance actions, however, may not hold when firms differ substantially in their cost structures (see Proposition 2). In the context of the U.S. airline industry, Dresner and Windle (1996 and 1999) find empirical support for the point that a low-cost carriers, or LCCs, focus on price-sensitive passengers providing no-frills service, whereas high-cost “full

35

service carriers”, or FSCs, offer superior service to travelers who are not as sensitive to airfares. As the services offered by high-cost and low-cost carriers become more differentiated in quality, smaller cross-price effects on demand would be expected. Therefore, the following hypothesis is proposed:

H2. Multimarket contact between carriers with similar production costs has a greater positive effect on yields than that between carriers with different levels of production costs.
3.2 Empirical Models

The two hypotheses are tested using data from the U.S. domestic airline market. The reasons why we focus on the airline industry are two-fold. First, airport-pair routes can be used to specify market scope without causing ambiguity. Thus, we can follow existing empirical studies (e.g., Evans and Kessides 1994, Baum and Korn 1999, Gimeno 1999, and Gimeno and Woo 1999) to measure the extent of multimarket contact by counting the overlapping routes served by any two carriers. More importantly, carrier costs in the airline industry are not private information, and cost differences between carriers are relatively consistent across routes. Typically, a lowcost carrier has its cost advantage over a high-cost carrier on all the routes in which they compete. The main input factors, such as labor and fuel, are invariant on a per unit basis across routes. Some route-related costs (e.g., airport landing fees) do not vary across carriers for the same aircraft type. All these characteristics make this industry ideal to test the differential competitive effects of multimarket contact, depending upon cost differences between carriers.

36

To test Hypothesis 1, we follow the modeling approach by Evans and Kessides (1994) to estimate the reduced-form price model specified as Equation (1.19). The unit analysis in our study is the yield for an individual airline on an airport-pair route.

ln (Yield)ir = ?0 + ?1 ln (Route HHI)r + ?2 ln(Route Market Share)ir+?3 ln (Airport HHI)r + ?4 ln (Airport Market Share)ir +?5 ln (Route Distance)r +?6 ln(Market Size)r +?7 (Slot Controlled)r +?8 ln(MMC)ir +?9 (Low-Cost Rival)ir +
10 i i =1,... N ?1

??

(Carrier )i + ? ir

(1.19)

The dependent variable (Yield)ir is the average one-way airfare for airline, i, on route, r, divided by the route non-stop distance. To control for the impact of market concentration on airfare, we include the Herfindahl indices on both route and airport levels, denoted by Route HHI, and Airport HHI. The degree of market concentration for a given route is calculated as the sum of squared market shares for all carriers flying on the route. Similarly, Airport HHI calculates the summed squares of the market shares for all the airlines at a given airport. Then we use the maximum HHI at the two endpoint airports to measure the airport-based market concentration level for a particular route.

A number of studies have found that an airline’s fare is positively related to its operation size at the route endpoint airports, well known as the hub premium effect (Borenstein 1989). We control for this market power effect by using (Airport Market Share)ir, which is the maximum of the market shares for carrier, i, at its endpoint airports on route, r. We also take into account the market power effect for carriers

37

having dominant positions on a particular route by using (Route Market share)ir, which measures the percentage of all passengers flying on route, r, that travel with airline, i. Moreover, Windle and Dresner (1995) find that the presence of low-cost carriers in an air traveling market results in significantly lower average fares for all carriers on the route. Hence, we include a dummy variable, (Low-cost Rival)ir, to indicate whether the focal carrier, i, has a low-cost rival on route, r. Market concentration, market power, and the low-cost carrier’s participation are factors all affecting the actual competitive level in the airline market.

The airline market is disciplined by potential competition as well. For instance, average airfares have been found to be higher on routes with slot-controlled endpoint airports. This finding supports the point that in an airline market, potential entrants are effectively deterred by slot control restrictions imposed on the airport. Accordingly, we control for this potential deterrence effect by using the dummy variable, (Slot Controlled)r, to indicate whether one or both endpoints on route, r, are slot-controlled.

The other two control variables included in the reduced-form price equation are Route Distance, and Market Size. Route Distance refers to non-stop distance, and Market Size measures the total number of passengers on a given route. It is widely known that airline operations are characterized by economies of distance and economies of density, and as a result, the average cost per passenger mile decreases with flight

38

distance and with traffic volume. In Equation (1.19), we expect the coefficients for ln(Route Distance)r and ln(Market Size)r to be negative.

The independent variable (MMC)ir measures the degree of multimarket contact for airline i on route r. As suggested in Hypothesis 1, the greater the (MMC)ir, the lower the rivalry intensity between carrier i and its competitors, and thus the higher the airfare for carrier, i, or (Yield)ir. To take into account carrier heterogeneity, we incorporate firm dummy variables, (Carrier)i, in Equation (19). After controlling for these fixed carrier effects and market-related effects on airfares, we interpret the coefficient for (MMC)ir as the impact of multimarket contact on a carrier’s yield.

The above empirical model is developed to estimate the overall effects of multimarket contact on pricing behaviors of carriers. Hypothesis 2 goes one step further by investigating the differential impacts of multimarket contact between carriers with similar cost levels, and between carriers with dissimilar cost levels. For a focal carrier on a given route, two additional multimarket contact variables are constructed. One measures the extent of the overlapping routes between the focal carrier and all of its rival carriers ranked in the same group according to operating expenses; the other measure captures the degree of multimarket contact between the focal carrier and all of its rival carriers belonging to the different group on the basis of operating costs. This approach requires that the sample carriers be grouped into low- and high-cost categories. The price equation to be estimated is specified as follows:

39

ln (Yield)ir = ?0 + ?1 ln (Route HHI)r +?3 ln(Route Market Share)ir + ?3 ln (Airport HHI)r + ?4 ln (Airport Market Share)ir +?5 ln (Route Distance)r +?6 ln(Market Size)r +?7 (Slot Controlled)r + ?hh (HHMMC)ir + ? hl (HLMMC)ir+ ?ll (LLMMC)ir + ?8 (Low-Cost Rival)ir +
9i i =1,... N ?1

??

(Carrier )i + ? ir

(1.20)

where (HHMMC)ir measures the multimarket contact between high-cost carrier i and its high-cost rivals on route, r; the variable (LLMMC) measures the multimarket contact between low-cost carrier i, and its low-cost rivals on route, r; and (HLMMC)ir is the multimarket contact measure for high- or low-cost carrier i with all of its rivals positioned in the opposite cost group. From the estimated coefficients for these variables, we can examine whether multimarket contact between carriers with similar cost levels impacts collusive behaviors differently from when multimarket contact occurs between carriers with dissimilar cost levels.
3.3 Data

The data used in this study are from Department of Transportation - DB1A (as provided by Database Product Inc), and from the Bureau of Transportation Statistics (BTS). DB1A contains the 10% Origin & Destination ticket survey data that can be used to determine a number of airline-route specific variables, such as yields for airport-pair markets, route distance, the average number of coupons per ticket, and the number of passengers on the route. BTS provides airline financial data and airport-related data, for example, the total number of passengers traveling into and out of an airport. The sample we collected includes the top 1,000 U.S. domestic routes in the year 2002. We use the complete dataset to calculate route specific characteristics, such as Route HHI and Airport HHI. Then, we exclude those carriers flying less than

40

1% of the total passengers on a route, and carriers flying fewer than 10 routes. This sampling approach follows the data filtering procedure used by Evans and Kessides (1994). The final sample includes 4,667 observations from 998 routes and 19 carriers. There are 89 endpoint airports. The 4 slot-controlled airports in the year 2002 are: Chicago O’Hare (ORD), New York City’s John F. Kennedy and LaGuardia (JFK, LGA) and Washington D.C.’s Reagan National (DCA).
3.4 Measurement of Multimarket Contact – MMC

Multimarket contact has been measured in several different ways. The most widely used approach is to count the number of markets in which firms compete against one another. In the context of the airline industry, the number of overlapping routes served by airlines is used to measure the extent of multimarket contact between carriers (e.g., Evans and Kessides 1994; Gimeno and Woo 1996). Building on this measurement, we construct a carrier-route specific MMC index capturing the extent of multimarket contact for each carrier on the route. First, we count the number of contacts between any pair of carriers i and j across all routes (r =1…R) as Aij: Aij =

?D
r =1

R

ir

D jr , where Dir is a dummy variable that equals 1 if airline i flies on route

r, and 0 otherwise, and Djr equal 1 if airline j flies on route r, and 0 otherwise. Next the multimarket contact MCij between airlines i and j, Aij, is scaled by the summation of the number of routes each carrier flies. The formula for MCij is: MCij = Aij (? Dir ) + (? D jr )
r =1 r =1 R R

.

41

Using this formula, the range of the value for MCij is within [0, 0.5]. Finally, the multimarket contact for carrier i on route r, MCir, is averaged across all of its competitors on route r. The expression for MCir is:

?D
MCir =
j =1

N

jr

* MCij , where N is the total number of carriers in the dataset ( i ? j ).
jr

?D
j =1

N

Table 3, below, presents the description and summary statistics for all the variables we use in the estimation. Table II-3: Descriptive Statistics for the Key Variables
Variable Yield Route HHI Route Market share Airport HHI Description Average one-way airfare charged by airline i on route r. Non-stop route distance is used to obtain Yield as price measure. [Dollar/Mile] Sum of squared market shares of all carriers flying on route r. The percentage of passengers on route r that fly with airline i. Sum of squared market shares of all carriers at the airport. For carrier i on route r, the maximum HHI of the two endpoints is carrier i’s airport HHI on route r. The maximum market share for carrier i on the two endpoint airports of route r. Non-stop distance on route r. [Miles] Total number of passengers on route r. Dummy variable (1-either one or both endpoint airports are slot controlled). In 2002, there were four slot controlled airports: ORD, JFK, LGA and DCA. Multimarket contact index for carrier i on route r. Adjusted operating cost for carrier i on route r. [Dollar/seat-mile] Mean and (Std. Deviation) 0.1407 (9.031e-02) 0.4352 (0.1870) 0.1944 (0.2421) 0.3523 (0.1470) 0.2108 (0.2082) 1,296.20 (656.45) 21,529.16 (18120.38) 0.15 (0.35) 0.2948 (0.1038) 0.1108 (3.1283e-02)

Airport Market share Distance Market size Slot controlled

MMC Expenses/ASM

3.5 Estimation of Airline Expenses/ASM

Airlines annually report to the DOT their total operating expenses. We use operating expenses per available seat-mile as an overall cost measure for each carrier.

42

Operating Expenses/ASM is an approximate assessment of the carrier’s cost level. In the airline industry, operating characteristics such as stage length contribute to economies of distance. Stage length is the distance of a flight leg. On average, the longer a carrier’s average stage length, the lower the average cost per mile incurred. To account for such economies of distance, we modify Expenses/ASM by using the elasticity of Expenses/ASM to stage length. The elasticity can be estimated by the following log-linear model: ln( Exp / ASM ) i = ? ln( D) i +? i , in which (D)i is the average flight length for carrier i and ? i is the error term.

ˆ equals -0.365. Using the estimated value for ? ˆ , we adjust The estimated elasticity ? each carrier’s overall expenses per available seat mile by the formula:
( Exp / ASM ) * i = ( Exp / ASM ) i * ( Di ?0.365 ) D
19

where D is the average stage length for all carriers (i.e., D = ? Di / 19 ). After the
i =1

stage length adjustment, ( Exp / ASM ) * i reflects the overall unit cost for each carrier. Taking the average ( Exp / ASM ) * i for all carriers as a cutoff value, we classify the sampled carriers into high-cost and low-cost groups. Table 4 presents the ranking
7 results based on adjusted ( Exp / ASM ) * i.

7

The high-cost group represents, roughly, the pre-deregulation or “legacy” carriers while the low-cost group represents, roughly, the post-deregulation entrants into the U.S. interstate air transport market.

43

Table II-4: Low-Cost and Hight-Cost Carriers
Carrier EXP/ASM (Dollar/Seat -Miles) 0.1390 0.1139 0.1114 0.1386 0.1154 0.1015 0.1032 0.1062 0.0988 0.0769 0.0809 0.0832 0.0807 0.0735 0.0643 0.0847 0.0739 0.0472 0.0249 Adjusted (Exp/ASM) (Dollar/Seat -Miles) 0.1253 0.1194 0.1176 0.1106 0.1071 0.1054 0.0979 0.0958 0.0891 0.0851 0.0840 0.0813 0.0798 0.0753 0.0737 0.0718 0.0667 0.0554 0.0235 Num of Rts Served 480 595 648 12 27 442 743 477 53 115 319 126 41 35 28 154 399 26 12 Average Flight Distance (Miles) 684.20 1036.05 1054.30 490.13 742.36 1008.22 788.66 686.70 686.50 1200.33 1009.32 854.92 881.75 970.77 1323.50 577.72 686.30 1408.82 775.80 High-cost/ Low-cost H H H H H H H H H L L L L L L L L L L

US Airways United Airlines American Airlines Midway Airlines Midwest Express Continental Airlines Delta Airlines Northwest Airlines Alaska Airlines American Trans America West Airlines Frontier Airlines Vanguard Airlines Spirit Airlines Jet Blue Airlines Airtran Southwest Airlines National Airlines Sun County Airlines

4. Results Tables 5 and 6, respectively, present the estimation results for Models 1 and 2, as shown by Equations (1.19) and (1.20). Three versions of each of the models are estimated. For Model 1, the classic OLS results show a positive and significant coefficient for Ln(MMC), supporting the tacit-collusion facilitating effect of multimarket contact. Consistent with Hypothesis 1, the airfare is found to be higher when a carrier has extensive market contact with its rivals, holding other variables constant. In addition, the results show that the presence of a low-cost rival has a significantly negative effect on yields, suggesting that airfares are lower when a carrier has low-cost rivals on a route, as compared to the situation where all of its competing carriers are high-cost, ceteris paribus.

44

From the classic OLS estimation results for Model 1, we also find that airport concentration, and airport market share, as expected, contribute to airfare premiums of various magnitudes. The airport concentration variable endows the airline with the most pricing power, followed by airport market share. The price elasticity associated with Airport HHI is 0.1919, which is 3.67 times as large as the elasticity related to Airport Market Share. On the other side, Route HHI is found to be negative, but insignificant. Moreover, we find that airfares are, ceteris paribus, higher on routes where either or both endpoint airports are slot controlled. Also implied is that the airfares decrease as route distance, or market size increases, holding other variables constant. Table II-5: Estimation Results for Model One
OLS estimates Fixed-effects estimates Random-effects estimates
Coefficient Coefficient Coefficient (t-statistics) (t-statistics) (t-statistics) 3.3709a 3.5436a 4.0197a Constant (42.48) (41.32) (43.20) -0.0003 0.0041 0.00346 Ln (Route HHI) (-0.03) (0.41) (0.34) c b 0.00735 -0.0056 -0.0084 Ln (Route Market Share) (-1.32) (1.72) (-1.97) a a 0.1919 0.1681a 0.1661 Ln (Airport HHI) (20.68) (18.76) (18.99) a 0.09576a 0.1018a Ln (Airport Market Share) 0.05234 (9.93) (16.92) (16.32) -0.61827a -0.61670a -0.6163a Ln (Distance) (-80.29) (-84.44) (-84.38) a a -0.06707 -0.06913a -0.0675 Ln (Market Size) (-11.12) (-11.79) (-12.07) a a 0.1427 0.1151a 0.1134 Slot Controlled (13.57) (11.24) (11.39) 0.08212a 0.1073a 0.1482a Ln (MMC) (10.54) (8.36) (7.67) -0.0509a -0.08223a -0.0793a Low-cost Rival (-5.63) (-8.90) (-9.31) 4667 4667 4667 Number of observations 0.7486 0.7816 0.7421 R2 a b Significant at 0.01 level , Significant at 0.05 level , Significant at 0.1 level c; The estimated coefficients for the carrier dummy variables are omitted in the column for the fixed-effects model.

Independent Variables

45

Table II-6: Estimation Results for Model Two
Independent Variable Constant Ln (Route HHI) Ln (Route Market Share) Ln (Airport HHI) Ln (Airport Market Share) Ln (Distance) Ln (Market Size) Slot Controlled Low-cost rival Multimarket Contact between high-cost and high-cost carrier Multimarket Contact between low-cost and low-cost carrier Multimarket Contact between high-cost and low-cost carrier Number of observations R2 Fixed-effects estimates Coefficient (t-statistics) 3.639a (42.57) 0.0071 (0.70) -0.00741c (-1.73) 0.1625a (18.37) 0.0998a (16.59) -0.6217a (-84.14) -0.0725a (-12.67) 0.10630a (10.42) -0.1025a (-7.57) 0.5695a (8.91) 0.4687a (4.38) -0.05173 (-0.78) 4667 0.7833 Random-effects estimates Coefficient (t-statistics) 3.3112a (41.77) 0.00582 (0.58) -0.0056 (-1.33) 0.1642a (18.56) 0.0957a (16.41) -0.6211a (-84.17) -0.0727a (-12.68) 0.1074a (10.53) -0.1031a (-7.81) 0.5006a (8.67) 0.5298a (5.15) -0.0492 (-0.76) 4667 0.7476

Significant at 0.01 levela, Significant at 0.05 levelb,Significant at 0.1 levelc; The estimated coefficients for the carrier dummy variables are omitted in the column for the fixed-effects model.

Since Market Size is defined as the total number of passengers on a given route, this aggregate measure of demand is most likely to be independent of the error term in the airfare regression. Nevertheless, other market structure variables, such as Route HHI and Airport Market Share, are potentially endogenous and thus may be correlated with the error term, ? ir , in airfare regressions. To address this potential issue, we include carrier-specific dummy variables in our model. Columns 3 and 4 of Table 5 report the estimation results using fixed-effects and random-effects models.

46

Comparing the classic OLS results (Column 2 of Table 5) to the results from the fixed-effects model (Column 3), we find that the coefficients for Ln(MMC) and for Ln(Airport Market Share) estimated by the fixed-effect model are twice as large as the respective coefficients estimated by the classic OLS regression. The fixed-effects estimation shows that the airline-specific effects account for 35.02% of the sample variation in the average airfare per mile. A comparison of the R-squared values indicates that the fixed-effects model provides a better goodness of fit than does the OLS model, which is not including carrier specific effects. It is further found that the coefficient for Route Market Share is, unexpectedly, negative in the estimation of the fixed-effects regression. The high correlation between Route Market Share and Airport Market Share (see Table 7) likely contributes to this result8. Table II-7: Correlation among Market Structure Variables
Airport HHI Airport HHI Airport Market Share Route HHI Route Market Share 1.0000 0.2334 0.3878 0.0918 Airport Market Share 1.0000 0.2074 0.7786 Route HHI Route Market Share

1.0000 0.2349

1.0000

In the estimation of the fixed-effects model, variance inflation factors (VIF) are computed to diagnose whether collinearity among some independent variables poses a serious concern for estimation reliability. We find that the values of VIF for all predictors are less than 10, indicating that multicollinearity is likely not a concern (Mason et al. 1991).

The alternative regression is also run for Model 1 after removing the variable, Route Market Share. The estimated coefficients for all other predicating variables are similar to the regression results in the original fixed-effects model.

8

47

The unit observation for the dependent variable in our estimation is average one-way airfare per mile for an individual airline on a given route. In this situation the errors for the same carrier are likely to be correlated across routes, or cov(eir , eit ) ? 0 . Within-route errors are likely correlated between carriers as well, or cov(eir , e jr ) ? 0 . If either of these cases occurs, the i.i.d. assumption for the error term will be violated, and the variance-covariance matrix estimated by the fixed-effects model will be biased, thereby making the further inferences invalid. Therefore, it is important to examine whether the results based on the fixed-effects model are robust to alternative estimation procedures, such as a GLS random-effects model.

The GLS random-effects model allows for stochastic regressors but relies upon the assumption of no correlation between predictors and the error term. Its estimators are asymptotically unbiased and more efficient. Column 5 of Table 5 presents the results for the random-effects model. A Hausman specification test is performed to examine whether the coefficients estimated by the fixed-effects model are statistically different from those estimated by the GLS random-effects model. The resulting chi-square statistic is 4.28 with 8 degree of freedom, which is insignificant at the 5 percent level. Thus, we cannot reject the null hypothesis that the coefficients estimated by the two procedures are the same.

Table 6 presents the results for Model 2, which examines whether the impact on firm collusive behavior is the same when multimarket contact occurs between firms with similar cost levels compared to when it takes place between firms with different cost

48

levels. Two variations of the model are estimated. From the fixed-effects estimation results, we find that the multimarket contact variables for carriers with similar costs have the expected signs and are statistically significant. Specifically, the positive coefficient for Multimarket Contact between high-cost and high-cost carriers indicates that the airfares for a high-cost carrier are higher on routes where it has more overlapping contacts with its high-cost rivals. Similarly, the positive coefficient for Multimarket Contact between low-cost and low-cost carriers suggests that airfares for a low-cost carrier are higher on routes where it has more overlapping markets with its low-cost counterparts. To see whether these two coefficients are statistically different, we run a restricted model where the two coefficients are constrained to be identical. The relevant F statistic comparing the unrestricted with the restricted regression is derived as F1, 4639 = 0.573, which is less than the critical value at the 5% level of significance. Therefore, we cannot reject the null hypothesis that the coefficient for multimarket contact between high-cost and high-cost carriers is the same as that for multimarket contact between low-cost and low-cost carriers. This result implies that multimarket contact between firms with similar cost levels has a positive effect on airfares, and it may not matter whether these rival firms are both high-cost, or both low-cost.

In comparison, the coefficient for Multimarket contact between high-cost and lowcost carrier is statistically insignificant. This finding supports our hypotheses that when multimarket contact is between carriers with dissimilar cost levels, there is no significant impact on airfares. In this case, firms make their pricing decisions

49

independent of multimarket contact; that is, multimarket contact does not facilitate tacit-colluding behavior. From Table 6, it is also found that the coefficient for LowCost Rival is negative and statistically significant. This finding is in line with the widely-held view that the presence of low-cost rivals on a given route intensifies price competition, thereby pulling down airfares on the route. The estimation results for other variables, such as market structure, route distance, and airport slotcontrolled status, are similar to those found in Model 1. 5. Conclusions and Implications This article theoretically and empirically investigates the differential impacts of multimarket contact on tacit-collusive behaviors for firms facing varying market characteristics, and for the rival pairs having similar/dissimilar production costs. The analytical results suggest that firms obtain more tacit collusion benefits when they compete simultaneously in multiple markets rather than in a single market. Therefore, multimarket contact facilitates tacit-colluding behavior and reduces the intensity of rivalry between multimarket competitors. A key contribution of our analytical study is to show that the collusion enhancing effects of multimarket contact hold true when markets are identical and firms produce outputs with identical marginal costs, which is constant throughout markets. Under this condition, Bernheim and Whinston (1990) suggest that multimarket contact is irrelevant and does not facilitate collusion. Their findings are based upon an analytical model studying infinitely repeated Bertrand price competition between firms in the multimarket contact setting. In comparison, the conjectural variation model we develop focuses on explaining how multimarket contact restrains the competitive intensity between multimarket rivals.

50

Our analytical model demonstrates that multimarket contact is more effective in facilitating tacit collusive pricing when it occurs between rival firms having similar production costs than when it occurs between rival firms with dissimilar production costs. It is the formation of higher conjectural variation and the presence of greater product substitutability that reinforces the collusion-facilitating effects of multimarket contact for firms having similar production costs. This finding may have implications for firms competing across multiple markets. For example, when two firms compete in a local market with a single product, one option for a firm to avoid fierce competition is to distinguish itself from the rival firm by introducing differentiated products. The more dissimilar the products, the less likelihood for the occurrence of a pricing war. However, under a multimarket scenario, tacit collusion and lower rivalry intensity may be more likely to sustain when the product lines firms develop are similar to one another. Consequently, the competitive implications of a product differentiation strategy may be dramatically different for single market and multimarket contact settings.

The empirical findings verify the propositions developed in our theoretical analysis. As expected, the estimation results support the longstanding view that multimarket contact reduces interfirm rivalry intensity. Using data from the U.S. airline market, we find that airfares are higher on routes where carriers have more overlapping contacts with rival carriers, ceteris paribus. Moreover, our estimations suggest that the positive impact of multimarket contact on airfares is present in the situation when

51

rival carriers have similar production costs; when rival carriers have dissimilar production costs, multimarket contact has little impact on a carrier’s yield.

From this paper, it is found that low-cost carriers have positive reasons to engage in mutual forbearance when their rivals are also low-cost carriers. As a result, it may not be sufficient to just open airline markets to low-cost competition without any regulatory oversight. Since low-cost carriers appear to engage in tacit collusion, some regulatory oversight might still be needed. It is also important to realize that although multimarket contact enhances tacit collusive prices for both low-cost and high-cost carriers, it matters less as their products become more differentiated within and between markets.

52

Chapter 3: Essay Two - A Two-Location Inventory Model with Transshipments in a Competitive Environment
1. Introduction Due to the random nature of demand, stock discrepancies (i.e., the difference between the product amount available and the product amount demanded) are commonly observed in single-location and multiple-location distribution systems. In a singlelocation environment, this gap can be filled by having an amount of safety stock; i.e., by operating with a higher inventory level to protect against demand uncertainty. Compared with the single-location system, the multiple-location network has more alternatives to deal with demand uncertainty. Among these methods, the implementation of lateral transshipments among outlets is an effective and efficient way for firms to reduce inventory carrying cost and to improve customer service levels at the same time.

Transshipments is a practice of transferring goods from one location with excess stock to satisfy demand at another location with insufficient stock (Dong and Rudi, 2004). In many industries with long lead-times, short selling seasons, great demand uncertainty, high inventory carrying costs, and/or high penalty stockout costs, transshipments have been widely used to reallocate inventory from an overstocked outlet to an out-of-stock outlet. This practice is logically equivalent to other types of risk-pooling strategies, such as inventory centralization, postponed differentiation, component commonality, and product substitution.

53

The literature on modeling transshipments in a multi-location inventory system dates back to Krishnan and Rao (1965). The distribution network they investigate has N warehouses, characterized by centralized control, independent demand, and identical inventory holding and shortage costs for all of the locations. Their analysis indicates that under these conditions, transshipments equalize optimal inventory and service levels among stocking locations. Krishnan and Rao (1965) present a fundamental framework to study the transshipment problem in several aspects. First, they identify a sequence of events with which transshipments are assumed to occur after the demand is realized, but before it is satisfied. Second, they set the transshipment size as the minimum of the excess stock at one location and the shortage at another location. When all locations are out of stock, or all have surplus stock, transshipments do not occur. The third contribution of their analysis is that they take into account the fact that there is certain transshipment costs incurred when units are delivered from the overstocked location to the under-stocked location. Within this framework, the practice of transshipments is modeled to enable the tradeoff between the total transshipment cost and the summation of inventory holding and shortage costs.

Since then, there has been a growing body of work published on the topic of transshipments. Tagaras (1989), for example, generalizes the analysis developed by Krishnan and Rao (1965) and investigates the effect of transshipments on the customer service level, measured by both non-stockout probability and fill rate. Tagaras (1989) builds a two-location inventory distribution system, having two locations replenished by a common supplier. Unlike the model developed by

54

Krishnan and Rao (1965), Tagaras (1989) relaxes the constraints on cost structure by allowing for different ordering and holding costs at different locations. Tagaras (1989) also extends the findings by Krishnan and Rao (1965) and argues that a complete pooling policy9 improves the service levels at both locations, even if the two stocking locations have different inventory ordering and holding costs. A complete pooling policy is consistent with the transshipment policy specified by Krishnan and Rao (1989). Moreover, Tagaras (1989) finds that under certain conditions a complete pooling policy is optimal in that it achieves the minimum total expected cost in a twolocation distribution system, and it equalizes the service levels at both locations. However, such an equality of service levels for the cost minimization solution would hold only if the demand and cost structures are the same at the two locations.

The approach of minimizing the total expected cost serves as the building block for the traditional newsvendor problem. A newsvendor must determine the order size of the newspaper before observing the actual demand for today’s paper. If the order size is more than the actual demand, the newsvendor suffers a loss because the current issue has little salvage value in the future; on the other hand, if the order is less than the actual demand, the newsvendor bears a direct loss from the stock insufficiency for the current period, and an indirect loss because some of those dissatisfied customers will switch to other newsvendors in the future. For a known distribution over demand, the probabilities of stocking-out and over-stocking will depend on the inventory level

According to complete pooling policy, the number of units transshipped from one firm to another is the minimum of the excess stock at one location and the shortage at the other location. In addition, no transshipments occur if both locations are stocked out or if neither of them is out of stock.

9

55

chosen by the newsvendor. Therefore, the optimal inventory level can be determined by minimizing the expected costs of stockouts and overstocks, given the cost structure as assumed.

Many transshipment studies have applied and extended the classic newsvendor problem to a multi-newsvendor setting or a multi-period context. Of these studies, Robinson (1990) examines the optimal ordering policy (i.e., the order-up-to point) in a multi-period and multi-location system, allowing transshipments among retail outlets. Robinson (1990) demonstrates that as a recourse action, transshipping products among retail outlets is an alternative to retailers making orders at the beginning of each period, and thus has an effect on the choice of the order-up-to level. By using a heuristic technique, Robinson (1990) verifies that if the base stock order-up-to point is nonnegative in the final period, it will be the optimal order-up-to level for all other periods, assuming that transshipments occur after demands are realized and before they are satisfied for each period. In Robinson’s model, the size of transshipments is consistent with the complete pooling policy; i.e., the amount of goods transshipped between a pair of outlets is just enough to meet the shortage at the outlet with insufficient stock, but not more than what is available at the surplus location after demands are realized.

Most of these previous studies on transshipments follow the line that transshipments, as a mechanism to reallocate resources among locations at the same echelon level, benefit both the sending outlet and the receiving outlet. Through transshipments, the

56

sending outlet reduces its surplus inventory that otherwise would be less valuable, while the receiving outlet satisfies customers who might not be served otherwise. One limitation of these studies is that the two locations considered are independent, and isolated from each other. Because of this constraint, many interesting, dynamic, and strategic interactions between locations are ignored. As Herer and Reshit (1999) point out, in a two-location inventory system allowing the implementation of transshipments, each location serves as a secondary, random source of supply to the other. Therefore, the employment of transshipments between locations must have a nontrivial impact on their replenishment decisions. Herer and Reshit (1999) further demonstrate that in a two-location inventory system with nonnegligible fixed and joint replenishment costs, the traditional replenishment policy, i.e., the order-up-topoint (s, S) at each location, is no longer optimal. Instead, coordination in inventory replenishment activities is necessary to leverage the benefits from transshipments.

When inventory coordination and the implementation of transshipments are jointly considered, a central “parent” agent is assumed to help determine the order size and the transshipment quantity at each location (Rudi et al. 2001). In reality, however, transshipments are also common in a decentralized environment, in which the inventory replenishment and transshipment decisions are made locally, rather than globally. The work by Rudi et al. (2001) addresses the transshipment problem in such a local decision-making context, in which each location aims to maximize its own profit. Their analysis demonstrates that joint profits would not be maximized in the decentralized environment, without using a transshipment price. It is also found that

57

an intermediate transshipment price makes it possible for each location to choose an order size, which would lead to the maximal joint profits. According to Rudi et al. (2001), the choices of order quantities at each location in a localized decision making environment are interrelated because of the externality effect arising from the transshipment practice. Specifically, when one location orders a large inventory, it becomes easier for other locations to rely on this inventory in case of stock outs; when one location makes a small-size order, it is easier for other locations to dispose of their surplus stock.

Recently, the impact of transshipments on supplier performance has received growing attention. Dong and Rudi (2004), for instance, examine the effect of transshipments on manufacturer profits with two distinctive assumptions: (1) An exogenous wholesale price, which is the same regardless of whether transshipments occur or not; and (2) An endogenous wholesale price, which is set by the manufacturer as the best response to the optimal order quantities and the transshipment decisions made by retailers. Moreover, Dong and Rudi (2004) investigate the role that the number of retailers, and the demand correlation among them, might play in affecting the relationship between the implementation of transshipments and the profits for manufacturers and retailers. They find that in the case of an exogenous wholesale price, the transshipment practice provides retailers with greater gains as the number of retailers increases, and as demand correlation among them decreases. Both of these factors contribute to the risk-pooling effects. In the case of an endogenous wholesale price setting, however, transshipments are found to make retailers worse

58

off. Finally, their analytical results show that the benefit to the manufacturer from the implementation of transshipments is conditional upon the wholesale price in an endogenous price-setting situation. In other words, it is found that the manufacture can achieve more profits by charging a higher wholesale price. Under such an exogenous wholesale price setting, the manufacturer is further found to benefit more from the transshipment practice when more retailers are participating and when their demands are less correlated.

In the prior studies, the practice of transshipments among retailers is either voluntary or motivated by an appropriate transshipment price. One notable example is the study by Dong and Rudi (2004), in which a transshipment price is set by a Stackelberg game between the supplier and retailers. In their study, Dong and Rudi (2004) investigate a unique distribution system, in which a common manufacturer sells to n retailers that are owned or operated by the same entity. The optimal inventory level choice for each retailer is made to maximize the total expected profits of these retailers, on the condition of having an either exogeneous or endogenous wholesale price. In an earlier work by Rudi et al. (2001), the authors consider the scenario where each location makes the order quantity decision to maximize its own profit, namely a local decision setting. They find that there exists a transshipment price that enables firms to achieve the same profit outcome in a local decision setting as that in a joint-decision setting, under which the order quantities are determined to maximize the joint profits of firms. These studies, however, assume away the possibility that transshipments might be implemented among neighboring, competing locations. In

59

reality, many retail outlets are head-to-head rivals. For example, when a customer cannot get a particular automobile at one dealer site, he/she might switch to a nearby dealer to make the purchase there. Several questions remain in this situation: (1) Will transshipments occur when retailers are vying for the same pool of customers? (2) Will transshipments always lead to win-win outcomes in such a competitive environment? and (3) Will there be a transshipment price that enables a large firm to achieve the same benefits from the practice of transshipments as does a small firm?

In this essay, the transshipment problem is explored in a variety of competitive environments consisting of firms with symmetrical and asymmetrical market demands, and the comparisons are made in the performance effects of transshipments for firms operating in local and joint decision-making contexts. The model is built upon the work by Krishnan and Rao (1965), Rudi et al. (2001), and Dong and Rudi (2004). The remainder of this essay is organized as follows. The next section presents the basic modeling framework. Section 3 analyzes the case where inventory decisions are made by two firms independently. Section 4 examines the case where inventory choices are coordinated. Numerical examples are then used in Section 5 to illustrate these findings. Section 6 offers conclusions and discusses limitation and future research. 2. The Model The analysis of the classic newsvendor problem provides a useful framework to study transshipments among competing firms. In the traditional newsvendor problem setting, the research focus is mainly on specifying an optimal order level for a single

60

newsvendor. The order quantity is determined to maximize the newsvendor’s expected profit, which is composed of the revenue from selling goods, the salvage value of the unsold stock, the penalty cost for the unmet demand, and the inventory purchasing cost. It has been found that for any type of monotonic, continuous demand distribution, there always exists a unique order quantity at which the expected marginal cost of adding another unit of order stock equals the expected marginal benefit. The newsvendor’s expected profit is therefore maximized at this inventory level.

The approach of modeling a single newsvendor problem has been extended to a twolocation environment. In the context of two independent locations, the previous studies have presented a good illustration of how transshipments affect a firm’s inventory management. In reality, transshipments sometimes might occur between two firms that are coincidently competing with each other. In this setting, it is important to incorporate interfirm rivalry intensity into the analysis of the transshipment problem. Indeed, the nature of market competition can have a significant consequence on firm inventory decisions. Therefore, the conclusion drawn from previous models with respect to the implication of transshipments for performance outcomes would not hold in a competitive environment.

Consider a distribution system consisting of two distributors and a common manufacturer (or, more generally, a supplier) that produces and sells to these two firms

61

noted as i and j. At the beginning of a single order cycle, each firm decides a nonnegative inventory level Qi(j) before observing the actual demand Di(j).

To capture the extent to which one firm is a direct or close competitor of the other, the model proposes the use of a customer’s switching rate (i.e., the probability of an individual consumer switching firms in the event of stockout). Formally, let ?ij stand for the switching rate from Firm i to j. It represents the probability of an individual customer switching to Firm j, when his/her demand at Firm i’s site cannot be satisfied because of insufficient stock. At an aggregate level, ?ij indicates the percentage of customers switching to Firm j when the primary supplier, Firm i, is stocked out. The more intense the competition between firms, the higher the switching rate. Further assume that the variable ?ij is exogenously given and can take any value between 0 and 1.

Table 1 presents the notation for a series of cost parameters that are used in the model. These parameters include the unit retailing price of Firms i and j, the manufacturing cost, the wholesale price, the average inventory carrying cost, the salvage value for each unsold unit, the penalty cost for each unment demand, the unit transshipment cost, and transshipment price. Table 1 also provides the notation for other relevant variables such as the level of transshipments, the amount of actual sales, unmet demand, and unsold stock.

62

Table III-1: Notations for Key Parameters and Variables used in the Model Notation Definition pi , p j m wi , w j j s p The unit price for goods sold by Firms i and j, respectively. The unit manufacturing cost incurred by the supplier. The wholesale price paid by Firms i and j, respectively. The average inventory carrying and holding costs. The salvage value for each unsold stock. The penalty cost for each unmet unit of demand. The cost for transshipping a unit of goods from Firm i to j, and vice versa. The transshipment price paid by Firm j to i, and by Firm i to j. The level of transshipments from Firm i to j, and from Firm j to i. The actual sale of Firm i, and j. The amount of unsold stock of Firm i, and j. The amount of unmet demand of Firm i, and j. The consumer’s switching rate from Firm i to j, and from Firm j to i.

?
cij , c ji X ij , X ji Ri , R j Ui , U j Zi , Z j

? ij , ? ji

The model builds upon the sequence of events described as follows. At the beginning of the single replenishment period, shipments from the common supplier are ordered by Firms i and j to bring their stock levels to Qi and Qj. At some point in the period, all of the demands at both locations are realized and observed. Before this point in time, neither Firm i nor Firm j has complete knowledge of the actual demand for the current period. Then Firm i(j) compares the demand Di (j) with the stock level Qi (j). Four events may arise. In the first event, both firms have sufficient inventory to satisfy their demand, and thus all of the consumers are served instantly; in the second event, one firm, but not both, is out-of-stock, and the aggregate demand at the two locations exceeds the summed stock of Firms i and j; the third event specifies the situation similar to the previous one except that the joint inventory of the two locations is greater than the aggregate demands for these two firms; in the fourth

63

event, both firms are stocked out, and, as a result, the satisfied demand at each location is up to the amount of stock that Firms i, and j, hold.

The model further assumes that when one firm is out of stock while another firm has stock in redundancy, the firm having excess stock has two options to choose. Either it can transship its extra stock to the firm that is in short of supply, or it can sell to consumers switching from the out-of-stock firm. Figures 1 and 2 provide graphical illustrations of these two alternative scenarios. In Figure 1, transshipments are implemented between Firms i and j in the event of stock out and in this case, consumers will not switch but rather wait for the arrival of the transshipped goods. Figure 2 shows what happens when no transshipments are implemented. In this scenario, it is likely that consumers switch in the event of stock out.
Firm i Orders Supplier Shipments Shipments Orders Firm j Transshipments

Figure III-1: An Illustration of the Scenario with Transshipments
Firm i Orders Supplier Shipments Shipments Orders Firm j Customers* * Customers switch firms in the event of stock out

Figure III-2: An Illustration of the Scenario without Transshipments

64

Since the model considers only one replenishment period, it is reasonable to assume that firms adopt the complete pooling policy. Suppose Firm i is out of stock, while Firm j has extra stock. According to this policy, all of the transshipments requests that Firm i makes to Firm j are honored if inventory at j’s location is available. In other words, Firm j will not transship more than it has available; on the other side, Firm i will not accept more than it requests. Moreover, no transshipments will occur if both locations are out of stock or if both have extra stock.

Most previous studies have set the revenue per goods sold by the retailer as a constant r (e.g., Dong and Rudi 2004). In contrast, this model assumes that the unit price charged by Firms i and j may be different, denoted by pi and p j , respectively. The manufacturer produces to order with unit cost m and sells to Firm i(j) at the wholesale price wi(j). In addition to purchasing costs, each unit of inventory incurs carrying costs. Let j be the average holding cost for each replenishment cycle, then the carrying costs associated with the inventory level Q can be written as jQ . Further assume that the salvage value for each unsold unit is s, and the penalty cost for each unmet unit of demand is p. For the goods transshipped from Firm i to j, Firm i is responsible for the delivery and thus bears a transshipment cost ? , for each unit transshipped. In return, Firm j pays the transshipment price to Firm i, cij per unit transshipped.

No short answer can be found for the questions of whether, when, and how much to transship from one Firm to the other. The complete pooling policy, nevertheless,

65

provides a straightforward solution to this problem. Following this rule, the transshipments from Firm i to j are determined by
X ij = min[[Qi ? Di ] + , [ D j ? Q j ] + ] , where [z]+ = max [z, 0].

In this expression, the notation [Qi ? Di ] + represents the extra supply at location i and
[ D j ? Q j ] + is for the excess demand at location j. According to the complete pooling

rule, the transshipment size takes the lower value of the overstock at one location and the stock shortage at another. Similarly, the level of transshipments from Firm j to i can be written as: X ji = min[[Q j ? D j ] + , [ Di ? Qi ] + ] .

Adding the transshipments from Firm j, Firm i’s sales are the followings: Ri = min( Di , Qi ) + X ji , and its unmet demand equals: Z i = ( Di ? Qi ? X ji ) + . Deducting the transshipments to Firm j, Firm i’s unsold stock is the followings:
U i = (Qi ? Di ? X ij ) + .

Correspondingly, the following expressions hold for Firm j: R j = min( D j , Q j ) + X ij , U j = (Q j ? D j ? X ji ) + , and Z j = ( D j ? Q j ? X ij ) + . With transshipments, the expected profits for Firms i and j can be written as:

? i (Qi , Q j , cij , c ji ) = E[ pi Ri + (c ji ? ? ) X ij ? cij X ji + sU i ? pZ i ] ? wi Qi ? jQi

(2.1)

? j (Qi , Q j , cij , c ji ) = E[ p j R j + (cij ? ? ) X ji ? c ji X ij + sU j ? pZ j ] ? w j Q j ? jQ j (2.2)
The profit for the supplier is a function of order quantities made by Firms i and j, shown by the expression below:

66

? s = ( wi ? m)Qi + ( w j ? m)Q j

(2.3)

To see the role that transshipments play in reallocating resources and thus affecting a prior inventory decisions, it is necessary to draw a comparison between the cases with and without transshipments. Consider a setting when Firm i is overstocked by (Qi – Di), whereas Firm j is out of stock by (Dj – Qj). Assume no transshipments are implemented from Firm i to j. Firm j would end with (Dj – Qj) unmet demand and of those dissatisfied customers, ? ji ( D j ? Q j ) would switch to Firm i. The demand at Firm i’s site would therefore increase to Di + ? ji ( D j ? Q j ) provided sufficient stock is available to serve consumers switching from Firm j. Alternatively, Firm i can transship part or all of its extra stock to Firm j.

Although transshipments, viewed as an inventory pooling practice, have been studied mostly from the retailer’s perspective, it is important to see how the supplier fares as well. Indeed, Rudi et al. (2001) suggest that an important extension of the transshipment study in the future is to incorporate the manufacturer into the analysis. A follow-up question arises as to how to align the supplier’s interest with the retailers’ concerns or profitability. For example, if the supplier designs a constant wholesale price, its profit grows invariably with the order quantities from retailers. The more goods retailers order, the more profits the supplier gains. However, a largesize order is inevitably accompanied by high inventory-carrying costs for retailer, resulting in potential losses during periods of low demand. Therefore, a large-size order benefiting supplier may not be favored by retailer. Moreover, retailers may

67

prefer small order sizes when transshipments provide them with the opportunity to replenish their stock, incurring costs no greater than those related to lost sales or backorders. The above discussion ignores the key role of the transshipment price in realigning retailer inventory decisions with supplier profitability. In fact, the joint order quantities of retailers change nonlinearly with the transshipment price. Therefore, it is in the supplier’s interest to coordinate the retailer inventory decisions through the use of transshipment price. Moreover, if it is found that a small retailer benefits more through transshipments than its large rival counterpart, some additional incentive mechanisms might be necessary in order for the large firm to participate in the practice of transshipments with the small firm.

Previous studies of the transshipment problem have established a number of constraints on cost parameters. These assumptions are used to ensure that the results are nontrivial and feasible (Tagaras 1989, Robinson 1990, and Dong and Rudi 2004). Following their approach, the cost parameters in the model are restricted by the conditions below. (1 ) s < wi + j , s < w j + j (2) wi + j < pi + p , w j + j < p j + p (3) m < wi , m < w j (4) s + ? + j < pi + p , s + ? + j < p j + p (5) cij ? [ s + ? , pi + p ] , c ji ? [ s + ? , p j + p] Conditions (1) and (2) together exclude two extreme possibilities: Firms ordering an infinite amount, and firms not ordering at all. When the salvage value per good is 68

greater than the summation of the unit wholesale price and the inventory carrying cost, firms can always recover the cost of adding additional stock, no matter whether it is sold or not. On the other hand, when the cost of ordering additional stock is greater than the summation of the unit price and the penalty cost; i.e., the marginal value per unit sold, firms have no willingness to distribute the product.

For the manufacturer or the common supplier to participate in the system, it is necessary that the unit manufacturing cost be less than the wholesale price, as shown in Condition (3). The inequality in Condition (4) suggests that transshipments, in general, are beneficial because the salvage value of the unit stock at one location, if not transshipped, is less than the revenue from selling it to another location, minus the cost incurred in transshipping and holding the good.

Condition (5) provides a feasible range for the transshipment price. The lower bound of this range is the total of the salvage value, and the transshipment cost, per unit good. It can be viewed as a reservation price for the firm sending the transshipped goods. From the sender’s perspective, it will not transship the goods to another location unless it gets a payment exceeding such a reservation price. The upper bound of this range represents the marginal value of an additional sale, which is the summation of the unit market price and the penalty cost per lost sale. Similarly, it can be viewed as a reservation price for the firm accepting the transshipped goods. On the recipient’s side, it will accept the transshipped goods only if the transshipment price it pays is less than such a reservation value. Therefore, only a transshipment price

69

restricted within this range can satisfy both the sender and the recipient (Note: cij represents the transshipment price paid by Firm i to j, and cji is the other way).

Although the following sections focus on studying expected profits for firms and their inventory decisions in a stochastic demand environment, it is necessary to describe the occurrence of transshipments in each of various scenarios, as presented in Figure 3. Figure III-3: Graphic Illustration of Scenarios Dj

II III Qj IV V

I

VI

Qi

Qi + Qj

Di

In this graph, Di, Dj represent the demand size at Firm i’s and Firm j’s locations, respectively. Qi and Qj are the order quantities that Firms i and j replenish at the beginning of the order cycle. In a single-period planning horizon, six scenarios can arise. Event I represents the scenario where Firms i and j are both out of stock. Event IV, on the contrary, is the scenario where Firms i and j are both overstocked. Intuitively, these two events involve no transshipments. Of particular interest are the other four events.

70

In Event II, Firm j has demand Dj that is more than its inventory stock Qj, while Firm i has demand Di that is less than its inventory stock Qi. In other words, Firm i has surplus stock (Qi - Di), and Firm j is out of stock by (Dj – Qj). Therefore, a transshipment is directed from Firm i to j. Similarly, in Event III, Firm j is stocked out, whereas Firm i is overstocked; thus Firm i transships its extra stock to Firm j. Although the directions of transshipments in Events II and III are the same, the quantities transshipped are different. A close look at the graph shows that in Event II, the total demand for Firms i and j, denoted as (Di + Dj), is greater than their aggregate stock (Qi+Qj). This implies that the surplus stock at Firm i’s location (Qi – Di) is not sufficient to fill the stock shortage of Firm j, denoted by (Dj – Qj). Therefore, the maximum quantity transshipped is (Qi-Di).

In Event III, however, the aggregate stock of Firms i and j is more than the joint demand at two locations. The system-wide inventory abundance implies that the short position at Firm j’s location can be fulfilled with the transshipment from Firm i. In this case, the transshipment quantity is (Dj- Qj).

Figure 3 also shows that Event VI is a situation parallel to Event II. The transshipment directions are opposite in these two events. Nevertheless, the two events result in the same amount of unmet demand (Di + Dj – Qi – Qj). Similarly, Event V and Event III are counterparts in that these two scenarios end with the equivalent overall stock surplus (Qi + Qj - Di – Dj).

71

3. Transshipments in a Competitive Decision-Making Environment In the competitive decision-making environment, each firm chooses its inventory level to maximize its own expected profit. The analysis is first conducted in the scenario where no transshipments are implemented between two competing firms, and then in the scenario where the complete pooling policy is employed to initiate transshipments between firms.
3.1 Optimal Inventory Decision without Transshipments

Suppose two firms are independent of each other, and the surplus stock at one firm’s site is not allowed to transship to the coincidentally out-of-stock location. The expected profits for Firms i and j can be written as

? i (Qi , Q j ) = E[ pi Ri + sU i ? pZ i ] ? wi Qi ? jQi ? j (Qi , Q j ) = E[ p j R j + sU j ? pZ j ] ? w j Q j ? jQ j

(3.1.1) (3.1.2)

For each firm, its expected profit includes the expected revenue from sales, revenue from the salvage value for unsold stock, the expected penalty cost for the unmet demand, and the inventory purchasing and holding costs. To simplify the analysis, some cost parameters, such as the unit salvage value, the unit penalty cost, and the average inventory carrying cost, are assumed to be the same for both firms; others are unique for each firm, e.g., the retail price and the wholesale price. Tables 2 and 3 display the amount of sales (R), unmet demand (U), and unsold stock (Z) for Firms i and j in each of the six Events from I to VI.

72

I Dj>Qj Di>Qi Ri Rj Ui Uj Zi Zj Qi Qj 0 0 Di - Qi Dj - Qj IV Dj<Qj Di<Qi Ri Rj Ui Uj Zi Zj Di Dj Qi - Di Qj - Dj 0 0

Table III-2: Key Values for Events I, II, and III II Dj>Qj Di+Dj>Qi+Qj Q ? Di Q ? Di ? ji < i ? ji > i Dj ? Qj Dj ? Qj Di + ? ji ( D j ? Q j )
Qi ? Di ? ? ji ( D j ? Q j )

III Dj>Qj Di+Dj<Qi+Qj Di + ? ji ( D j ? Q j )

Qj 0 0 0

Qi ? Di ? ? ji ( D j ? Q j ) 0 0 Dj - Qj VI Dj>Qj Di+Dj<Qi+Qj Qj ? Dj Di ? Qi

Qj

0 Dj - Qj

Table III-3: Key Values for Events IV, V, and VI V Dj<Qj Di+Dj<Qi+Qj Qi D j + ?ij ( Di ? Qi ) 0 Q j ? D j ? ?ij ( Di ? Qi ) Di - Qi 0

?ij <

?ij >

Qj ? Dj Di ? Qi

Qi D j + ?ij ( Di ? Qi ) 0
Q j ? D j ? ?ij ( Di ? Qi )

0 0

Di - Qi 0

In Tables 2 and 3, ? ji and ? ji denote the percent of unsatisfied consumers switching from Firm j to i, and from Firm i to j, respectively. The value of the switching rate represents the degree of competition between firms. When two firms are close rivals, the switching rate from one to the other is expected to be higher. Consumer switching behavior can be explained by several factors, such as product substitutability, consumer loyalty, price difference, geographical distance between firms, and so on. In the following analysis, the switching rate is assumed to be an exogenously given variable, which is unrelated to the retail price.

73

To see how the values for R, U, and Z are determined, take Event II as an example. In this case, Firm i has (Qi – Di) stock left after satisfying its own consumers (Di); Firm j, in contrast, cannot sell more than its own stock (Qj) without getting transshipments from Firm i. Of those unserved consumers at j’s location, ? ji ( D j ? Q j ) switch to Firm i. Therefore, the units sold at Firm i’s location equals Di + ? ji ( D j ? Q j ) , while the sales by Firm j are Q j . Further, for a relatively low switching rate ? ji , Firm i still has unsold stock of Qi ? Di ? ? ji ( D j ? Q j ) even after satisfying all the switching consumers from Firm j; when the switching rate is above the threshold value Qi ? Di , the extra stock left after Firm i sells products to its own market is not Dj ? Qj sufficient to satisfy all the switching consumers from Firm j. Nevertheless, those unsatisfied switching consumers will not incur penalty costs for Firm i, and thus the unmet demand at Firm i’s location can be identified as zero.

The optimal inventory levels for Firms i and j are derived by solving the expected profit maximization problem in (3.1.1) and (3.1.2), with respect to Qi and Q j .
?? i Q ? Di = pi Prob( I ? V ? VI ) + s[ Prob( II ) Prob(? ji < i + Prob( III ) + Prob( IV )] ?Qi Dj ? Qj

+ pProb( I ? V ? VI ) ? wi ? j = ( pi + p)[1 ? Prob( Di < Qi )] + s[ Prob(Qi + Q j ? D j < Di < Qi ) Prob(? ji ( D j ? Q j ) + Di < Qi ) + Prob( Di < Qi ) ? Prob(Qi + Q j ? D j < Di < Qi )] ? wi ? j ?? j ?Q j = p j Prob( I ? II ? III ) + s[ Prob( IV ) + Prob(V ) + Prob(VI ) Prob(?ij < + pProb( I ? II ? III ) ? w j ? j
(3.1.3) Qj ? Dj Di ? Qi )]

74

= ( p j + p )(1 ? Prob( D j < Q j )] + s[ Prob( D j < Q j ) ? Prob(Qi + Q j ? Di < D j < Q j )

+ Prob(Qi + Q j ? Di < D j < Q j ) Prob(?ij ( Di ? Qi ) + D j < Q j )] ? w j ? j

(3.1.4)

Equation (3.1.3) shows the marginal expected profitability of increasing the inventory level for Firm i. The right hand side of (3.1.3) consists of three parts. First, the value ( pi + p ), or the summation of the retail price and the penalty cost, corresponds to the marginal benefit of adding an additional unit in stock when the demand happens to be greater than the stock level, denoted by Prob( Di > Qi ) . Second, when the actual demand falls short of the inventory stock (i.e., in Events II, III, and IV), additional stock contributes to the revenue; increasing the unsold stock allows Firm i to obtain the product salvage value s. In Event II, only when the switching rate ? ji < Qi ? Di , Dj ? Qj

an additional unit in stock will be accompanied by an increase in the unsold stock, which in turn results in the fulfillment of the salvage value s. Finally, the value wi + j is the cost for acquiring and carrying an additional inventory unit. Similarly, Equation (3.1.4) gives the marginal expected profitability of increasing the inventory level for Firm j.

Table 4 provides a list of shorthand variables that can be used to simplify Equations (3.1.3) and (3.1.4). Suppose the demand for each firm, Di and Dj, has continuous distribution, then the probability functions denoted as ? i ( j ) , ? i ( j ) , ? i ( j ) and yi ( j ) are continuous, given fixed levels for Qi and Qj.

75

Notation

Table III-4: Variable Notations and Definitions Variable Pr ob( Di < Qi ) Pr ob(Qi + Q j ? D j < Di < Qi ) Pr ob( Di < Qi ? ? ji ( D j ? Q j )) Pr ob(Qi < Di < Qi + Q j ? D j ) Pr ob( D j < Q j ) Pr ob(Qi + Q j ? Di < D j < Q j ) Pr ob( D j < Q j ? ?ij ( Di ? Qi )) Pr ob(Q j < D j < Qi + Q j ? Di )

Description

? i (Qi ) ? i (Qi , Q j )
yi (Qi , Q j , ? ji )

The probability for Firm i to be overstocked The probability in the occurrence of Event II The probability for Firm i to have leftover stock after selling to switching consumers from Firm j The probability in the occurrence of Event V The probability for Firm j to be overstocked The Probability in the occurrence of Event VI The probability for Firm j to have leftover stock after selling to switching consumers from Firm i The probability in the occurrence of Event III

? i (Qi , Q j ) ? j (Q j ) ? j (Qi , Q j )
y j (Qi , Q j , ?ij )

? j (Qi , Q j )

Using the notations in Table 4, Equations (3.1.3) and (3.1.4) can be rewritten as:
?? i = ( pi + p )(1 ? ? i (Qi )) + s[? i (Qi ) ? ? i (Qi , Q j ) + ? i (Qi , Q j ) y i (Qi , Q j , ? ji )] ? wi ? j ?Qi (3.1.5)

?? j ?Q j

= ( p j + p)(1 ? ? j (Q j )) + s[? j (Q j ) ? ? j (Qi , Q j ) + ? j (Qi , Q j ) y j (Qi , Q j , ?ij )] ? w j ? j (3.1.6)
* i

Next, the optimal inventory level for Firm i, Q , can be derived by solving the equation
?? i = 0 , assuming Firm j’s inventory level Q j as given. Similarly, the ?Qi*

optimal inventory level for Firm j, Q * j , can be derived by solving the equation
?? j ?Q * j = 0 , given Firm i’s inventory choice Qi . The conditions characterizing optimal

inventory levels for Firms i and j are, therefore, as follows.

? i (Qi ) ? ? i (Qi , Q j ) y i (Qi , Q j , ? ji )(

p + p ? wi ? j s s ) + ? i (Qi , Q j )( )= i pi + p ? s pi + p ? s pi + p ? s (3.1.7)

76

pj + p ? w? j s s ) + ? j (Qi , Q j )( )= pj + p ? s pj + p ? s pj + p ? s (3.1.8) Rearrange Equation (3.1.7). The condition characterizing the optimal inventory for

? j (Q j ) ? ? j (Qi , Q j ) y j (Qi , Q j , ?ij )(

Firm i can be written as

? i (Qi ) =

p i + p ? wi ? j s s ) + ? i (Qi , Q j ) y i (Qi , Q j , ? ji )( ) ? ? i (Qi , Q j )( pi + p ? s pi + p ? s pi + p ? s

(3.1.7?) Given a continuous distribution over the demand, the value for Qi increases with ? i (Qi ) , which represents the probability of the demand Di being less than the inventory level Qi . Therefore, as the value for the right-hand side of Equation (3.1.7?) increases, the optimal inventory level goes up. From the above discussion, Propositions 3.1.1 and 3.1.2 are stated as follows.

Proposition 3.1.1:

Without transshipments, Firm i’s optimal inventory level is increasing with the salvage value, holding the summation of the retail price and the stockout cost constant, for a continuous demand distribution.

Proposition 3.1.2:

Without transshipments, Firm i’s optimal inventory level is decreasing with the wholesale price and the inventory carrying cost, holding other cost parameters constant, for a continuous demand distribution.

77

Proposition 3.1.3:

Without transshipments, there exists a static Nash equilibrium (Qi* , Q * j ) for two competing Firms i, and j, in the inventory-decision game; Firm i’s optimal inventory level decreases with j’s optimal inventory, for pi + p > s . Proof: According to Fudenberg and Tirole (1991), a unique Nash equilibrium exists if the reaction function is monotonic, and its absolute slope value is less than 1. Therefore, to prove Proposition 3.1.3, it is sufficient to show that the reaction function ?Qi / ?Q j satisfies the monotonic and less-than-one slope value requirements. Transform Equation (3.1.7) to the function F (Qi , Q j , ? ji ) , as shown in (3.1.9). By taking the implicit differentiation of Equation (3.1.9) with respect to Qi , and Q j , the expression for
FQ ?Qi ?Qi / ?Q j can be derived as = ? 'j . ?Q j FQi
'

The following equation is transformed from (3.1.7): F (Qi , Q j , ? ji ) = ? i (Qi ) ? ? i (Qi , Q j ) y i (Qi , Q j , ? ji )(
pi + p ? w ? j pi + p ? s

s s ) + ? i (Qi , Q j )( ) pi + p ? s pi + p ? s (3.1.9)

-

For the continuous and differentiable functions ? i (Qi ) , ? i (Qi , Q j ) , and yi (Qi , Q j , ? ji ) , use the following symbols to represent the relevant marginal probabilities, in which ft is the probability density function for the variable t.

78

Let

ai = f Di (Qi )
1 mij = Pr ob( Di > Qi ) f Di + D j |Di > D j (Qi + Q j ) 2 mij = Pr ob( Di + D j < Qi + Q j ) f Di |Di + D j <Qi +Q j (Qi ) 1 nij = Pr ob( Di < Qi ) f Di + D j |Di <Qi (Qi + Q j ) 2 nij = Pr ob( Di + D j > Qi + Q j ) f Di |Di + D j >Qi +Q j (Qi )

qij = f Di + ? ji D j (Qi + ? ji Q j )

Therefore, the partial derivatives of F (Qi , Q j , ? ji ) with respect to Qi , and Q j , are:
' =( FQ j

s s 1 1 )(nij y i ? qij ? ji ? i ) ? ( )nij pi + p ? s pi + p ? s s s 1 2 1 2 )[ y i (? nij + nij ) + ? i qij ] + ( )(? nij + nij ) pi + p ? s pi + p ? s

(3.1.10)

' FQ = ai ? ( i

(3.1.11)

Hence, the reaction function ?Qi / ?Q j is:
1 s ( y i ? 1)nij ? s? ji ? i qij ?Qi =? 1 2 ?Q j ( pi + p ? s )ai + s ( y i ? 1)(nij ? nij ) ? s? i qij

(3.1.12)

It can be shown that the absolute value for the right-hand-side of Equation (3.1.12) is less than 1.

79

3.2 Optimal Inventory Decision with Transshipments

This section first examines the inventory level each firm chooses in order to maximize its own expected profit after allowing for the implementation of transshipments. The optimal inventory level is then compared with the results drawn from Section 3.1 (i.e., the inventory choice in the setting of no transshipments). When the practice of transshipments is incorporated into the analysis, the expected profits for Firms i and j have the following expressions.

? i (Qi , Q j , cij , c ji ) = E[ pi Ri + (c ji ? ? ) X ij ? cij X ji + sU i ? pZ i ] ? wi Qi ? jQi

(3.2.1)

? j (Qi , Q j , cij , c ji ) = E[ p j R j + (cij ? ? ) X ji ? c ji X ij + sU j ? pZ j ] ? w j Q j ? jQ j (3.2.2)
Consider Firm i’s expected profit. The revenue side has three parts: the expected sales to meet its demand, the expected revenue from transshipping its extra stock to Firm j, and the expected salvage value for unsold items; the expected costs include: the transportation cost involved to make transshipments to Firm j, the payment to Firm j for receiving its transshipped items, the penalty cost for lost sales, and the inventory purchasing and carrying costs. Table 5 shows the amount of transshipments (X), sales (R), unmet demand (U), and unsold stock (U) for Firms i and j in each of the six Events from I to VI.
I Dj>Qj, Di>Qi 0 0 Qi Qj 0 0 Di-Qi Dj-Qj

Xji Xij Ri Rj Ui Uj Zi Zj

Table III-5: Events and Associated Key Values II III IV V Dj>Qj Dj>Qj Dj<Qj Dj<Qj Di+Dj<Qi+Qj Di+Dj>Qi+Qj Di+Dj<Qi+Qj Di<Qi 0 0 0 Di - Qi Qi – Di Dj - Qj 0 0 Di Di Di Di Qi + Qj -Di Dj Dj Dj 0 Qi+Qj –Di-Dj Qi – Di 0 0 0 Qj-Dj Qi + Qj –Di-Dj 0 0 0 0 Di+Dj-Qi-Qj 0 0 0

VI Dj<Qj Di+Dj>Qi+Qj Qj - Dj 0 Qi + Qj - Dj Dj 0 0 Di+Dj-Qi-Qj 0

80

Event II, again, is used as an example to show how these values are determined. In this example, Firm i has surplus stock (Qi – Di) available to transship to Firm j, whose inventory stock (Qj) is not sufficient to satisfy all its demand (Dj). Moreover, the amount of the surplus stock at Firm i’s location is less than Firm j’s shortage. According to the complete pooling policy, the size of the transshipment from Firm i to j, Xij, is (Qi – Di). Therefore, sales by Firm i, Ri, are Di and sales by Firm j, Rj, are equal to (Qj +(Qi – Di)). With the transshipment, Xij, Firm i consumes all of its extra inventory and thus the unsold stock, Ui, is zero; Firm j, however, still has unmet demand of (Dj + Di – Qi -Qj), denoted by Zj.

Take the derivative of the expected profit in (3.2.1) and (3.2.2), with respect to Qi, and Qj, respectively. The results are shown in (3.2.3) and (3.2.6). ?? i = pi Prob( I ? VI ) + (c ji ? ? ) Prob( II ) + cij Prob(V ) + sProb( III ? IV ) ?Qi + pProb( I ? VI ) ? wi ? j = ( pi + p )[1 ? Prob( Di < Qi ) ? Prob(Qi < Di < Qi + Q j ? D j )] + (c ji ? ? ) Prob(Qi + Q j ? D j < Di < Qi ) + cij Prob(Qi < Di < Qi + Q j ? D j ) + s[ Prob( Di < Qi ) ? Prob(Qi + Q j ? D j < Di < Qi ) ? wi ? j (3.2.3)

Equation (3.2.3) presents the marginal expected profitability of increasing the inventory level for Firm i. The right hand side of (3.2.3) has five parts. First, the value of ( pi + p) represents the marginal benefit of increasing the inventory level when transshipments from Firm j are impossible or not sufficient to fill the oversized demand; i.e., either Event I or Event IV occurs. Second, in Event II, Firm i transships

81

all of its surplus stock to Firm j. As such, each additional inventory unit increases Firm i’s revenue by the transshipment price minus the transportation cost (as denoted by c ji ? ? ). Third, an additional unit in stock can save Firm i the transshipment price, cij, which otherwise would be paid to Firm j when Event V occurs. Fourth, when either Events III or IV occurs, raising Firm i’s inventory level only leads to an increase in unsold items, and thus contributes to the bottom line with the salvage value, s. Lastly, the marginal cost of increasing inventory stock equals the summation of the purchasing and carrying cost (as denoted by wi + j ).

By using notations ? , ? , ? and y in Table 4, Equation (3.2.3) is simplified as:
?? i = ( pi + p )(1 ? ? i (Qi ) ? ? i (Qi , Q j )) + (c ji ? ? )? i (Qi , Q j ) + cij ? i (Qi , Q j ) + s (? i (Qi ) ?Qi ? ? i (Qi , Q j )) ? wi ? j (3.2.4)

Next, the optimal inventory level for Firm i, Qi* , is determined by solving the equation
?? i = 0 , given Firm j’s inventory choice of Q j . At the optimal inventory ?Qi

level Qi* , the following condition holds.

? i (Qi ) + ? i (Qi , Q j )(

pi + p ? cij pi + p ? s

) ? ? i (Qi , Q j )(

c ji ? s ? ? pi + p ? s

)=

pi + p ? wi ? j pi + p ? s

(3.2.5)

Similarly, for Firm j, the marginal expected profitability of increasing the inventory level is: ?? j ?Q j = p j Pr ob( I ? II ) + (cij ? ? ) Pr ob(VI ) + c ji Pr ob( III ) + s Pr ob( IV ? V ) + p Pr ob( I ? II ) ? w j ? j

82

= ( p j + p)[1 ? Pr ob( D j < Q j ) ? Pr ob(Q j < D j < Qi + Q j ? Di )] + (cij ? ? ) Pr ob(Qi + Q j ? Di < D j < Q j ) + c ji Pr ob(Q j < D j < Qi + Q j ? Di ) + s[Pr ob( D j < Q j ) ? Pr ob(Qi + Q j ? Di < D j < Q j )] ? w j ? j = ( p j + p)(1 ? ? j (Q j ) ? ? j (Qi , Q j )) + (cij ? ? )? j (Qi , Q j ) + c ji ? j (Qi , Q j ) + s (? j (Q j ) ? ? j (Qi , Q j )) ? w j ? j And the condition for (3.2.6)

?? j ?Q j

= 0 , assuming Firm i’s inventory level Qi as given, is: cij ? s ? ? pj + p ? s p j + p ? wj ? j pj + p ? s

? j (Q j ) + ? j (Qi , Q j )(

p j + p ? c ji pj + p ? s

) ? ? j (Qi , Q j )(

)=

(3.2.7)

Rearrange Equations (3.2.5), and (3.2.7). The conditions characterizing the optimal inventory choices for Firms i, and j, are shown below.

? i (Qi ) =

pi + p ? cij c ji ? s ? ? pi + p ? wi ? j ? ? i (Qi , Q j )( ) + ? i (Qi , Q j )( ) pi + p ? s pi + p ? s pi + p ? s p j + p ? wj ? j pj + p ? s ? ? j (Qi , Q j )( p j + p ? c ji pj + p ? s ) + ? j (Qi , Q j )( cij ? s ? ? pj + p ? s )

(3.2.5?)

? j (Q j ) =

(3.2.7?)

For a continuous demand distribution, the optimal inventory level Qi* increases with the value for the right-hand side of Equation (3.2.5?). Accordingly, Propositions 3.2.1 and 3.2.2 always hold.

Proposition 3.2.1:

With transshipments, Firm i’s optimal inventory level is increasing with the salvage value, holding the summation of the retail price and the stockout cost constant, for a continuous demand distribution; with transshipments, Firm i’s optimal inventory level is

83

decreasing with the wholesale price and the inventory carrying cost, holding other cost parameters constant, for a continuous demand distribution.

Proposition 3.2.2:

With transshipments, Firm i’s optimal inventory level is increasing with the transshipment price, when the transshipment price cij < pi + p and c ji > s + ? .

It is a commonly accepted assumption that the summation of the retail price and the penalty cost is greater than the salvage value. According to Proposition 3.2.2, Firm i chooses to have more inventory when the transshipment price it pays to the sender becomes greater; on the other side, Firm i chooses to have more inventory when the transshipment price paid by the recipient becomes greater. By comparing Equation (3.2.5?) with (3.1.7?), it is found that the key determinants for the optimal inventory level without transshipments include the salvage value and the switching rate; when transshipments are implemented, the optimal inventory choice is determined mainly by other factors, such as transshipment price and transshipment cost.

Proposition 3.2.3:

With transshipments, there exists a unique Nash equilibrium (Qi* , Q * j ) for two competing Firms i, and j, in the inventory-decision game; Firm i’s optimal inventory level decreases with j’s optimal inventory, when the transshipment price cij < pi + p and c ji > s + ? .

84

The proof for Proposition 3.2.3 is similar to that for Proposition 3.1.3. By checking the sign and the slope value for ?Qi / ?Q j , as indicated in (3.2.11), the existence of the equilibrium can be proved. Proof: F (Qi , Q j ) = ? i (Qi ) + ? i (Qi , Q j )( (3.2.8)
FQ ?Qi = ? 'j ?Q j FQi
'

pi + p ? cij pi + p ? s

) ? ? i (Qi , Q j )(

c ji ? s ? ? pi + p ? s

)?

pi + p ? wi ? j pi + p ? s

Let

ai = f Di (Qi )
1 mij = Prob( Di > Qi ) f Di + D j | Di > D j (Qi + Q j ) 2 mij = Prob( Di + D j < Qi + Q j ) f Di | Di + D j < Qi + Q j (Qi ) 1 nij = Prob( Di < Qi ) f Di + D j | Di < Qi (Qi + Q j ) 2 nij = Prob( Di + D j > Qi + Q j ) f Di | Di + D j > Qi + Q j (Qi )

' FQ =( j

pi + p ? cij pi + p ? s

1 )mij +(

c ji ? s ? ? pi + p ? s

1 )nij

(3.2.9)

' FQ = ai + ( i

pi + p ? cij pi + p ? s

1 2 )(mij ? mij )+(

c ji ? s ? ? pi + p ? s

1 2 )(nij ? nij )

(3.2.10)

1 1 ( pi + p ? cij )mij + (c ji ? s ? ? )nij ?Qi =? 1 2 1 2 ?Q j ( pi + p ? s )ai + ( pi + p ? cij )(mij ? mij ) + (c ji ? s ? ? )(nij ? nij )

(3.2.11)

It can be shown that the absolute value for the right-hand-side of Equation (3.2.11) is less than 1.

85

4. Transshipments in a Cooperative Decision-Making Environment In a cooperative decision-making environment, the optimal inventory level at each firm’s location is determined by maximizing the joint profits of the two firms. This scenario has been studied by Robinson (1990), and Rudi et al. (2001). The analysis developed in this section differs from previous research in two aspects. First, the model takes into account the fact that consumers switch firms in case of stockout when transshipments are not implemented between firms. Second, the model investigates and compares the inventory decisions and profit outcomes of firms that are implementing transshipments in two different cooperative mechanisms.

In the first setting, the inventory level at each location is optimized to maximize the aggregate expected profits of the two firms. For each firm, its expected profit is based on the demand forecast of the local market. This case has been studied by Rudi et al. (2001). The second cooperative scenario modeled in this section differs from previous research (e.g., Rudi et al. 2001) in that the aggregate profits of the two firms are determined by the total demand forecasts in the markets of the two firms. In this case, the two firms determine their joint order quantities based on the aggregate market demand forecasts and then allocate the total inventory according to the respective local market demands. In both cases, the practice of transshipments can be viewed as an intra-firm reallocation of inventories and it allows firms to reduce inventory investments without lowering customer service level. The analysis in this section provides a framework to examine whether the practice of order coordination enhances the profit benefits that firms achieve from transshipments.

86

The rest of this section is organized as follows. Section 4.1 investigates the scenario where no transshipments are implemented between two cooperative firms. Consistent to the approach used by Rudi et al. (2001), the inventory levels are optimized to maximize the joint profits of the two firms. As discussed in the preceding section, the “without transshipments” cooperative scenario is distinct from the one studied by Rudi et al. (2001) in that it takes the likelihood of consumers’ switching between firms into consideration when stockout occurs at one but not both locations. Section 4.2 investigates two cooperative scenarios when transshipments are implemented between firms. In Section 4.2.1, the optimal inventory level at each location is determined by maximizing the summation of the expected profits of the two firms. The expected profit for each firm is based on the anticipated demand in the local market. In comparison, Section 4.2.2 makes a further assumption that the two firms coordinate their inventory decisions so that aggregate profits of the two firms are maximized basing on their joint demand forecasts. In this section, firms first make their joint order quantity decision and then allocate the optimal inventory. Since such a practice of order coordination enables firms to pool the demands at the local market, it is expected to find that firms will achieve greater profits in the scenario modeled by Section 4.2.2, as compared to in the previously studied scenario, in which firms simply share their inventories through the employment of transshipments.
4.1 Optimal Inventory Decision without Transshipments

In Expression (4.1.1), ? J (Qi , Q j ) is the joint expected profit for Firms i and j, in the case when no transshipments are implemented. Without transshipments, some of the consumers at Firm j’s location switch to Firm i, for Events II, and III, in which Firm j is stocked out

87

while i is overstocked. The size of the switching consumer group is determined by the value of the switching rate, and the number of unserved consumers. Tables 6 and 7 list the number of units sold by each firm, the total number of unsold stock units, and unmet demand for Firms i and j, that are associated with each of the six events.

? J (Qi , Q j ) = E[ pi Ri + p j R j + sU i + sU j ? pZ i ? pZ j ] ? wi Qi ? jQi ? w j Q j ? jQ j (4.1.1)
Table III-6: Key Values for Events I, II, and III I II Dj>Qj Di+Dj>Qi+Qj Dj>Qj, Di>Qi Q ? Di Q ? Di ? ji < i ? ji > i Dj ? Qj Dj ? Qj Ri Rj Ui + Uj Zi + Zj Qi Qj 0 Di + Dj - Qi - Qj Di + ? ji ( D j ? Q j )
Qi ? Di ? ? ji ( D j ? Q j )

III Dj>Qj Di+Dj<Qi+Qj Di + ? ji ( D j ? Q j )

Qj 0

Qi ? Di ? ? ji ( D j ? Q j ) Dj - Qj

Qj

Dj - Qj

Table III-7: Key Values for Events IV, V, and VI IV V Dj<Qj, Di<Qi Dj<Qj Di+Dj<Qi+Qj Qi D j + ?ij ( Di ? Qi ) Q j ? D j ? ?ij ( Di ? Qi ) Di - Qi

?ij <

VI Dj<Qj Di+Dj>Qi+Qj Qj ? Dj Di ? Qi

?ij >

Qj ? Dj Di ? Qi

Ri Rj Ui + Uj Zi + Zj

Di Dj Qi + Qj - Di - Dj 0

Qi D j + ?ij ( Di ? Qi )
Q j ? D j ? ?ij ( Di ? Qi )

0

Di - Qi

Then the optimal inventories for Firm i and Firm j are derived from solving the joint profit maximization problem with respect to the stock levels Qi , and Q j .

88

?? J Q ? Di = ( pi + p) Prob( I ? V ? VI ) ? ?ij p j Prob(V ? VI ) + s[ Prob( II ) Prob(? ji < i ) + Prob( III ) ?Qi Dj ? Qj Q ? Dj + Prob( IV ) + ?ij Prob(V ) + ?ij Prob(VI ) Prob(?ij < j )] ? wi ? j Di ? Qi = ( pi + p)(1 ? Prob( Di < Qi )) ? p j ?ij [ Prob(Qi < Di < Qi + Q j ? D j ) + Prob(Qi + Q j
? Di < D j < Q j )] + s[ Prob(Qi + Q j ? D j < Di < Qi ) Prob(? ji < Qi ? Di ) + Prob( Di < Qi ) Dj ? Qj

? Prob(Qi + Q j ? D j < Di < Qi ) + ?ij Prob(Qi < Di < Qi + Q j ? D j ) + ?ij Prob(Qi + Q j
? Di < D j < Q j ) Prob(?ij < Qj ? Dj Di ? Qi
)] ? wi ? j

(4.1.2)

?? J Q ? Di ) = ? pi ? ji Prob( II ? III ) + ( p j + p ) Prob( I ? II ? III ) + s[? ji Prob( II ) Prob(? ji < i ?Q j Dj ? Qj Q ? Dj ) ? wj ? j + ? ji Prob( III ) + Prob( IV ) + Prob(V ) + Prob(VI ) Prob(?ij < j Di ? Qi = ( p j + p)(1 ? Prob( D j < Q j )) ? pi ? ji [ Prob(Qi + Q j ? D j < Di < Qi ) + Prob(Q j < D j
< Qi + Q j ? Di )] + s[ Prob(Qi + Q j ? Di < D j < Q j ) Prob(?ij < Qi ? Di )] ? w j ? j Dj ? Qj
) + Prob( D j < Q j ) Di ? Qi ? Prob(Qi + Q j ? Di < D j < Q j ) + ? ji Prob(Q j < D j < Qi + Q j ? Di ) + ? ji Prob(Qi + Q j

Qj ? Dj

? D j < Di < Qi ) Prob(? ji <

(4.1.3)

Using the notation given in Table 4, the above equations can be simplified as the following:
?? J = ( pi + p ? wi ? j ) + (? pi ? p + s )? i (Qi , Q j ) + (? p j + s )?ij ? i (Qi , Q j ) + ( y i ? 1) s? i (Qi , Q j ) ?Qi

+ (? p j + sy j )?ij ? j (Qi , Q j )

(4.1.4)

?? J = ( p j + p ? w j ? j ) + (? p j ? p + s )? i (Qi , Q j ) + (? pi + s)? ji ? j (Qi , Q j ) + ( y j ? 1) s? j (Qi , Q j ) ?Q j + (? pi + sy i )? ji ? i (Qi , Q j ) (4.1.5)

89

?? J ?? J Now let = 0 and = 0 . Using the notation in Table 4, the solution for the ?Qi ?Q j optimal inventory levels can be simplified as follows.

? i (Qi ) + ? i (Qi , Q j )(
= pi + p ? wi ? j pi + p ? s

p j ?ij ? s?ij pi + p ? s

) + ? i (Qi , Q j )(

p j ?ij ? sy j ?ij s ? yi s ) + ? j (Qi , Q j )( ) pi + p ? s pi + p ? s (4.1.6)

? j (Q j ) + ? j (Qi , Q j )(
= p j + p ? wj ? j pj + p ? s

pi ? ji ? s? ji pj + p ? s

) + ? j (Qi , Q j )(

s ? yjs pj + p ? s

) + ? i (Qi , Q j )( (4.1.7)

pi ? ji ? sy i ? ji pj + p ? s

)

Rearrange (4.1.6) and (4.1.7), and the amount for the optimal stock Qi , and Q j can be obtained by solving Equations (4.1.6?) and (4.1.7?).
? i (Qi ) =
p j ?ij ? sy j ?ij p j ?ij ? s?ij s ? yi s pi + p ? wi ? j ? ? i (Qi , Q j )( ) ? ? i (Qi , Q j )( ) ? ? j (Qi , Q j )( ) pi + p ? s pi + p ? s pi + p ? s pi + p ? s

(4.1.6?)

? j (Qj ) =
(4.1.7?)

p j + p ? wj ? j pj + p ? s

? ? j (Qi , Qj )(

pi ? ji ? s? ji pj + p ? s

) ? ? j (Qi , Qj )(

s ? yjs pj + p ? s

) ? ? i (Qi , Qj )(

pi ? ji ? syi ? ji pj + p ? s

)

Proposition 4.1.1:

Without transshipments, Firm i’s optimal inventory level is decreasing with the switching rate, ?ij , when the retail price charged by its rival firm is greater than the salvage value.

90

Proposition 4.1.2:

Without transshipments, Firm j’s optimal inventory level is decreasing with the switching rate, ? ji , when the retailer price charged by its rival firm is greater than the salvage value.
4.2 Optimal Inventory Decision with Transshipments

4.2.1 Joint Decision-Making without Order Coordination This section examines the case where the inventory level decisions are made by two firms individually to maximize their joint expected profit. The expected profit for each firm is determined by the demand distribution in the local market. The joint expected profit, ? JTI (Qi , Q j ) , is expressed by (4.2.1), in which X ji + X ij represents the total number of units transshipped between Firms i and j, and ? is the unit transshipment cost. In this model, the order stock levels Qi , and Q j , are optimized to maximize the joint expected profits for Firms i and j. Therefore, the transshipment payment made between firms is cancelled out in (4.2.1).

? JTI (Qi , Qj ) = E[ pi Ri + p j Rj ?? ( X ji + X ij ) + s(Ui + U j ) ? p(Zi + Z j )] ? wiQi ? jQi ? wjQj ? jQj (4.2.1)
Table III-8: Events and Associated Key Values II I III IV V Dj>Qj Dj>Qj Dj>Qj Dj<Qj Dj<Qj Di+Dj<Qi+Qj Di>Qi Di+Dj>Qi+Qj Di+Dj<Qi+Qj Di<Qi 0 Qi – Di Dj - Qj 0 Di - Qi Qi + Qj Qi + Qj Di + Dj Di +Dj Di + Dj 0 0 Qi + Qj –Di-Dj Qi + Qj Qi + Qj –Di-Dj – Di -Dj Di+ Dj Di+Dj-Qi-Qj 0 0 0 -Qi-Qj
VI Dj<Qj Di+Dj>Qi+Qj Qj - Dj Qi + Qj 0

Xji+Xij Ri +Rj Ui +Uj Zi +Zj

Di+Dj-Qi-Qj

91

Table 8 shows that for each of the six events, the total number of units sold by Firms i, and j, the total number of units transshipped between Firms i and j, the aggregate unsold stocks and unmet demands of the two firms. Their optimal stock levels are derived by simultaneously solving Equations (4.2.2) and (4.2.3). ?? JTI = ( pi + p) Prob( I ? VI ) + ( p j ? ? + p) Prob( II ) + (? + s ) Prob(V ) + sProb( III ? IV ) ? wi ? j ?Qi = ( pi + p)[1 ? Prob( Di < Qi ) ? Prob(Qi < Di < Qi + Q j ? D j )] + ( p j ? ? + p) Prob(Qi + Q j ? D j < Di < Qi ) + (? + s ) Prob(Qi < Di < Qi + Q j ? D j ) + s[ Prob( Di < Qi ) ? Prob(Qi + Q j ? D j < Di < Qi )] ? wi ? j (4.2.2)

?? JTI = ( p j + p )[1 ? Prob( D j < Q j ) ? Prob(Q j < D j < Qi + Q j ? Di )] + ( pi + p ? ? ) Prob(Qi ?Q j + Q j ? Di < D j < Q j ) + (? + s ) Prob(Q j < D j < Qi + Q j ? Di ) + s[ Prob( D j < Q j ) ? Prob(Qi + Q j ? Di < D j < Q j )] ? w j ? j (4.2.3)

By using the notation in Table 4, the above optimization problem is simplified as (4.2.4) and (4.2.5). To get (4.2.4) and (4.2.5), let ?? JTI ?? JTI = 0 , and = 0. ?Qi ?Q j

? i (Qi ) + ? i (Qi , Q j )(

p j + p ?? ? s pi + p ? ? ? s p + p ? wi ? j ) ? ? i (Qi , Q j )( )= i (4.2.4) pi + p ? s pi + p ? s pi + p ? s p j + p ?? ? s pj + p ? s ) ? ? j (Qi , Q j )( p j + p ? wj ? j pi + p ? ? ? s )= (4.2.5) pj + p ? s pj + p ? s

? j (Q j ) + ? j (Qi , Q j )(

Therefore, the optimal stock levels when Firms i and j implement transshipments in a cooperative setting are determined by (4.2.4?) and (4.2.5?).

? i (Qi ) =

p j + p ?? ? s pi + p ? wi ? j p + p ?? ? s ) + ? i (Qi , Q j )( ) ? ? i (Qi , Q j )( i pi + p ? s pi + p ? s pi + p ? s (4.2.4?)

92

? j (Q j ) =

p j + p ? wj ? j pj + p ? s

? ? j (Qi , Q j )(

p j + p ?? ? s pj + p ? s

) + ? j (Qi , Q j )(

pi + p ? ? ? s ) pj + p ? s (4.2.5?)

Propositions 4.2.1:

With transshipments, Firm i’s optimal inventory level is decreasing with transshipment cost, holding other cost parameters constant, for a continuous demand distribution.

Proposition 4.2.2:

With transshipments, Firm i’s optimal inventory level is decreasing with the product price in its own market relative to the product price in Firm j’s market, for a continuous demand distribution.

Finally, the solution for the optimal (Qi , Q j ) is unique, proved as follows. F (Qi , Q j ) = ( pi + p ? s)? i (Qi ) + ( pi + p ? ? ? s)? i (Qi , Q j ) ? ( p j + p ? ? ? s)? i (Qi , Q j ) ? ( pi + p ? wi ? j ) Let ai = f Di (Qi )
1 mij = Prob( Di > Qi ) f Di + D j | Di > D j (Qi + Q j ) 2 mij = Prob( Di + D j < Qi + Q j ) f Di | Di + D j < Qi + Q j (Qi ) 1 nij = Prob( Di < Qi ) f Di + D j | Di < Qi (Qi + Q j ) 2 nij = Prob( Di + D j > Qi + Q j ) f Di | Di + D j > Qi + Q j (Qi )

(4.2.6)

93

' FQ =( j

p j + p ?? ? s 1 pi + p ? ? ? s 1 )mij + ( )nij pi + p ? s pi + p ? s p j + p ?? ? s 1 pi + p ? ? ? s 1 2 2 )(mij ? mij )+( )(nij ? nij ) pi + p ? s pi + p ? s

(4.2.7)

' FQ = ai + ( i

(4.2.8)

' 1 1 FQ ( pi + p ? ? ? s)mij + ( p j + p ? ? ? s)nij ?Qi j =? ' =? 1 2 1 2 ?Q j FQI ( pi + p ? s)ai + ( pi + p ? ? ? s)(mij ? mij ) + ( p j + p ? ? ? s)(nij ? nij )

(4.2.9)

4.2.2 Joint Decision-Making with Order Coordination This section examines an alternative cooperative decision making scenario, in which the joint inventory for the two firms is optimized to maximize their total expected profits that are determined by the aggregate market demands. Then the two firms allocate the joint inventory. The order quantity assigned to an individual firm is commensurate with its market demand. To simplify the analysis, we make a further assumption that Firm i and j have identical retailing price (i.e., pi = p j = r ). The joint inventory level of Firm i and j is denoted as Q (i.e., Q = Qi + Q j ) , and their aggregate demand is represented by D (i.e., D = Di + D j ) . In Expression (4.2.10), the joint profits for Firms i and j are composed of five parts: The revenue from selling R units of goods, the salvage value associated with U units of unsold stock, the costs of transshipping X ij + X ji amount of goods, the penalty cost of having Z units of unmet demand (i.e., Z = Z i + Z j ) , and the costs of purchasing and carrying Q (i.e., Q = Qi + Q j ) units of inventory.

? (JTII Q ) = E[ rR + sU ? ? ( X ij + X ji ) ? pZ ] ? ( w + j )Q
94

(4.2.10)

Table 9 presents the values for R, U, Z, and X ij + X ji that are associated with each of the six events. Of these variables, the number of goods transshipped from one firm to another is determined by the quantities of stock assigned to Firms i and j, and the actual demand realized in the markets of the two firms. The model further assumes that the allocation is based on the market demand one firm has relative to another. Let Qi =
n ?1 Q , and Q j = ( )Q . The value for parameter n can be derived by solving n n
1 D = i . According to this allocation rule, the stock levels allocated n ?1 Dj

the equation:

to Firms i and j is proportionate to the ratio of market demands for these two firms; i.e.,
Qi Di . = Qj Dj

To illustrate this rule, consider a special example where the two firms have identical demand distribution. In this case, the value for n equals to 2, and Firms i and j each has an inventory level of Q/2. Table III-9: Events and Associated Key Values I II III IV V VI Dj<Qj Dj<Qj Dj<Qj Dj>Qj Dj>Qj Dj>Qj Di>Qi Di+Dj>Qi+Qj Di+Dj<Qi+Qj Di<Qi Di+Dj<Qi+Qj Di+Dj>Qi+Qj Q Q D D D Q 0 0 Q-D Q-D Q–D 0 D-Q D-Q 0 0 0 D-Q 0 0 Q n ?1 n ?1 Q ? Di Dj ? ( )Q ( )Q ? D j Di ? n n n n

R U Z X ij + X ji

Given the values provided in Table 9, the optimal aggregate stock level is derived by solving the equation (4.2.11) = 0.

95

?? JTII ? n ?1 = (r + p ) Prob( I ? II ? VI ) + sProb( III ? IV ? V ) ? Prob( II ) ? ( )?Prob(VI ) ?Q n n ? n ?1 +( )?Prob( III ) + Prob(V ) ? w ? j (4.2.11) n n

Table III-10: Notations for Key Parameters Q n ?1 ? i (Q) = Prob( < Di < Q ? D j ) ? j (Q) = Prob( Q < D j < Q ? Di ) n n Q n ?1 ? i (Q) = Prob(Q ? D j < Di < ) ? j (Q) = Prob(Q ? Di < D j < Q) n n ? (Q) = Prob( D < Q)

Using the notation in Table 10, the Expression (4.2.11) can be simplified as (4.2.12).
?? JTII ? n ?1 n ?1 ? = (r + p)(1 ??(Q)) + s?(Q) ? ? i (Q) ? ( )?? j (Q) + ( )?? j (Q) + ?i (Q) ? w ? j ?Q n n n n

(4.2.12) Therefore, the optimal joint inventory level for Firms i and j is determined by solving the following equation.

?(Q) =

(n ?1)? (n ?1)? ? ? r + p ? w? j ? ? i (Q) ? ? j (Q) + ? j (Q) + ?i (Q) n(r + p ? s) n(r + p ? s) n(r + p ? s) r + p?s n(r + p ? s) (4.2.13)

In the previous section, the optimal inventory level for Firm i and j are jointly determined by solving Equations (4.2.4?) = 0 and (4.2.5?) = 0. In comparison, the optimal total inventory in the Scenario II is determined by solving Equation (4.2.13) = 0. It would be interesting to examine whether the inventory level decisions that Firms i and j make in these two scenarios are identical, and whether these two scenarios leads to an equivalent profit outcome. If not, then a follow-up question is: Of these two cooperative settings, which scenario is more efficient and provides greater benefits to the participating firms?

96

Now consider a special case, in which Firms i and j are assumed to face identical demand distribution, and the values for other parameters are symmetrical. In this case, Firms i and j evenly share the optimal total inventory. In other words, the following conditions hold: n = 2, ? i (Q) = ? j (Q) , and ? i (Q) = ? j (Q) . Hence, Expression (4.2.13) can be rewritten as:
? (Q ) = ? ? r+ p?w? j ? i (Q ) ? ? i (Q ) + r+ p?s r+ p?s r+ p?s

(4.2.14)

The optimal joint inventory Q* is determined by solving (4.2.14) = 0, and for each firm, its optimal inventory equals to Q*/2. To illustrate these analytical results, several numerical examples are developed in the following section.
5. Numerical Examples

In this section, a series of numerical examples are used to illustrate the analytical results. In Example 1, Firm i and Firm j are assumed to face an identical uniform demand distribution within [0, 200]. In the second example, Firms i and j have asymmetrical demands; the demand for Firm i is uniformly distributed between [0, 200], and the demand for Firm j is uniformly distributed between [0, 300]. In Example 3, the difference in the mean demand for these two hypothetical firms becomes larger; Firm j has its demand distributed within [0, 400] and the demand for Firm i remains within [0, 200]. In all of these examples, the values for relevant cost parameters are invariant for Firms i and j (see Table 11).

97

Table III-11: Assumed Values for Relevant Cost Parameters Cost Parameters Notation Assumed Value Wholesale price Retail price Salvage value Penalty cost Inventory carrying cost Transshipment cost Transshipment price Switching rate
5.1 Results for Example 1

wi , w j pi , p j
s

20 40 10 8 4 2 [0, 48] [0, 1]

p
j

?
cij , c ji

?ij , ? ji

In this section, the analysis is drawn from Example 1, in which Firms i and j are assumed to have identical, uniformly distributed demands within [0, 200].

5.1.1 Results for the Scenario with Transshipments Figure 4 shows the relationship between the optimal inventory level and the value of the switching rate when no transshipments are implemented between the two firms. In the competitive setting, each firm’s optimal stock is invariant with the switching rate, as shown by the flat line in Figure 4. In our examples, the switching rate values are assumed to be symmetrical for Firms i and j. For each firm, therefore, the potential loss of consumers to its competitor is counteracted by the same number of consumers diverting from the rival firm, as the two firms are assumed to have identical demand distribution. In such a symmetrical scenario, the competitive intensity between rival firms has no impact on optimal stock levels, individually and jointly.

98

By contrast, the optimal stock level decreases with the switching rate in the cooperative setting, as shown in Figure 4. Without transshipments, consumers divert away from one firm to another, thereby providing two cooperating firms with opportunities to share their stocks. As the value for the switching rate increases, firms are better able to pool their inventories and thus more likely to hold fewer stock units.
Optimal Inventory Level
130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 0 0.1 0.2

Inventory Level Comparison

Competitive Setting
Cooperative Setting

Switching Rate

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

Figure III-4: Inventory Level Comparison In this example, the optimal inventory level for Firm i is calculated by using the formulas (3.1.7?) and (4.1.6?), given the assumed demand distributions for Firms i and j. To obtain an average profit outcome for each firm under various scenarios, we first derive the mean demand for each of these six events and then compute the probability associated with an occurrence of each individual event, given the stock levels determined. For example, when the switching rate between two rival firms is 0.5, the mean demands for Firms i and j under competitive settings are: (162.58, 162.58) for Event I; (103.25, 178.08) for Event II; (43.88, 154.94) for Event III; (62.58, 62.58) for Event IV; (154.94, 43.88) for Event V; and (178.08, 103.25) for Event VI.

99

The graphs in Figure 5 show that when no transshipments are implemented, firms are better off as the switching rate gets higher in both competitive and cooperative settings. Moreover, the improved performance outcomes as a result of cooperation between the two firms become enlarged when these two firms have a higher switching rate. The degree to which coordinated inventory decisions lead to a better performance outcome than noncooperative inventory decisions is determined by the opportunities for firms to share their inventories and reduce the demand-related risks. The more opportunities for firms to pool their inventories and serve customers, the greater the performance outcome enhanced through cooperative replenishment decisions. Profit
Profit Comparison

1000 975 950 925 900 875 850 825 800 775 750 725 700

Cooperative Setting Competitive Setting

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9 1

Switching Rate

Figure III-5: Profit Comparison When the two firms cooperate in their replenishment decisions to maximize joint profits, it would be more profitable for them to hold fewer stock units as their consumers become more likely to divert from one firm to another. At a high level for the switching rate, the two firms are better able to reduce their inventory investments without losing a great number of consumers to stockouts, and as a result, the two firms benefit more from inventory coordination than from decentralized inventory 100

decisions. On the contrary, these two firms do not benefit much from the use of coordinated inventory mechanism when the switching rates between them are relatively low. The graph in Figure 5 shows that for switching rates greater than 0.5, firms achieve more profits under cooperative setting than competitive setting; however, there is little difference in the profit outcome between coordinated inventory policy and localized inventory decision when the level of switching rate is below 0.5.

5.1.2 Results for the Scenario without Transshipments The extent to which transshipments affect inventory replenishment decisions and performance outcomes is determined by the level of transshipment price implemented between rival firms. Under the competitive setting, Equation (3.2.5?) in Section 3 sets up the condition characterizing the inventory choice for Firm i. In this formula,

? i (Qi ) on the left-hand-side of Formula (3.2.5?) represents the likelihood that the
market demand for Firm i is less than the chosen inventory level. The right-hand-side in this formula sets the value for the threshold probability of having extra stock, which can be used to derive the optimal inventory level.

? i (Qi ) =

pi + p ? cij c ji ? s ? ? pi + p ? wi ? j ? ? i (Qi , Q j )( ) + ? i (Qi , Q j )( ) (3.2.5?) pi + p ? s pi + p ? s pi + p ? s

By solving this equation along with (3.2.7?), the optimal stock levels are derived for Firms i and j under the scenario where transshipments are implemented between the two rival firms. The Formula (3.2.5?) clearly reveals that the optimal inventory level for Firm i increases with the transshipment price cij (c ji ) , holding other cost

101

parameters constant. Transshipment price drives up the inventory level in two ways. First, as transshipment price gets higher, the net revenue that Firm i earns per unit transshipped to Firm j rises, and as a result, Firm i tends to hold more inventories. The part ? i (Qi , Q j )(
c ji ? s ? ? pi + p ? s

) of the right-hand-side in (3.2.5?) is the expected

revenue Firm i can obtain from transshipping goods to Firm j, and it increases with the transshipment price c ji for a given occurrence of transshipment. On the other hand, as transshipment price becomes higher, Firm i can reduce its transshipment payment by holding more stock and thus avoiding transshipment requests from Firm j. In Equation (3.2.5?), the part ? i (Qi , Q j )(
cij ? pi + p pi + p ? s

) is the expected cost that Firm

i incurs when getting the transshipments from Firm j, and it increases with the transshipment price, cij , for a given occurrence of transshipment. Consequently, the optimal stock level for each firm increases with the transshipment price, as illustrated below in Figure 6.
Optimal Inventory Level Qi(j)
150 140

Inventory Level Comparison

Competitive Setting
130 120 110 100 90 80 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48

Cooperative Settings I & II

Transshipment Price

Figure III-6: Inventory Level Comparison

102

Figure 6 also shows that under the two cooperative settings, a firm’s optimal inventory level does not change with the level of transshipment price. When firms coordinate their replenishment decisions to maximize joint profits, transshipment payments from one firm to another can be viewed as the same as an internal monetary transfer. Under this circumstance, transshipment price does not affect the optimal inventory levels that are determined by maximizing the joint profits of the two firms.

It is not surprising to find that the inventory level choices firms make are the same in the two cooperative settings. In this example, the two firms are assumed to have identical uniform demand distribution. As a result, their aggregate demand has a symmetrical triangular distribution, denoted as [0, 400, 200]. The optimal stock levels in the cooperative setting I are determined by solving a pair of Equations (4.2.4?) = 0, and (4.2.5?) = 0. In comparison, the optimal joint inventory in the cooperative setting II is determined by solving Equation (4.2.14) = 0. Since the two firms are assumed to have identical demand in this example, it is not surprising to find that these two cooperative scenario lead to the equivalent inventory level choice. In other words, the optimal order quantities that the two firms choose based on their aggregate market demand forecast are the same as those determined by the accumulation of the expected profits from each of their market demands. It would be interesting to study whether these two cooperative mechanisms still give rise to an equivalent inventory and profit outcomes when the two firms are assumed to have asymmetrical demand distributions.

103

Figure 7 presents the profit outcomes for Firm i(j) when per unit transshipment prices charged between these two rival firms range from 0 to $48 under two cooperative and non-cooperative inventory decisions. As shown in this graph, Firm i(j)’s profit has an inverted U-shape relationship with respect to transshipment price. Although the optimal inventory level chosen by each firm increases steadily with transshipment price, the profit outcome for Firm i(j) rises with transshipment price when it is less than $28 per transshipped unit; the profit outcome for Firm i(j) declines with transshipment price when it is greater than $28 per transshipped unit. An intuitive explanation for this nonlinear effect of transshipment price on profits is as follows. At a high level of transshipment price, firms tend to hold a great amount of stock. Thus, the likelihood for the occurrence of transshipments decreases as both firms keep more inventory to prevent the chance of stockouts. Under these circumstances, the expected transshipment revenue declines, despite an increased level for the transshipment price. The expected revenue from transshipments is not sufficient to compensate for the expected increase in inventory-related costs, which is associated with a greater level of transshipment price. As a result, a high transshipment price has a negative impact on firm performance. On the contrary, at a low transshipment price, firms tend to hold fewer stocks in order to take advantage of opportunities for inventory sharing. Under this circumstance, transshipments are more likely to be employed between firms. Thus, the expected revenue through implementing transshipments rises with transshipment price. Although the inventory level increases with transshipment price, the increased revenues from transshipments are great

104

enough to cover the incremental inventory-related costs. As such, a low transshipment price has a positive impact on firm performance.
Profit Comparison
Average Profit for 955 Firm i or j ($)
940 925 910 895 880 865 850 0 4 8 12 16

Competitive Setting

Transshipment Price

20

24

28

32

36

40

44

48

Figure III-7: Profit Comparison The next section examines how the implementation of transshipments affects a firm’s inventory replenishment decision and the resulting performance outcome when firms meet in various competitive settings.

5.1.3 The Impacts of Transshipments on Firm Inventory Level Choice and the Profit Outcome in Various Competitive Settings Figure 8 compares the inventory levels with and without transshipments for two firms competing in the setting where the switching rate from one to another is 0.5 and the unit transshipment price between them varies between 0 and $48. The results indicate that within a certain range of low transshipment prices (i.e., from 0 to $36), the inventory levels chosen by the two rival firms are greater when no transshipments are employed between them than when transshipments are implemented. The stock level 105

held by each of the two rival firms rises as transshipment price increases. It is shown that for any transshipment price beyond $36, the optimal inventory each firm holds with transshipments is greater than without the implementation of transshipments.
Optimal Inventory Level Qi
160 140

Inventory level comparison
Qi without transshipments for

? = 0 .5

120

100

Qi with transshipments
80 60

40

20

0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48

Transshipment Price

Figure III-8: Inventory Level Comparison Previous studies have found that transshipments, when implemented among stocking locations operating on the same echelon, improve their service levels and performance outcomes through risk sharing and safety stock reduction. Nevertheless, the practice of transshipments has not been investigated in a competitive setting, in which rival firms might face various market demands and set different services levels. Several interesting questions remain as to: (1) Whether the practice of transshipments still provides benefits when firms compete with one another; (2) what factors have potential to affect the improved performance outcomes arising from transshipments in the competitive setting; (3) whether transshipments have differential impacts on profit

106

outcomes depending on firm service levels and demands; and (4) what transshipment price firms should set to achieve the greatest benefits under various competitive environments. Figure 9, below, graphically illustrates the performance impact of transshipments implemented between firms that are intense competitors, moderate rivals, and non competitors.

From this graph, we can draw several interesting conclusions. First, whether the implementation of transshipments improves the performance outcome depends on the intensity of competition between rival firms. When two firms are perfect rivals (i.e., the switching rate =1), transshipments will not improve the profitability of firms. Instead, firms will earn more profits if they choose not to employ transshipments and make their inventory decisions accordingly. This is because transshipments add costs to firms. When switching rate between two firms is high, it is less costly to just let consumers divert to the alternative firm in the event of stock out. In comparison, transshipments will improve the profitability of firms when the two firms are moderately competitive or non-rivals. The degree of performance improvements is affected by the level of transshipment price. Specifically, it is found that the transshipment price has a non-linear impact on the profit improvement for a given rivalry intensity. For example, when the two rival firms have switching rates of 0.5, the profit benefit that each firm gains from the practice of transshipments increases with transshipment price, when the level of transshipment price is below $28. In contrast, the profit benefits decrease with transshipment price when transshipment prices are greater than $28.

107

300

($) Switching rate ? =0

Profit with Transshipments Minus Profit without Transshipments

250 200 150 100 50 0 -50 -100 -150

Switching rate ? = 0.5

0 2 4 6

8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48

Switching rate ? = 1

Transshipment Price

Figure III-9: The Performance Impacts of Transshipments The forgoing discussions are based on Numerical Example 1, in which the market demands for the two rival firms are identical. In Example 2, we consider a situation where the two rival firms differ in their mean demands, while other parameters remain unchanged.
5.2 Results for Example 2

In Example 2, the mean demands are assumed to be different for the two rival firms. The purpose of analyzing an asymmetric demand scenario is to show whether firm size affects the performance outcome of transshipments; i.e., how does the practice of transshipments affect the profit for a large firm relative to a small firm in various competitive environments.

In this example, we assume that Firms i and j differ only in the mean demand and that the switching rates between these two rivals are symmetric. Specifically, the demand for the small firm, or Firm i, is assumed to have a uniform distribution within [0,

108

200]. In comparison, the large firm, or Firm j, has its demand distributed within [0, 300]. To assess the impact of transshipments on firm performance (as measured by profits), given the unit transshipment price of $24, we first calculate the optimal stock levels for the “without transshipment” scenario by solving a set of equations (3.1.7) and (3.1.8). For the “with transshipments” scenario, we solve Equations (3.2.5?) and (3.2.7?) to obtain the optimal stock levels for Firms i and j, respectively. Then we compute the expected profits associated with each of these scenarios. For example, at the unit transshipment price of $24, the optimal stock levels determined for Firms i and j are (124.746, 188.239). Given this pair of inventory levels, the probabilities for Firm i falling into each of the six events are: 0.1864 for Event I; 0.1238 for Event II; 0.0987 for Event III; 0.3217 for Event IV; 0.2001 for Event V; and 0.0692 for Event VI.

At the inventory level of (124.746, 188.239), the mean demands associated with each of these six events are as follows. In Event I, the mean demands for Firms i and j are 154.428, and 238.661, respectively. In Event II, they are 73.4733 for Firm i, and 263.5161 for Firm j. In Event III, they are 31.8832 for Firm i, and 209.2052 for Firm j. In Event IV, they are 54.428 for Firm i, and 88.661 for Firm j. In Event V, they are 146.769 for Firm i, and 65.875 for Firm j. Finally, in Event VI, they are 173.3045 for Firm i, and 150.6265 for Firm j. Given the mean demands presented above, we then calculate event revenues for Firms i and j based on the following variables: units transshipped (i.e., Xij, Xji), sales (i.e., Ri, Rj), unmet demands (i.e., Zi, Zj), and unsold stocks (i.e., Ui, Uj) (See Table 5). For Firm i, the revenue associated with each of

109

these six events is derived as follows: 3989.664 for Event I; 3717.351 for Event II; 2427.654 for Event III; 2721.4 for Event IV; 4960.848 for Event V; and 4479.344 for Event VI. Multiplying event revenues by the derived probability associated with each of these six events, we get an amount of $3621.96, the expected revenue that Firm i achieves at the unit transshipment price of $24. After the deduction of inventory acquisition and carrying costs, the average profit for Firm i equals $1009.426. In a similar way, we use this procedure to calculate the expected profit for Firms i and j, respectively, under various competitive scenarios (as indicated by different switching rates ranging between 0 and 1). Table 12, below, presents some of these results.

5.2.1 The Impacts of Transshipments on Firm Inventory Level Choice and the Profit Outcomes in Various Competitive Settings Table III-12: The Impacts of Transshipments on Performance Outcomes Switching Rate = 0 Switching Rate = 0.5 Switching Rate = 1 Profit Outcome Firm i Firm j Firm i Firm j Firm i Firm j (small) (large) (small) (large) (small) (large) With transshipments* 1009.416 1145.332 1009.416 1145.332 1009.416 1145.332 Without transshipments 710.886 1070.604 911.786 1203.634 1144.006 1347.524 Change in absolute term 298.53 74.728 97.63 -58.302 -134.59 -202.192 % Change 41.99% 6.98% 10.708% -4.844% -11.765% -15.005% * The unit transshipment price is assumed to be $24. Several interesting results can be drawn from this table. First, the implementation of transshipments benefits both the large firm and small firm, when the rivalry intensity between these two rivals is relatively low. However, transshipments make neither firm better off when their competition intensifies to a higher level, as indicated by the switching rate approaching to 1. This result reveals that the profit benefits arising

110

from the implementation of transshipments are decreasing as the two rival firms become more competing. More interestingly, we find that the small firm always benefits more from transshipments than does the large firm at various levels of switching rates ranging between 0 and 1. This is true both in actual monetary terms and in percentage terms. For example, the results show that the performance improvements the small firm (i.e., Firm i) achieves through transshipments are 3.995 (6.016) times in absolute (percentage) terms as the benefits for the large firm, when switching rate between these two firms is 0. As the intensity of rivalry between these two firms increases, the small firm achieves more profit benefits through transshipments than does the large firm. When the switching rate is 0.5, the practice of transshipments endows the small firm (i.e., Firm i) with an improved performance outcome, while making the large firm (i.e., Firm j) fare worse. These findings suggest that the positive impacts from transshipments depend on the relative demand levels of the firms, and on the degree of competition between the two rivals.

In Table 12, we present the differential impacts of transshipments on performance outcomes for Firms i and j at a given unit transshipment price of $24. The table shows how firm profitability is affected by transshipments given different levels of transshipment price. The results from the tables are illustrated in Figures 11 and 12. They illustrate the performance impacts of transshipments for large and small firms, respectively, given different levels of transshipment price, from 0 to $48. Before discussing the impact of the practice of transshipments on firm performance, it is necessary to investigate whether the stock levels that firms choose in the “with

111

transshipments” scenario differ from those chosen in the “without transshipment” scenario, and how transshipment price affects inventory decision-making for firms with different market demands.

Inventory Level Comparison
200 175 150 125 100 75 50 0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48

Inventory level of large firm without transshipments for switching rate of 0.5 Inventory level of large firm with transshipments (II) Inventory level of small firm without transshipments for switching rate of 0.5

Inventory level of small firm with transshipments (I)

Transshipment Price

Figure III-10: The Impact of Transshipment on Firm’s Inventory Level The graphs in Figure 10 reveal the positive impact of transshipment price on firm inventory decisions. As transshipment price rises, the optimal stock levels chosen by both the small firm and the large firm increase. Moreover, we find there is a broader range of transshipment price, under which the implementation of transshipment facilitates the reduction of inventory investment for the firm with greater market demand. As shown in Figure 10, the institution of transshipments decreases the inventories that the large firm holds when transshipment price is less than $41 (given a switching rate of 0.5). In comparison, the implementation of transshipments enables the small firm to hold less stock only when transshipment price is less than $32. Finally, simply comparing Curves I with II in Figure 10, we find that the growth rate of stock level with respect to transshipment price is greater for the small firm (i.e., Firm i) than for the large firm (i.e., Firm j). This result suggests that the optimal

112

inventory level that a large firm holds is less sensitive to transshipment price than for a small firm. In other words, a large firm is less likely than the small firm to take into account transshipment price when making inventory decisions.
Switching rate ? =0

Profit with Transshipments Minus Profit without Transshipments

90 60 30 0 -30 -60 0 -90 -120 -150 -180 -210 -240 -270 -300 -330 -360

($)

4

8

12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48

Switching rate ? =0.5

Switching rate ? =1

Transshipment Price

Figure III-11: The Performance Impacts of Transshipments for Large Firm Figure 11 compares the profit outcomes that a large firm (i.e., Firm j) incurs with and without the implementation of transshipments for three scenarios: The large and small firms are close competitors, moderate rivals, or non-competitors. The impacts of transshipments on the profits of the small firm (i.e., Firm i) are provided in Figure 12. From Figure 11, two factors are found to determine whether a large firm benefits from the implementation of transshipments: the level of transshipment price and the competitive intensity between the two rivals. When two firms compete intensely (as indicated by the switching rate of 1), transshipments will not benefit the large firm in terms of the profit outcome. The large firm achieves higher profits without transshipments. As well, transshipment price also affects profits. As shown in Figure 11, there is an inverted U-shape relationship between transshipment price and the profits of the large firm for the various intensity levels.

113

In comparison, the performance improvement for the small firm, or Firm i, continuously declines with transshipment price, as shown in Figure 12. We also find that the small firm, unlike the large firm, benefits from transshipments even under moderate competition (as indicated by the switching rate of 0.5).
Profit with Transshipments Minus Profit without Transshipments ($)

340 290 240 190 140 90 40 -10 -60 0 -110 -160

Switching rate ? =0 Switching rate ? =0.5
4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48

Switching rate ? =1

Transshipment Price

Figure III-12: The Performance Impacts of Transshipments for Small Firm The main point from the forgoing analysis is that the performance improvements (as measured by the increase in profits) resulting from transshipments diminish with competitive intensity between rivals. This is true for both the large and the small firm. The reason for this relationship is that under high levels of competitive intensity, switching consumers “substitute” for transshipments, thereby reducing the benefits of a transshipment policy. A more difficult question is what causes transshipment price to differentially impact the large and small firms. To understand why this might occur, we start by comparing the probabilities associated with each of the six events (see Figure 13). We have noted from Figure 10 that the optimal stock levels for both the small and large firm (a.k.a. Firms i and j, respectively) increase steadily with transshipment price. The increasing rate of optimal inventory with respect to transshipment price, however, is greater for the small firm than for the large 114

firm. For example, Firm i would hold an additional 24 stock units if transshipment price rises from $10 to $22. By contrast, Firm j only adds 5 stock units. The fact that a small firm increases its inventory to a greater extent than does a large firm in response to an increase in transshipment price leads to asymmetric occurrences of transshipments between the firms. Figure 13 plots the optimal stock levels for Firms i and j (as noted by Qi and Qj), and the six scenarios (as noted by I, II, III, IV, V, and VI) that are associated with two levels of transshipment price, $10 and $22. Figure III-13: Graphic Illustration of Scenarios for Different Transshipment Prices
Dj 300

Graph (1)

Dj 300 281.464

Graph (2)

251.981

II III

I III
Qj =176.635

II

I

Qj = 171.342

VI IV V IV V

VI

Qi = 80.6392

200

Di 251.981

Qi =104.829

200

Di 281.464

Transshipment Price = $10

Transshipment Price = $22

From Figure 13, we can see that as Firms i and j increase their inventories in response to a rising transshipment price, it becomes less likely for the two firms to both stock out, as indicated by the shrinking area for Event I from Graph (1) to (2). On the contrary, there is an increased probability of having the two firms both overstocked when transshipment price rises from $10 to $22, as shown by the expanded region for Event IV. As for the amount of transshipments between these two firms, it is intuitive to find that a large firm tends to transship more to a small firm than the

115

reverse. Such asymmetric occurrences are simply because the large firm tends to hold greater inventories, on average, than does the small firm at any given transshipment price. However, the likelihood of transshipments from the small firm to the large firm increases with transshipment price, while the occurrence of transshipments from the large firm to the small firm becomes less likely.

In the two graphs in Figure 13, Event II represents a scenario when Firm i transships all of its redundant stock to Firm j to satisfy Firm j’s stockout demand. The goods transshipped from Firm i to j, nevertheless, are not sufficient to fully cover all of the under-stocked demand at Firm j’s location. In comparison, Event III represents the situation when the transshipments from Firm i to j are great enough to fully satisfy the extra demand occurring in Firm j’s market. Under this circumstance, Firm i still has some units left over after transshipping to Firm j. In a similar way, Events V and VI identify the two scenarios for transshipping goods from Firm j to i. Comparing each of these four regions (i.e., II, III, IV, and V) between Graphs (1) and (2), we can draw two conclusions. First, the likelihood that Firm i transships to Firm j is greater at a higher transshipment price. The goods that Firm i transships to Firm j are either all of its extra stock (as represented by Event II), or part of the additional inventories it has (as indicated by Event III). Second, the probability of transshipping goods from Firm j to i is lower with an increase in transshipment price. In other word, a high transshipment price suppresses the probability of transshipping goods from the large firm to the small firm, while making it more likely for the occurrence of transshipments from the small firm to the large firm.

116

We can find that the changing patterns in the probabilities associated with the series of Events from I to VI hold under various transshipment prices. The only exception occurs with Event II, which refers to the scenario when the transshipments from Firm i to j are not sufficient to completely meet Firm j’s excess demands. The graphs in Figure 14 illustrate a reduction in the probability of Event II when transshipment price rises from $22 to $34. Figure III-14: Graphic Illustration of Scenarios for Different Transshipment Prices
Dj 300 281.464

Graph (3)

Dj 309.084 300

Graph (4)

II III
Qj =176.635

I
Qj =182.666

II III

I

VI IV V IV

VI V

Qi =104.829

200

Di 281.464

Qi =126.418

200

Di 309.084

Transshipment Price = $22

Transshipment Price = $34

A closer look at the two graphs in Figure 14 helps explain why the probability associated with Event II decreases as transshipment price increases from $22 to $34. At a transshipment price of $34, the joint inventories the two firms hold include 309.084 units, greater than the maximum demand (equal to 300) that Firm j has in its market. As a result, the goods transshipped from Firm i to j are sufficient to completely satisfy the excess demand for Firm j. In other words, it is the expanded

117

area associated with Event III that suppresses the occurrence of Event II, as shown by the smaller region II in Graph (4) compared to that in Graph (3).

Figure 15 provides an in-depth illustration of the relationship between transshipment price and the resulting probabilities related to each of the six events. These graphs extend the forgoing discussion based on three different transshipment prices to the whole range of transshipment price from 0 to $48, and provide consistent arguments with regard to the relationship between transshipment price and the likelihood of each of the six events. As shown in the graph (top-right), the probabilities for the occurrence of Event I steadily decrease with transshipment price, suggesting it becomes less likely that the two firms will both stock out as transshipment price increases. On the other side, the probability for the two firms to be both overstocked increases with transshipment price, as shown in the graph (Event IV). Figure III-15: Event Probability and Transshipment Price
0 .16 0 .14 Ev ent I II
0 .1 2 E v en t I I

Event I 0.3

Probability

Probability

0 .12 0 .1 0 .08 0 .06 0 .04 0 1 0 20 30 40 T ran ss hi pme nt Pri ce
Event IV 0.45

0 .1 1 0. 1 0 5 0 . 1 0. 0 9 5 0 .0 9 0 1 0 20 3 0 Tr a n s sh i p m e nt Pr i c e 4 0

Probability

0. 1 1 5

0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price
Even V t I

Event V 0.22

Probability

Probability

0.4 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price

0.21 0.2 0.19 0.18 0.17 0.16 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price

y t i l i b a b o r P

0.1 4 0.1 2 0. 1 0.0 8 0.0 6 0.0 4

0

10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price

118

As discussed in the preceding section, the likelihood for the occurrence of Event II increases with transshipment price to a threshold level. As transshipment price gets higher than the threshold value, the probability that Firm i and j fall into Event II declines with transshipment price. The probability of Event III, however, shows a continuous increase with transshipment price. By contrast, the occurrence of Events V and VI shows an opposite trend with respect to transshipment price. Overall, transshipments from a large firm to a small firm become less likely as transshipment price increases.

The analysis, so far, has shown how transshipment price affects the likelihood for the occurrence of each of the six events that Firms i and j experience in a single-period replenishment cycle. To study the impact of transshipments on firm profits, we also need to assess the revenues that firms achieve under various scenarios. Table 13, below, provides the formula to calculate revenues associated with Events I to VI. The notations in Table 13 are the same as those used in Section 2. Table III-13: Event Revenues for Large and Small Firms Firm i Firm j pi × Qi ? p × ( Di ? Qi ) p j × Q j ? p × (D j ? Q j )
pi × Di + (c ji ? ? ) × (Qi ? Di )
p i × D i + ( c ji ? ? ) × ( D j ? Q j ) + s × (Q i + Q j ? D i ? D j )

Event I Event II Event III Event IV Event V Event VI

p j × ( Q i + Q j ? D i ) ? c ji × (Q i ? Di ) ? p × ( Di + D j ? Qi ? Q j )

p j × D j ? c ji × ( D j ? Q j ) p j × D j + s × (Q j ? D j )
p j × D j + (cij ? ? ) × ( Di ? Qi )

pi × Di + s × (Qi ? Di ) pi × Di ? cij × ( Di ? Qi )
p i × ( Qi + Q j ? D j ) ? c ij × (Q j ? D j ) ? p × ( Di + D j ? Qi ? Q j )

+ s × (Qi + Q j ? Di ? D j )

p j × D j + (cij ? ? ) × (Q j ? D j )

119

From Table 13, we can see that there are transshipments that occur in Events II, III, V, and VI. In these events, transshipment price plays a double-role in affecting event revenue. Above all, transshipment price determines the unit revenue received by the firm that transships goods, and the payment per transshipment from the firm that receives a shipment. Secondly, transshipment price has an indirect impact on revenues since the optimal inventory levels that firms adopt are related to transshipment price. The combination of these effects makes it hard to draw straightforward conclusion regarding the effect of transshipment price on revenues. Moreover, the problem becomes more complicated in the context of two firms with different mean demands. Figures 16 and 17 present the calculated average revenues associated with events from I and VI for Firms i and j. Figure III-16: Revenues for Small and Large Firms in Events I, II, and III Firm i – a small firm Firm j – a large firm Event I Event I 7500 Event I 5500
5000

7250

Revenue

4500 4000 3500 3000 2500 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price

Revenue

7000 6750 6500 6250 6000 0 10 20 30 Transshipment Price 40

Event II

6000 5000 e u n 4000 e v e R 3000 2000 0

Event II 7000 6500 e u n e 6000 v e R 5500 5000 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price 0

Event II

10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price

120

Event III
Revenue

Event III 4000 3500 3000 2500 2000 1500 1000 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price

Event III 7600 e 7550 u n e v e 7500 R 7450 7400 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price

From Figure 16, we observe that transshipment price affects revenues differently for the small firm (i.e. Firm i) than for the large firm (i.e., Firm j). For example, Firm i’s revenue in Event II increases with transshipment price, whereas Firm j’s revenue decreases. As shown in Table 13, Firm i’s revenue in Event II consists of two parts: The revenue from selling to its own customers, and the revenue it receives from transshipping all overstocked goods to Firm j. As transshipment price rises, Firm i tends to hold a greater inventory and thus has more extra stock to transship. As a result, transshipment revenue for Firm i is positively related to transshipment price. In comparison, the event revenue for Firm j under this scenario is composed of three segments: 1) The revenue from selling to its own market; 2) the transshipment payment it makes to Firm i; and 3) the penalty cost it incurs from not being able to satisfy all of the market demand, even after receiving transshipments from Firm i. Transshipment price, in this example, has both positive and negative impacts on the revenue for Firm j. On the negative side, the transshipment payments that Firm j makes to Firm i increase with the unit transshipment price and with the greater transshipment quantities associated with a higher transshipment price. On the positive side, Firm j tends to hold greater inventories as transshipment price rises and thus gains more revenues from selling to its own market and reducing the penalty cost

121

it would otherwise incur. The negative effect of transshipment price on revenue, nevertheless, dominates. Therefore, overall revenue for Firm j in Event II decreases with transshipment price.

In the case of Event III, the revenue for Firm i steadily increases with transshipment price, whereas the revenue for Firm j is affected by transshipment price in a more complicated way. From Figure 10, we note that the marginal increase in optimal inventory for Firm j is decreasing with transshipment price at a lower range of transshipment price. In contrast, it is increasing with transshipment price when transshipment price rises beyond a threshold level. This non-uniform pattern can help explain why the growth rate of Firm j’s revenue in Event II is first decreasing with transshipment price and then increasing when transshipment price rises above a critical level. The revenue for Firm j in Event III can be written as:
p j × D j ? c ji × ( D j ? Q j ) , as shown in Table 13. In the numerical example, the market

price p j is given at $40, and transshipment price is denoted by c ji . To examine the question as to how the event revenue changes with transshipment price, we first use f ('Q j ) to represent the growth rate of optimal inventory for Firm j with respect to transshipment price. Drawing upon the forgoing analysis, we have the following
' inequalities: 1) f ('Q j ) > 0 for transshipment price within [0, 48]; 2) f ('Q < 0 when j) ' > 0 when the transshipment price is less than a critical level; and 3) f ('Q j)

transshipment price is greater than the critical level. Taking the first derivative of the revenue expression with respect to transshipment price, we get the growth rate of

122

revenue as: ? D j + Q j + c ji × f (?Q j ) . In Event III, it is known that Firm j’s inventory level Q j is always less than its market demand D j . Therefore, the growth rate of revenue is positive when the following inequality holds: c ji × f (?Q j ) + Q j > D j ; on the other side, the growth rate of revenue is negative when c ji × f (?Q j ) + Q j < D j . These inequality expressions can be used to explain the findings that first: Firm j’s revenue in Event 3 increases with transshipment price when the transshipment price is less than $18; then decreases with transshipment price when the transshipment price is within ($18, $40); and it increases with transshipment price when the transshipment price is greater than $40. In Section 2, we have discussed how to set a feasible range for the transshipment price to make sure that the transshipment price within this range is acceptable to both sender and recipient. Given the cost parameters assumed in this example, the feasible range for the transshipment price is [$12, $48].

So far, we have analyzed the scenarios when the direction of transshipments is from Firm i to j, as represented by Events II and III. It may be expected that the revenues associated with Events V and VI for Firm i(j) have a similar pattern as those for Firm j(i) in Events II and III, given that Events V and VI differ from Events II and III only in the direction of transshipments. However, transshipments between Firms i and j are not symmetric. It is reasonable to assume that more goods may be expected to be transshipped from the large firm to the small firm than the other way, simply because the large firm, on average, holds greater inventory than the small firm. Actually, the answer to this question is not that simple. What makes the question complicated is that the small firm increases its inventory more than does the large firm as 123

transshipment price rises. Figure 17 (below) graphically presents the relationship between transshipment price and revenues for Firms i and j for Events IV, V, and VI. Figure III-17: Revenues for Small and Large Firms in Events IV, V, and VI Event IV Event IV Event 3500 IV 4800
3000 e u n e v e R 2500 2000 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price e u 4600 n e v e R 4400 4200 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price

Event V

EventV 5400 e 5200 u n e v 5000 e R 4800 4600 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price
Revenue

5500 5000 4500 4000 3500 3000 2500 0

Event V

10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price

Event VI
Revenue

Event VI 5250 5000

Event VI 8000 7500

Revenue
0 10 20 30 Transshipment Price 40

4750 4500 4250 4000 3750

7000 6500 6000 5500 5000 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price

In comparison to Events II and III, Figure 17 suggests that when the large firm transships its extra stock to the small firm, the revenue for both the small and large firm increases steadily with transshipment price. This result is distinct from those related to Events II and III.

124

The revenues reported in Figures 16 and 17 are deterministic values in that these results have not taken into account different probabilities associated with the occurrence of various events from I to VI. In Figure 15, we presented the probabilities for Events from I to VI at transshipment prices ranging from 0 to $48. Multiplying the event probability by its respective revenue, we get the expected event revenues for Firms i and j. These results are summarized in Figures 18 and 19. Figure III-18: Expected Revenues for Small and Large Firms in Events I, II, and III Event I Event II Event III Firm i –
Expected Revenue
750 700 650 600 550 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price Event I

Event II e 500 u n e v e R 400 d e t c 300 e p x E 200 10 20 30 40 0 Transshipment price
Expected Revenue
6 0 0 5 0 0 4 0 0 3 0 0 2 0 0 1 0 0 0 0

E v e n tI I I

small firm

1 0 2 0 3 0 4 0 T r a n s s h i p m e n t P r i c e
Event III

Firm j –
Expected Revenue

Event I 1800

Event II 800

1200

large firm

1600 1400 1200 1000 800 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price

700 600 500

e u n e v e R d e t c e p x E
0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price

Expected Revenue

1000 800 600 400 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price

The graphs in Figure 18 support the notion that transshipment price has differential impacts on expected event revenues for the small firm and the large firm. As transshipment price increases, the probability that Firms i and j both stock out is steadily reduced, as represented by Event I. Although the revenues related to Event I increase with transshipment price for the two firms, the expected revenue for the small firm (i.e., Firm i) has an inverted-U shaped relationship with transshipment

125

price. In comparison, the expected revenue for the large firm (i.e., Firm j) under this scenario is monotonically declining with transshipment price. Such differences are also present in the relationship between transshipment price and expected revenues for Event II. In the case of Event III, the expected revenues for both small and large firms monotonically increase with transshipment price. Similarly, the consistent relationship between transshipment price and expected revenues are found in Events IV and VI, as revealed in Figure 19. In these two events, the expected revenues for Firms i and j decrease with transshipment price. Figure III-19: Expected Revenues for Small and Large Firms in Events IV, V, and VI Event IV Event V Event VI Firm i –
Expected Revenue
Event IV 1600 1400 1200 1000 800 600 400 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price
1020 Event V

Event VI e u 500 n e v e 400 R d e t 300 c e p x E 200 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price

Expected Revenue

1000 980 960 940 920 900 880 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price

small firm

Firm j –
Expected Revenue

Event IV 2250 2000 1750 1500 1250 1000 750 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price
850

Event V

Ev ent VI 7 00

Expected Revenue

800 750 700 650 600 550 0 10 20 30 40 Transshipment Price

Expected Revenue

large firm

6 00 5 00 4 00 3 00 0 10 20 30 40 Transshi pment Pric e

Event V refers to a scenario where the large firm (i.e., Firm j) transshipments some of its extra stock to Firm i, a small firm. With the occurrence of transshipments, the market demands of Firm i are completely satisfied. It is interesting to find that the expected revenue that Firm j gets from the implementation of transshipments

126

increases with transshipment price, but at a decreasing rate. On the other hand, the expected revenue that Firm i gets after accepting the transshipments from Firm j is increasing with transshipment price, and then decreasing as transshipment price rises from 0 to $48. Comparing the results in Event V with those in Event II, we argue that transshipment price impacts the expected revenue for the small firm differently from it does for the large firm within and across events.

Overall, the expected revenues for Firms i and j are the summation of event revenues, weighted by the probability related to each of the six events. The expected profits for Firms i and j are calculated by subtracting inventory costs from the expected revenue. Inventory expenses include wholesale purchasing costs and inventory carrying costs. Figure 20 presents the expected revenue, inventory costs, and expected profits for Firms i and j at various transshipment prices. The steeper curves in the graph for Firm i suggests that the expected revenue and inventory costs are more elastic for the small firm with respect to transshipment price compared to those for the large firm, or Firm j. To investigate how the expected profits for Firms i and j are affected by the level of transshipment price, the values for the expected profits are redrawn in Figure 21. Figure III-20: Expected Revenues vs. Inventory Costs with Transshipments Expected Revenues Vs. Inventory Costs Large Firm – Firm j
4500 4000
5000 4000

Small Firm – Firm i
Expected Revenue
3500 3000

Expected Revenue
$

$

2500

3000 2000 1000 0 10

Inventory Costs Expected Profit
20 30 Transshipment Price 40

2000 1500 1000 0 10

Inventory Costs Expected Profit
20 30 Transshipment Price 40

127

The two curves in Figure 21 represent the expected profits that Firms i and j achieve in the scenario when transshipments are implemented, and the transshipment price varies from 0 to $48. Figure III-21: Expected Profits with Transshipments
Expected Profit 1125

Firm j – Large Firm
1100 1075 1050 1025 1000 0 10 20 30 TransshipmentPrice 40

$

Firm i – Small Firm

Figure 21 clearly suggests that transshipment price has differential effects on the expected profits for the small and large firms. Specifically, there is an inverted-U shaped relationship between transshipment price and the expected profits of the large firm, or Firm j. The expected profits of the small firm, or Firm i, are negatively related to transshipment price. Moreover, Figure 21 reveals that the small firm has greater expected profits under a transshipment policy than does the large firm when transshipment price is relatively low, or less than $8. On the contrary, the expected profits under a transshipment policy are greater for the large firm than for the small firm when transshipment price rises above $8. To examine whether firms benefit from the implementation of transshipments, Figure 22 compares the expected profits for firms when transshipment are implemented to the expected profits without transshipments.

128

Profit with “Transshipments” Minus Profit without “Transshipments” Switching Rate = 0 Switching Rate = 0.5 Switching Rate = 1.0
150
300

100

-100

Firm i – small firm
200

50 $ 0 -50 -100 -150 -200 0

Firm i – small firm Firm j – large firm

-150 $ -200 -250 -300

Firm i – small firm Firm j – large firm
0 10 20 30 40 TransshipmentPrice

Firm j – large firm
0 0 10 20 30 TransshipmentPrice 40

$ 100

10

20 30 40 TransshipmentPrice

-350

Figure III-22: The Performance Impacts of Transshipments in Various Competitive Settings Interestingly, we find that the small firm consistently benefits more from the implementation of transshipments than does the large firm no matter the competitive intensity (as measured by switching rate). Moreover, the result that the small firm benefits more than large firm from transshipments always holds true independently of the transshipment price level. These findings complement those from Figure 21. It seems that the large firm gains greater profits from the practice of transshipments than does the small firm. However, the relative benefits from the practice of transshipments are greater for the small firm. For example, the graph illustrates that only the small firm benefits from transshipments when the switching rate between firms is 0.5. When the switching rate rises to 1.0, neither firm is found to benefit from transshipments.

Based on the forgoing discussion, we conclude that there are several factors affecting the performance benefits that firms achieve through the strategy of transshipments. These factors include: the rivalry intensity between firms, the transshipment price, and the market demand that one firm has relative to the other.

129

5.2.2 The Impacts of Transshipments on Joint Inventory Level and Aggregate Profit Outcomes in Various Competitive Settings In the previous section, we have discussed the impacts of transshipments on the inventory levels and the profit outcomes for Firms i, and j. In this section, we focus on how transshipments impact the joint inventory of the two firms and the differences in aggregate profits that firms achieve from the implementation of transshipments under various competitive environments.
Joint inventory level (in units) Joint inventory without transshipments 360 (switching rate ? =0.5) 340
320 300 280 260 240 220 200 0 4

Joint inventory with transshipments
8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48

Transshipment Price

Figure III-23: The Impacts of Transshipments on Joint Inventories of Firms In Figure 23, the flat line represents the joint inventory that Firms i and j hold when the two firms compete in a market with a switching rate of 0.5, and when no transshipments take place between the two firms. In comparison, the upward sloping line presents the inventories that Firms i and j jointly carry when the two firms transship their stocks at various transshipment prices ranging from 0 to $48. Two conclusions are drawn from this graph. First, transshipment price has a positive effect on the joint inventory held by the two firms; in other words, the amount of inventory that Firms i and j jointly hold is greater at a higher transshipment price. Moreover, the inventory that the two firms jointly hold when no transshipments take place is 130

different from the inventory levels under a transshipment policy. Specifically, firms hold greater inventories when there are no transshipments, as compared to in the scenario with transshipments when the unit transshipment price is less than $36. With the unit transshipment price rising above $36, the joint inventories that firms hold with transshipments are greater than without transshipments.

Joint Profit with Transshipments Minus Joint Profit without Transshipments

500 400

($)

Switching rate ? =0 Switching rate ? =0.5

300 200 100 0 -100 -200 -300 -400 -500 -600

0

4

8

12

16 20

24

28 32

36 40

44 48

Switching rate ? =1

Transshipment Price

Figure III-24: The Impacts of Transshipments on Joint Profits of Firms The graphs in Figure 24 shows the differences in the joint profits that Firms i and j achieve through the practice of transshipments under various competitive settings. The results suggest first, the joint performance benefits from transshipments are greatest when the two firms experience no competition, as indicated by the switching rate of 0. As the switching rate between the two firms rises from 0 to 1.0, the joint benefits that the firms achieve through the practice of transshipments are declining and then becoming negative. In particular, it is found that the implementation of transshipments no longer improves the joint profits of the two firms, relative to the scenario without transshipments, when there is a switching rate between 0.5 and 1. These findings are in line with the suggestion that transshipments are more profitable

131

when the participating firms compete less intensely with one another. Furthermore, it is shown that in any of the three settings illustrated in Figure 24, joint benefits from transshipments are greatest when the unit transshipment price is $20.

The above result raises a follow-up question: What impacts does the practice of transshipments have on small and large firm, respectively, when the two firms, viewed together, achieve maximal performance benefits through transshipments. Figure 25 presents the performance impacts of transshipments for Firms i and j when transshipments are implemented at the price level of $20.
Profit with Transshipments Minus Profit without Transshipments ($)

330 280 230 180 130 80 30 -20 -70 0 -120 -170 -220

The performance impact of transshipments for small firm

Switching rate
0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

The performance impact of transshipments for large firm

Figure III-25: The Profit Impact of the Transshipment Strategy that Maximizes Joint Benfits The main findings from Figure 25 are three-fold. First, at the transshipment price of $20, both small and large firms benefit from the implementation of transshipments when the switching rate between them is less than 0.25. Secondly, transshipments benefit the small firm only, when the switching rate between the two firms is greater than 0.25, but less than 0.75. Finally, neither firm benefits from the implementation of transshipments when the switching rate is greater than 0.75. These results suggest that it is necessary to provide the large firm, or Firm j, with an extra incentive to

132

implement transshipments when the switching rate between the two firms is within [0.25, 0.5]. As shown in Figure 24, the implementation of transshipments improves the system-wide profits when the switching rate is below 0.5. However, what Figure 25 reveals is that the large firm, or Firm j, does not benefit from the practice of transshipments when the switching rate is between [0.25, 0.5]. Under this circumstance, it is, therefore, important to reduce the asymmetric benefits (costs) between small and large firms. One approach is to use asymmetric transshipment prices between the small and large firms. An alternative solution is to employ side payments from the small firm to the large firm. The question of how to design an appropriate, effective mechanism remains for future research.

5.2.3 The Impacts of Order Coordination on Firm Inventory Level Choice in the Joint Decision-Making Environment with Transshipments In Section 4.2, we have presented the analysis focusing on how the optimal inventory level decisions of firms are made when two firms operate in a joint decision-making environment, and when transshipments are implemented between them. Following Rudi et al. (2001), we first investigate the scenario, in which the inventory level decisions of the two firms are determined to maximize their aggregate profits. In this case, there is no effort to coordinate the ordering decisions made by firms, and the optimal order quantities for Firms i and j are derived by solving Equations (4.2.4?) and (4.2.5?), jointly. In comparison, the second scenario we developed assumes that the two firms make their joint inventory level decision based on the expected aggregate demands, and then allocate such an optimal inventory in proportion to their

133

relative market demands. In this setting, the optimal total inventory for the two firms is determined by solving Equation (4.2.13). The ratio of the inventory allocated to each location (i.e., Qi/Qj) equals to the relative forecasted market demands of the two firms (i.e., Di/Dj). As compared to the previous setting, this scenario involves order coordination between firms.

The results based on Numerical Example 1 in Section 5.1.2 suggest that these two joint decision-making mechanisms are equivalent when firms have identical demand distribution and other cost parameters are symmetric. Nevertheless, it remains unknown whether order coordination makes difference in the inventory decision and profit outcomes when firms have different market demands. This section compares the optimal inventory levels and the profit outcomes that are determined by these two decision-making rules.

In this numerical example, the market demands for Firms i and j are assumed to have uniform distribution denoted as follows: Di ~ U[0, 200], Dj ~U[0,300]. Table 14 provides the expressions for those key probability parameters included in (4.2.4?) and (4.2.5?).

? i (Qi ) = Qi / 200 ? i (Qi , Q j ) = ? i (Qi , Q j ) =

Table III-14: Expressions for Key Parameters ? j (Q j ) = Q j / 300 0.5Qi2 60000 0.5(200 ? Qi ) 2 ? j (Qi , Q j ) = 60000

[Q j (200 ? Qi ) ? 0.5(200 ? Qi ) 2 ] 60000 [0.5Q + Qi (300 ? Qi ? Q j )]
2 i

? j (Qi , Q j ) =

60000

134

In Table 14, the probabilities associated with various events are expressed as functions of order quantities for Firms i and j. Using these notations and the assumed values for relevant cost parameters, the optimal inventory levels for Scenario I (see Section 4.2.1), Qi* , Q* j are calculated by solving Equations (4.2.4?) = 0, and (4.2.5?) =0. The results are: Qi* = 116.129 and Q* j = 174.194. Thus, their total inventory equals to 290.323.

Next, we use Equation (4.2.13) and Table 10 to calculate the joint optimal inventory level for Scenario II (see Section 4.2.2). In this scenario, Firms i and j are assumed to make their joint order quantity decision based on their aggregate demand forecasts. Then the two firms allocate the optimal inventory. In this example, the ratio of the inventory allocated to the two firms Qi/Qj equals to 2/3. Thus, the value for n is 5/2. Table 14 provides the expressions for the probability parameters included in Equation (4.2.13). Given the assumption that Firms i and j have uniform demand distributions, their aggregate demand has a trapezoidal distribution. Table 15 shows the expressions for the key probability parameters used in Equation (4.2.13). Table III-15: Expressions for Key Parameters 0.5(0.4Q) 2 [0.6Q (200 ? 0.4Q) ? 0.5(200 ? 0.4Q) 2 ] ? i (Q) = ? j (Q) = 60000 60000 2 [0.5(0.4Q) + 0.4Q(300 ? Q)] 0.5(200 ? 0.4Q) 2 ? i (Q) = ? j (Q) = 60000 60000 2 200 200 Q ? (Q) = + ? 2 × 60000 300 300 Using the notations in Table 14, the optimal joint inventory Q* is derived by solving Equations (4.2.13) = 0. The order quantities allocated to Firms i and j are: 135

* Qi* = 0.4 × Q , and Q* j = 0.6 × Q . The results are as follows: Q = 291.991 ,

Qi* = 116.796 , and Q* j = 175.195 . It is shown that firms hold similar amount of stock

in Scenarios I and II. This finding suggests that the two cooperative mechanisms lead firms to have equivalent inventory decisions and profit outcomes.
5.3 Results for Example 3

In Section 5.2, we analyzed the case where the demand differences between a large firm and a small firm are moderate. We find that transshipments benefit small firms more than large firms in reducing inventory investments and in improving performance outcomes. These differences are present under various competitive settings and become greater as firms compete more vigorously. In this section, we further investigate to what extent transshipments reward small firms disproportionately to large firms when the scale of demand differences becomes further enlarged. In Example 3, the demand for the large firm (Firm j) is assumed to be uniformly distributed within [0, 400], and the demand for the small firm (Firm i) is within [0, 200].

The numerical results based on Example 3 are consistent with those from Example 2. In Section 5.3.1, we first present the inventory and profit outcomes in the scenario when no transshipments are implemented between Firms i and j. Next, Section 5.3.2 provides the inventory level and profit outcomes in the scenario when transshipments are implemented between the two firms. Finally, the impacts of transshipments on inventory and profit of firms, overall and separately, are investigated in Section 5.3.3.

136

5.3.1 Results for the Scenario without Transshipments
Inventory Level

400 375 350 325 300 275 250 225 200 175 150 125 100

Joint Inventory

Inventory Level for Large Firm

Inventory Level for Small Firm

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

Switching Rate

Figure III-26: Inventory Levels Under Various Competitive Settings Consistent with the previous findings, the optimal inventory levels that Firms i and j choose under various competitive settings remain nearly the same. Given the assumption of symmetrical switching rates, it is expected that firms make their inventory decisions regardless of the level of switching rate. This argument is verified by the flat lines in Figure 26 suggesting the constant inventory levels that are chosen by firms for various switching rates within [0, 1]. Although firms maintain constant inventory levels, the profit outcomes for both small and large firms increase with the switching rate. As shown in Figure 27, Firms i and j both have greater profits when the switching rate is higher.

137

Expected Profit ($)
2900 2700 2500 2300 2100 1900 1700 1500 1300 1100 900 700 500 0

Joint Profits

Profit for Large Firm

Profit for Small Firm
0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1

Switching Rate Figure III-27: Profit Outcomes under Various Competitive Settings A potential explanation for this result is that firms have more opportunities to share their inventories when consumers are more likely to switch from one firm to another. As a consequence, the expected revenues for both firms are greater when the switching rate between the two firms is higher. Since the inventory-related costs are constant for different switching rates, the increase in the expected revenue contributes to the performance improvements, as indicated by the higher profit outcome.

5.3.2 Results for the Scenario with Transshipments In the scenario, when transshipments are implemented between Firms i and j, the results are also consistent with those in the previous example. As shown in Figure 28, both small and large firms increase their inventory levels with transshipment price. However, the inventory level chosen by the small firm is more elastic with respect to transshipment price than it is for the large firm. This finding further suggests that transshipment price has differential impacts on the inventory replenishment decisions for firms facing differing market demands.

138

Inventory Level
395 370 345 320 295 270 245 220 195 170 145 120 95 70 45 0 Joint Inventory Inventory for Large Firm

Inventory for Small Firm

4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48

Transshipment Price

Figure III-28: Inventory Levels at Various Transshipment Prices
3000 2750 2500 2250 2000 1750 1500 1250 1000 750 500 0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48 Profit for Large Firm Profit for Small Firm

Profit ($)
Joint Profit

Transshipment Price

Figure III-29: Profit Outcomes at Various Transshipment Prices In Example 2, we have found the presence of an inverted-U shaped relationship between transshipment price and the profit outcome of the large firm. Moreover, it is found that there is a negative relationship between transshipment price and the profit outcome for the small firm. These findings also hold true in Example 3, where the difference in the mean demand between large and small firm increases to 100 units.

139

5.3.3 The Impacts of Transshipments on Firm Inventory Level Choice and the Profit Outcomes in Various Competitive Settings The graphs in Figures 30 and 31 compare the optimal inventory levels with and without transshipments for Firm i and j, respectively, assuming the switching rate of 0.5.
160 150 140 130 120 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40

Inventory Level
Inventory level of small firm without transshipments at switching rate of 0.5

Inventory level of small firm with transshipments 0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40

Transshipment Price

Figure III-30: Inventory Levels for Small Firm with and without Transshipments The upward-sloping curve in Figure 30 suggests a positive impact of transshipment price on Firm i’s inventory level. As transshipment price rises, the optimal stock levels chosen by the small firm increase. Similar results are found for Firm j, as shown in Figure 31.
265 260 255 250 245 240 235 230 225 220 0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48 Inventory level of large firm with transshipments

Inventory Level
Inventory level of large firm without transshipments at switching rate of 0.5

Transshipment Price

Figure III-31: Inventory Levels for Large Firm with and without Transshipments

140

Comparing Figure 30 with Figure 31, we find that although the inventory levels for both small and large firms increase with transshipment price, the growth rate for the small firm is increasing with transshipment price, and the growth rate for the large firm is decreasing with transshipment price. Such differences in the growth rate of inventory levels were also found in the previous example, in which the mean demand for the large firm is greater than that for the small firm by 50 units.
Inventory Level
425 400 375 350 325 300 275 250 0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48 Joint inventory level with transshipments Joint inventory level without transshipments at the switching rate of 0.5

Transshipment Price

Figure III-32: Joint Inventories with and without Transshipments In Figure 32, the flat line represents the joint inventory that Firms i and j hold when the two firms compete in the market with a consumer’s switching rate of 0.5, and when no transshipments are implemented between the two firms. In comparison, the upward sloping line displays the inventories that Firms i and j jointly hold when the two firms implement transshipments under various transshipment prices from 0 to $48. It is found that the joint inventories that Firms i and j hold with transshipments are greater than those held by the two firms without transshipments, when the unit transshipment price is above $34. Note that in Example 2, it was found that the threshold transshipment price was $36. In these two examples, we have held everything else constant. Therefore, the larger gap in the mean demand between the

141

two firms might lead to a lower threshold transshipment price in Example 3, compared to that in Example 2.

The performance impacts of transshipments for Example 3 are presented in the following table. Table 16 indicates that the implementation of transshipments benefits the small firm more than the large firm at various competitive settings. This finding is consistent with the results presented in Table 12 for Example 2. Table III-16: The Impacts of Transshipments on Performance Outcomes Switching Rate = 1 Switching Rate = 0 Switching Rate = 0.5 Profit Outcome Firm i Firm j Firm I Firm j Firm i Firm j (small) (large) (small) (large) (small) (large) With transshipments* 1529.543 1650.422 1529.543 1650.422 1529.543 1650.422 Without 673.794 1433.404 933.926 1569.586 1197.774 1708.898 transshipments Change in 855.749 217.018 595.617 80.836 331.769 -58.476 absolute term % Change 127.005% 15.14% 63.776% 5.15% 27.699% -3.421% * The unit transshipment price is assumed to be $12.
6. Conclusions and Future Research

The analytical model developed in this essay investigates the practice of transshipments between two competing stocking locations. Many previous studies in supply chain management have modeled the performance impacts of uncertainties, such as demand and lead time variability, and their implications for inventory management. The role of competition in affecting the performance outcomes of transshipments has not received much attention. This essay examines inventory replenishment decisions and the application of the transshipments strategy in various competitive environments. The analysis can be used to predict under what conditions

142

transshipments are likely to be employed between rival firms (e.g., auto dealerships). The results suggest that there exist opportunities for rival firms to collaborate through transshipments. In other words, the practice of transshipments is able to improve firm performance (as measured by profits), even when the participating firms are direct rivals. Moreover, the numerical results are used to illustrate how firms with asymmetric demands benefit differently from transshipments under various competitive settings.

It is found that transshipments provide more performance improvements for the small firm than for the large firm. Such imbalanced benefits become more substantial as the competition intensity between the two firms increases. These results suggest that it is important to design an effective, appropriate incentive mechanisms (e.g., monetary transfers, asymmetric transshipment prices) to initiate transshipments between rival firms with varying demands.

A few interesting questions remain for further research. One extension is to investigate what the performance impacts of transshipments are for firms operating under the competitive environment, in which the prices of their products vary with the rivalry intensity between firms. In this study, the retail prices of product are held constant under various competitive settings. It would be more interesting to characterize the market of greater competition with both a lower level of retail price and a higher value of switching rate. The use of endogenous price and switching rate would provide us with an opportunity to view the pricing decision of firms conjointly

143

with their inventory decision. The second extension of this essay is to relax the assumption that the demands at different locations are independent. The study of transshipments between rivals firms with correlated demands would help us understand to what extent the factor of competition moderates the benefits from the risk-pooling strategy enabled through transshipments.

Chapter 4: Conclusions
This dissertation explores two types of strategic behaviors and market outcomes: (1) How strategic interactions across markets affect multimarket competitors in their pricing behaviors and collusive outcomes, and (2) how transshipments in a competitive market affect rival firms in their inventory decisions and profit outcomes.

In Essay 1, a conjectural variation model is developed to examine how a firm makes product pricing decisions when taking into account the strategic contacts the firm has with its rivals across multiple markets. An insight that has not received much attention, but revealed from our formal analysis of competitive behavior in a multimarket contact setting, is that similarity in production costs plays an important moderating role in the inverse relationship between multimarket contact and rivalry intensity. That is, multimarket contact is more effective in facilitating tacit collusive pricing when it occurs between rival firms having similar production costs than when it occurs between rival firms with dissimilar production costs.

Such differential impacts of multimarket contact on collusive behavior arise from the consideration that rival firms of similar production costs have greater conjectural 144

variation with respect to one another, and more importantly, they have less degree of vertical product differentiation. It is the formation of higher conjectural variation and the presence of greater product substitutability that reinforce the collusion facilitating effects of multimarket contact for firms having similar production costs.

This finding gives firms competing in single market and multimarket contexts different implications with respect to product development strategy. For example, when two firms compete in a local market with a single product, one option for a firm to avoid fierce competition is to distinguish itself from the rival firm by introducing differentiated products. The more dissimilar the products are, the less likelihood for the occurrence of a pricing war. However, it would be a different story if firms competed simultaneously in multiple markets. Under this scenario, tacit collusion and lower rivalry intensity are more likely to sustain when the product lines firms develop are similar with one another. Consequently, the competitive implications of product differentiation strategy are dramatically different in single market and multimarket contact settings.

Competitive interactions across multiple markets and their economic consequences have received growing interest in the marketing and strategic management literatures. In a review paper by Jayachandran et al. (1999), the authors discuss, in detail, the implications of multimarket competition for marketing strategies, in particular, product line rivalry and market entry decision. The notion of mutual forbearance and multimarket competition also applies to conglomerate firms with diversified

145

businesses (Hughes and Oughton 1993). Along with these studies, our work extends and enhances the understanding of the questions: What nature of multimarket contact facilitates tacit collusion and how these collusion enhancing effects differ in various market circumstances.

Moreover, the finding that the tacit-colluding opportunities endowed with multimarket contact are more likely to hold between carriers with similar production costs has policy implications. Traditionally, it has been well recognized that high cost carriers tend more than low cost carriers to engage in tacit collusive pricing. In the multimarket contact setting, however, low cost carriers also have positive reasons to engage in mutual forbearance when their rivals are also low cost carriers. As a result, it may not be sufficient to just open airline markets to low-cost competition without any regulatory oversight. Since low-cost carriers appear to engage in tacit collusion, some regulatory oversight might still be needed.

Finally, it is also important to realize that although multimarket contact enhances tacit collusive prices for both low cost and high cost carriers, it matters less as their products become more differentiated within and between markets.

There are several research extensions from the multimarket contact essay. Since our empirical analysis is based on the U.S. airline market in the year 2002, one concern of using this dataset is that the U.S. airline market had not yet fully recovered from the 9/11 shock. The airfare impact of multimarket contact consequently might be

146

overestimated or underestimated. In future research, it would be worthwhile to attempt to estimate the airfare impact of multimarket contact during other time periods.

Another limitation of the current study is that it investigates the competitive effects of multimarket contact only in a static setting. An interesting question remains how multimarket contact affects airlines in making route entry and exit decisions. In other words, it would be of our particular interest to examine whether airlines select routes that enable them to avoid or seek contact with “rival” carriers. An investigation of the competitive effect of multimarket contact in a dynamic setting will also provide an insight into the question: Under what circumstances does multimarket contact contribute to stable or unstable outcomes after new entries.

The second essay in this dissertation focuses on the implementation of lateral transshipments among competing firms. The analytical model developed in this paper investigates the practice of transshipments between two competing stocking locations. It contributes to the existing literature on transshipments in several ways.

First, many previous studies have modeled the performance impacts of environmental uncertainties, such as demand and lead time variability, and their implications for inventory management. The role of competition between firms in affecting the transshipment strategy and profitability outcomes has not received much attention. This paper examines inventory replenishment decisions and the application of the

147

transshipment strategy in various competitive environments. The results suggest that transshipments may not be cost effective if the firms are operating in an environment that allows consumers to easily switch between firms. In such an environment, firms compete more intensely with one another and consumers have lower loyalty towards firms, both of which result in a high consumer’s switching rate.

Second, the analysis incorporates the role that transshipment price plays in reallocating the benefits from transshipments between firms. It is found that the use of an appropriate level of transshipment price is an effective tool for firms to optimize their inventory level decision and maximize the performance improvement from transshipments. In particular, there exists a unique transshipment price that is optimal for both firms when the two firms are identical in market demand and inventoryrelated cost parameters. However, it is shown that when the two firms are not identical, the smaller firm will prefer a lower transshipment price, and will achieve greater benefits from transshipments.

Third, the consideration of asymmetric firm characteristics into the study of transshipments adds to the previous literature and enriches the managerial implications. The finding that transshipments are likely to provide asymmetric benefits when firms have asymmetric market demands suggests that transshipments actually enable the small firm to take a “free” ride on the great amount of inventory that the large firm holds. Moreover, the opportunity for such a free ride makes it difficult for the two firms having asymmetric demands to reach a common

148

transshipment price. Under these circumstances, it is necessary to design an effective incentive mechanism (e.g., side payments, flexible transshipment price) to make transshipments pay off for both firms.

In the transshipment essay, both consumer switching rate and product price are considered as exogenous variables. The use of fixed, constant values for these variables makes the analytical solutions tractable and explicable. As an immediate future research, the practice of transshipments can viewed in a multi-stage sequential game modeling framework. For example, firms make stock level decision in the first stage; the pricing decisions are made in the second stage by firms competing in the same market; and finally, firms decide whether to implement transshipments and what policy to follow in terms of the transshipment volume. In such a three-stage game theoretical model, both the price and inventory level decisions can be thought of as endogenous variables.

On one side, the price of one firm relative to the other’s might affect the probability of a consumer’s switching firms. On the other side, the inventory level one firm holds relative to the other’s might affect the direction and the magnitude of transshipments. By incorporating the consumer’s utility function into the classic newsvendor model (see Dana and Petruzzi 2001 as an example), the price decision of firms can be jointly analyzed with their inventory and transshipment decisions from the strategic perspective.

149

The analysis developed in the transshipment essay relies on a major assumption on the consumer switching behavior. According to this assumption, no consumers switch firms when transshipments are implemented in the event of stockout. However, it would be useful to extend the current model into other more complicated and dynamic situations. For example, consumers might switch before or after the occurrence of transshipments. Since the performance impacts of transshipments are subject to the specification in the sequence of events, it would be important and necessary to examine transshipments in other hypothetical settings. In this aspect, there are great potentials for the simulation work to be developed in quantifying and validating the analytical results.

Furthermore, it would be interesting to explore the implementation of transshipments in an empirical setting. Several interesting hypotheses can be developed and tested by integrating various perspectives in the fields such as operations management, consumer behavior, marketing, and industrial organization economics.

150

References
Abreu, D. (1986), “External equilibria of oligopolistic supergames,” Journal of
Economic Theory, 39, 191-225.

Axsater, Sven. 2003. A new decision rule for lateral transshipments in inventory system. Management Science 49 (9), 1168-1179. Baum, Joel A.C. and Korn, Helaine J. (1996), “Competitive dynamics of interfirm rivalry,” Academy of Management Journal, 39:2, 255-291. Baum, Joel A. C. and Korn, Helaine J. (1999), “Dynamics of dyadic competitive interaction,” Strategic Management Journal, 20, 251-278. Bernheim Douglas B and Whinston, Michael D. (1990), “Multimarket contact and collusive behavior,” Rand Journal of Economics, 21:1, 1-26. Brander, James A. and Zhang, Anming (1990), “Market conduct in the airline industry: an empirical investigation,” Rand Journal of Economics, 21:4, 567-583. Bulow, Jeremy I., Geanakopos, John D., and Klemperer, Paul D. (1985), “Multimarket oligopoly: strategic substitutes and complements,” The Journal of
Political Economy, 93: 3, 488-511.

Cohen, Morris, Cull, Carl, Lee, Hau, and Willen Don. 2000. Saturn’s supply-chain innovation: high value in after-sales service. Sloan Management Review Summer, 93101. Dana, James D., Jr. and Petruzzi, Nicholas C. 2001. Note: The newsvendor model with endogenous demand. Management Science 47 (11), 1499-1497.

151

Dixit, Avinash (1979), “A model of duopoly suggesting a theory of entry barriers,”
Bell Journal of Economics, 10, 20-32.

Dong, Lingxiu and Rudi, Nils. 2004. Who benefits from transshipment? exogenous vs. endogenous wholesale prices. Management Science 50 (5), 645-657. Dresner, Martin and Tretheway, M. (1992), “Modeling and testing the effect of market structure on price: the case of international air transport,” Journal of
Transport, Economics and Policy, 26: 2, 171-184.

Dresner, Martin and Windle, Robert (1996), “The impacts of low cost carriers on airport and route competition,” Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, 30: 3, 309-328. Dresner, Martin and Windle, Robert (1999), “Competitive responses to low cost carrier entry,” Transportation Research E: The Logistics and Transportation Review, 35, 59-75. Dresner, Martin, Windle, Robert and Yao, Yuliang (2001), “Airport barriers to entry in the US,”Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, forthcoming. Edwards, C.D. (1955), Conglomerate bigness as a source of market power. Business
Concentration and Price Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Evans, William N. and Kessides, Ioannis N. (1994), “Living by the ‘golden rule’: multimarket contact in the U.S. airline industry,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(2), 341-366. Feinberg, Robert M. (1985), ““Sales-at-risk”: a test of the mutual forbearance theory of conglomerate behavior,” The Journal of Business, 58:2, 225-241.

152

Fernandez, Nerea and Marin, Pedro L. (1998), “Market power and multimarket contact: some evidence from the Spanish hotel industry,” The Journal of Industrial
Economics, XLVI: 301-315.

Fu, Xiaowen, Dresner, Martin, and Oum, Tae H. (2005), “Oligopoly competition with differentiated products: what happened after the effect of southwest’s entries stabilized,” Working paper, Sauder School of Business, University of British Columbia, December. Fuentelsaz, Lucio and Gomez, Jaime (2006), “Multipoint competition, strategic similarity and entry into geographic markets,” Strategic Management Journal, 27, 477-499. Fudenberg, Drew and Tirole, Jean. 1991. Game Theory. The MIT Press. Gimeno, Javier and Woo, Carolyn Y. (1999), “Multimarket contact, economies of scope, and firm performance,” Academy of Management Journal, 43:3, 239-259. Gimeno, Javier (1999), “Reciprocal threats in multimarket rivalry: staking out ‘spheres of influence’ in the U.S. airline industry,” Strategic Management Journal, 20, 101-128. Gimeno, Javier (2002), “The performance effects of unintended and purposive multimarket contact,” Managerial and Decision Economics, 34: 209-224. Granot, Daniel and Sosic Greys. 2003. A three-stage model for a decentralized distribution system of retailers. Operations Research 51 (5), 771-784. Heggestad, Arnold A. and Rhoades, Stephen A. (1976), “Multi-market interdependence and local market competition in banking,” The Review of Economics
and Statistics, 60, Nov., 523-532.

153

Herer, Yale T. and Rashit, Ayelet. 1999. Lateral stock transshipments in a twolocation inventory system with fixed and joint replenishment costs. Naval Research
Logistics. 46 (5), 525-547.

Hughes, Kirsty and Oughton, Christine (1993), “Diversification, multi-market contact and profitability,” Economica, 60: 203-224. Jans, I., and Rosenbaum, D. (1996), “Multimarket contact and pricing: evidence from the U.S. cement industry,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, 15: 391412. Jayachandran, Satish, Gimeno, Javier, and Varadarajan, P.Rajan (1999), “The theory of multimarket competition: a synthesis and implications for marketing strategy,”
Journal of Marketing, 63, 49-66.

Karnani, Aneel and Wernerfelt, Birger (1985), “Multiple point competition,”
Strategic Management Journal, 6:1, 87-96.

Krishnan, K. S. and Rao, V.K. 1965. Technical Notes: Inventory control in N warehouses. The Journal of Industrial Engineering May-June, 212-215. Li, Lode. 2002. Information sharing in a supply chain with horizontal competition.
Management Science 48 (9), 1196-1212.

Mason, Charlotte H. and Perreault, William D. (1991), “Collinearity, power, and interpretation of multiple regression analysis,” Journal of Marketing Research, 18, 268-280. Morrison, Steven A., Winston, Clifford, Bailey, Elizabeth E., and Carlton, Dennis W. (1996), “Causes and consequences of airline fare wars,” Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, Microeconomics, 1996, 85-131.

154

Needham, Paul M. and Evers, Philip T. 1998. The influence of individual cost factors on the use of emergency transshipments. Trans. Res. – E (Logistics and Trans. Rev.) 34 (2), 149-160. Parker, Philip M. and Roller, Lars-Hendrik (1997), “Collusive conduct in duopolies: multimarket contact and cross-ownership in the mobile telephone industry,” Rand
Journal of Economics, 28:2, 304-322.

Phillips, Owen R. and Mason, Charles F. (1992), “Mutual forbearance in experimental conglomerate markets,” Rand Journal of Economics, 23: 3, 395-414. Phillips, Owen R. and Mason, Charles F. (1996), “Market regulation and multimarket rivalry,” Rand Journal of Economics, 23:3, 395-414. Robinson, Lawrence W. 1990. Optimal and approximate policies in multiperiod, multilocation inventory models with transshipments. Operations Research 38 (2) 278-295. Rosenbaum, David and Manns, Leslie (1994), “Cooperation v. rivalry and factors facilitating collusion,” Review of Industrial Organization, 9(6), December, 823-836. Rudi, Nils, Kapur, Sandeep, and Pyke, David E. 2001. A two-location inventory model with transshipment and local decision making. Management Science 47 (12), 1668-1680. Scott, John T. (1982), “Multimarket contact and economic performance,” Review of
Economics and Statistics, 64: 368-375.

Singal, Vijay (1996), “Airline mergers and multimarket contact,” Managerial and
Decision Economics, 28: 2, 304-322.

155

Singh, Nirvikar and Vives, Xavier (1984), “Price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly,” Rand Journal of Economics, 15:4, 546- 554. Sivakumar, K. and Raj, S.P. (1997), “Quality tier competition: how price change influences brand choice and category choice,” Journal of Marketing, 61, 71-84. Tagaras, George. 1989. Effects of pooling on the optimization and service levels of two-location inventory systems. IIE Transactions 21(3), 250-257. Thomas, Charles J. and Willig, Robert D. (2004), “The risk of contagion from multimarket contact,” Working paper, Simon School of Business, University of Rochester; Princeton University, March. Xu, Kefeng, Evers, Philip T., and Fu, Michael C. 2003. Estimating customer service in a two-location continuous review inventory model with emergency transshipments.
European Journal of Operations Research 145, 569-584.

Weng, Z.K. 1995. Channel coordination and quantity discounts. Management
Science 41, 1509-1522.

Windle, Robert J and Dresner, Martin (1995), “The short and long run effects of entry on U.S. domestic air routes,” Transportation Journal, 35(2), pp.14-25.

156



doc_762627701.pdf
 

Attachments

Back
Top